1
The Role of Price Tiers in Advance Purchasing of Event Tickets
Wendy W. Moe
Associate Professor of Marketing
Robert H. Smith School of Business
University of Maryland
3469 Van Munching Hall
College Park, MD 20742
301.405.9187
Peter S. Fader
Frances and Pei-Yuan Chia Professor
The Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
700 Huntsman Hall
3730 Walnut Street
Philadelphia, PA 19104
215.898.1132
January 2008
The authors would like to thank the anonymous company mentioned in this paper for providing the data and for
many insightful discussions surrounding the issues tackled in this paper. The authors would also like to thank Peggy
Tseng for assisting with the preliminary data analysis.
2
The Role of Price Tiers in Advance Purchasing of Event Tickets
ABSTRACT
Advance purchasing is common in several product markets (e.g., concerts, air travel, etc.) but has
generally been understudied in the marketing literature. Research to date has focused primarily
on the analytical modeling of optimal pricing policies. Our work complements this literature by
focusing on the empirical modeling of advance purchasing and the effects of price on consumer
purchasing behavior. Since pricing strategies in practice are typically more complex than simply
setting a single price point, we consider multiple aspects of price: (1) the existence and use of
multiple price tiers (generally based on seat quality), (2) the face value of each ticket, and (3)
discounts that result in week-to-week variations in price. We show that failure to account for
price tiers can lead to exaggerated inferences about the role of price over time. To sort out these
effects, we develop a tier-specific Weibull timing model to describe sales arrivals for event
tickets in the advance selling period, using a proportional hazards framework for the time-
varying covariates. Additionally, we include a component that captures the role of similar
covariates to explain spot market purchasing. Our empirical findings reflect substantial
differences across tiers. Purchasers in the high-priced tier tend to buy earlier in the selling period
and are influenced by price discounts/premiums in the spot market. Purchasers in the low- and
mid-priced tiers tend to delay purchasing and are influenced only by face value prices in the spot
market. Advance purchasers are not influenced by any aspect of price (after accounting for
differences across price-tiers), and this holds true across all price tiers for our dataset of 22
family events. We discuss the implications of these empirical observations for future modelers.
3
The Role of Price Tiers in Advance Purchasing of Event Tickets
In recent years, advance purchasing behavior has attracted increased attention from both
marketing managers and academics. In the technology and entertainment industries, for
example, marketers have been focusing more efforts on announcing and taking orders for
products well before they are actually available for consumption (Knowledge @ Wharton 2007).
These advance orders can provide marketers with actionable information pertaining to overall
demand, the diffusion process across customers, and customer responsiveness to marketing
efforts (e.g., Moe and Fader 2002).
Recent theoretical research in marketing has studied a number of market environments in
which advance purchasing is common (e.g., concerts, air travel, etc.) and has delineated key
differences among these markets. Desiraju and Shugan (1999) differentiate among advance
purchasing markets based on demand characteristics such as the nature of purchase arrivals and
consumer price sensitivity, two characteristics they analytically show to drive optimal pricing
policies. Other studies (Xie and Shugan 2001, Shugan and Xie 2000) have examined the role of
marginal costs and capacity constraints when determining optimal advance pricing policies.
A substantial amount of research on advance purchase markets can also be found in the
yield management literature, particularly with respect to airline revenue management, where
dynamic pricing policies are designed to maximize revenues given capacity constraints. Many of
these studies examine these dynamic pricing policies as a means to price discriminate between
high and low valuation customers (e.g., Biyalogorsky et al 1999, Borenstein and Winston 1990,
Dana 1998). A key behavioral assumption underlying these policy decisions is that low
valuation customers purchase earlier while high valuation customers purchase later.
4
In this paper, we take a different perspective in studying pricing in advance markets.
Rather than focusing on the optimal pricing policy that would arise from a set of behavioral
assumptions, we empirically examine customer purchasing and the role of price in these markets
and identify regularities in behavior, particularly as they pertain to the purchase timing and
nature of sales arrivals. Without a clear understanding of the underlying customer behavior, the
potential benefits of optimal pricing models may be limited. While our findings may have
significant policy implications for practice, our objective is not to propose an optimal pricing
policy or to provide a forecasting tool. Instead, our objective is to empirically study how
customers respond to various aspects of price in the advance purchase market.
Price has several dimensions in many advance markets. The first is the existence of price
tiers, i.e., the variety of prices that are typically offered at any given time. For example, tickets
for a given event may vary dramatically in price depending on the quality of the seats. As a
result, each price tier tends to attract a different segment of buyer, unique in its valuation for the
performance, purchase timing and price responsiveness over time. The second is the ticket’s
face value, which is set in advance for a given tier of tickets and remains unchanged throughout
the duration of the selling period. Finally, we model the effects of price discounting, a common
practice that leads to week-to-week variations in price.
We focus on the advance market for arena events. Like in the airline industry, event
tickets are generally available for purchase months before the actual performance takes place.
Also like in the airline industry, different price tiers for the same performance (or flight) exist.
However, the two industries differ substantially in other ways. First is how they identify price
tiers. In the airline industry, the allocation of price tiers within a flight (at least among coach-
class seats) is largely arbitrary and at the discretion of the airline. Additionally, these price tiers
5
have limited quality differences and are differentiated primarily by the time of purchase. In
contrast, event tickets have clearly distinguishable price tiers that are closely associated with
seating quality (e.g., distance from the stage). As such, the allocation of price tiers is not a
discretionary decision but rather one that is obviously related to the layout of the venue in ways
that virtually every customer would acknowledge and agree upon. Additionally, dynamic ticket
pricing is not a common practice among box offices and major ticket distributors. As a result,
price discrimination occurs primarily when the consumers choose their price tiers or use discount
codes; it is rarely the result of strategic week-to-week price changes instituted by the seller.
One relevant empirical paper that moves away from the airline setting is Leslie (2004),
who examined price discrimination in Broadway theater tickets through the use of price tiers and
couponing. The focus of his research was on the buyer’s price sensitivity and choice of tier.
When and what a consumer purchased depended on the ticket price, transaction costs and
capacity constraints. While Leslie (2004) examined the consumer’s choice of price tiers and
response to price discounting, he did not address any differences in purchase timing among the
available tiers (which reflect differences between low versus high valuation customers) aside
from the effects resulting from capacity constraints.
Despite the frequent focus on capacity constraints in many of these papers, surprisingly
few events actually bump into such constraints. While the press tends to highlight the sold-out
Hannah Montana concert or playoff basketball games, most arena performances (primarily
concerts, sporting activities, and family shows) take place with excess capacity. Even in Leslie’s
(2004) study of Broadway shows, only 12 of the 199 performances in their dataset were sold-out
shows – and those are held in theaters with far smaller capacity than most arenas. In our data set,
not a single performance sold out its capacity, either for the entire venue or for specific price
6
tiers. Therefore, in this paper, we examine advance purchase behavior in the absence of capacity
constraints – and we are quite comfortable generalizing from the observations we make here
We develop a Weibull timing model of purchasing for each tier that describes both the
purchase timing decision of buyers in that price tier as well as measuring their responsiveness to
various dimensions of price through the use of time-varying (and tier-specific) price-related
covariates. We also incorporate into the model a measure of spot market size. In this component
of the model, we allow the pricing schedule employed in the advance selling period to affect the
relative size of the spot market.
While previous research has modeled the nature of sales arrivals in advance markets
using stochastic models, they have done so at the aggregate performance level rather than at the
price-tier level (see McGill and van Ryzin 1999 for a review). By examining sales arrivals for
specific price tiers, we can empirically examine and compare the behaviors of buyers with
different valuations for the performance.
Our findings show that advance purchasing behavior tends to vary dramatically across
different price tiers even within a single performance. We examine a highly varied set of events
and find consistent results across them. While buying behavior varies across price tiers, buyers
are virtually unaffected by the face value price or week-to-week price variations in the advance
selling period. The only element of price that is important to these buyers is the price tier. Spot-
market buyers, on the other hand, are influenced both by face values (in the low- and mid-priced
tiers) and the spot-market price relative to the advance price (in the high-priced tier). Overall,
however, the largest source of variation in behavior arises from the differences across price tiers
rather than any pricing strategy within tier. This is a significant finding that we hope will
contribute to the extant literature as well as to how event marketers think about pricing.
7
The Role of Price Tiers in the Market for Event Tickets
Our Sample
Our analysis focuses on a sample of 22 performances of “family” events (e.g., circus,
children’s concerts, etc.). The 22 performances in our sample are held in a variety of locations
ranging from major markets such as New York and Los Angeles to smaller markets such as
Wheeling, WV, and Laredo, TX. As a result, sales and prices vary substantially across events.
The events all took place between January and June 2004, but ticket sales began far earlier with
events experiencing as many as 18 weeks of tickets sales leading up to the performance date.
Table 1 provides some descriptive information for each of the 22 performances in our sample.
The data were provided to us by a leading nationwide ticketing agency, which at the time
served as the dominant distribution channel for the vast majority of tickets at all events. Small
numbers of tickets can be held back by the venue, the event promoter, and other local entities.
But these tickets are not sold in a conventional manner (e.g., they are used for local radio station
giveaways), so there is little “leakage” of these tickets into the general population of buyers.
Thus our dataset provides a fairly accurate and complete representation of the sales patterns for
every event. (Our data period precedes the prominent role of now-popular resellers such as
StubHub.)
8
Table 1. Descriptive Information for Event Performances
Total Range of Selling
Event Location Month Sales Prices Paid Weeks
1. New York, NY April 2004 12252 $5.00 - $169.95 18
2. New York, NY March 2004 9929 $5.00 - $169.95 16
3. San Diego, CA February 2004 8247 $7.00 - $56.30 10
4. Atlanta, GA February 2004 7979 $5.00 - $101.35 15
5. Albany, NY April 2004 7713 $5.50 - $37.15 17
6. Phoenix, AZ June 2004 7198 $2.50 - $79.75 10
7. Los Angeles, CA January 2004 6695 $5.00 - $56.30 11
8. Nashville, TN January 2004 6336 $5.75 - $43.25 10
9. Raleigh, NC February 2004 6274 $10.00 - $42.80 8
10. Kansas City, MO March 2004 6160 $9.50 - $48.90 9
11. San Antonio, TX June 2004 6048 $5.00 - $40.05 10
12. Sacramento, CA February 2004 5891 $10.00 - $55.00 13
13. Phoenix, AZ January 2004 5405 $2.50 - $58.90 13
14. Miami, FL April 2004 5036 $8.50 - $58.00 12
15. Laredo, TX May 2004 4845 $8.25 - $44.50 7
16. Miami, FL January 2004 2866 $2.50 - $41.70 9
17. New Orleans, LA May 2004 2746 $10.50 - $40.50 8
18. Jacksonville, FL April 2004 1950 $10.00 - $54.25 10
19. Wheeling, WV March 2004 1720 $5.00 - $23.55 6
20. Atlantic City, NJ May 2004 1548 $6.50 - $66.00 10
21. Madison, WI May 2004 561 $6.00 - $33.25 5
22. Miami, FL March 2004 428 $1.50 - $58.00 11
The price of a ticket has several dimensions in our data. First is the face value of each
ticket. The face value is the full price of that ticket prior to any service charges or facilities fees
that may be imposed. The face value is set well in advance of the selling period and is fixed for
the duration of the selling period. However, this is not to say that consumers face unchanging
prices over time. Instead, discounts are common and vary from week to week. The price paid
by each buyer is the face value plus any service/facilities charges and less any price discount
available that week and claimed by the buyer. Because the available discounts vary from week
to week, the average price paid also changes from week to week. Therefore, the second
dimension of price that we consider is the week-to-week variation in price. We will discuss
measures of this aspect of price later when we develop our model. The final facet of price is the
9
price tier. For each performance, there are a variety of tickets with different face values and/or
seating locations that are defined by the layout of the venue. The number of ticket categories
varies across events. While some had as few as three ticket categories, others had as many as
nine. In many cases, multiple categories shared the same face value but were divided into two
separate categories to reflect the seating location. In these cases, we collapsed the two categories
into one.
To allow for comparability across performances, we grouped ticket categories into three
tiers: high-priced, mid-priced and low-priced. Two separate coders independently viewed the
floor plans of the venues along with the face-value prices and seating locations of those tickets
available for sale. Based on the distribution of ticket prices and seating locations, ticket
categories were assigned to one of the three price tiers. The task was surprisingly straight-
forward since the face value prices of tickets tended to cluster together.
One final issue that we need to address is that of capacity utilization. As noted earlier,
while the perception may be that capacity limitations pose frequent and pressing constraints in
this industry, this is rarely the case. The more common events, such as gymnastics competitions,
skating shows, circuses, rodeos or even concerts by less popular artists, are less salient than the
sold-out rock concerts that tend to be the focus of news stories and conversations. In our
conversations with two separate firms (i.e., our data provider and another nationwide ticketing
company), we were told that capacity is rarely an issue for a given performance. With the
exception of a handful of popular concerts, venue sizes far exceed demand for most events.
Table 2 summarizes the capacity utilization across the performances in our data. These measures
show that capacity constraints are non-binding in our data and therefore should not be the driving
force behind the purchasing behavior we model
10
Table 2. Capacity Utilization*
High-Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier Low-Priced Tier
Minimum 22.0% 6.3% 2.9%
25
th
percentile 81.7% 58.0% 20.8%
Median 88.8% 83.5% 31.6%
75% percentile 91.7% 95.7% 64.3%
Maximum 99.7% 98.6% 97.3%
* Percentages are the percent of tickets available for sale that are actually sold. This measure excludes all
those tickets that are held back for special promotions.
Aggregate Sales and Pricing Patterns
To illustrate the typical sales and pricing patterns observed, consider two different events
that took place in Miami, FL. Figure 1 plots the overall sales and prices (aggregated across price
tiers) for each advance selling week, t.
Figure 1: Overall Sales and Pricing Patterns
Overall Sales and Price
Miami (January Event)
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
1234567Event
Week
Selling Week
Sales
$0.00
$5.00
$10.00
$15.00
$20.00
$25.00
$30.00
Price
sales average price
Overall Sales and Price
Miami (April Event)
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Event
Week
Selling Week
Sales
$0.00
$5.00
$10.00
$15.00
$20.00
$25.00
$30.00
$35.00
$40.00
$45.00
Price
sales average price
In both cases, peak sales occur in the performance week. In the advance weeks, sales start
relatively low and gradually build as the performance approaches. In contrast, average price paid
in the advance weeks starts high and gradually declines as the performance week approaches.
These aggregate sales and price patterns are similar across events and are consistent with the
11
analytical findings of Desiraju and Shugan (1999) relating optimal pricing policies to the nature
of sales arrivals.
Difference across Price Tiers
At first glance, the downward sloping price curve seems to suggest that the ticket seller is
employing a deliberate pricing policy of decreasing price as the performance nears. However,
upon further investigation, this trend is primarily an artifact of aggregating across price tiers.
Figure 2 plots the percent of sales attributable to each price tier and shows that tickets in the
high-priced tier tend to sell disproportionately in the early weeks of the advance selling period
while tickets in the low-priced tier tend to sell more as the performance approaches. When these
differences across price tiers are ignored and aggregated to provide an overall average price paid,
the result is what appears to be a schedule of decreasing prices over time.
Figure 2. Percent of Weekly Sales by Price Tier
Percent of Weekly Sales by Tier
Miami (January Event)
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1234567Event
Week
Selling Week
% of Weekly Sales
Low -Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tie
r
Percent of Weekly Sales by Tier
Miami (April Event)
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1234567Event
Week
Selling Week
% of Weekly Sales
Low -Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tie
r
The same phenomenon can be observed across the remaining events in our data set.
Figure 3 shows the percent of all sales that occur in the early selling period (i.e., all weeks prior
to the final month of sales) and provides an overview of how this measure varies across events
12
for each tier. The boxes represent the events in the interquartile range (i.e., the middle 50
th
percentile), while the lines indicate the full range of observed values. It is quite evident that only
a small percentage of the low-priced tickets sell in the early weeks of the advance selling period.
In contrast a significant percentage of high-priced tickets sell in the first four weeks. This
pattern is similar to that described above where the proportion of ticket sales in the high-priced
tier tend to decrease as the performance approaches while the opposite is true in the low-priced
tier. These sales patterns highlight the potential pitfalls of ignoring price tiers and conducting
aggregate level research, as many of the dynamics within price tiers are masked in aggregation.
They also highlight one of the key differences, discussed earlier, between demand patterns for
events compared to airlines and other industries that rely upon traditional notions of yield
management.
Figure 3. Summary of Sales Timing by Tier
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
Low-Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Percent Early Sales
13
Pricing over Time
In addition to the price differences across tiers, week-to-week price variations also exist
within tiers. However, these variations are not as dramatic and systematic as the price plots in
Figure 1 might suggest. For some events and tiers, prices do decline as the performance
approaches. However, there are also several instances where an increasing price pattern is
observed. In fact, pricing patterns differ even across the two Miami events used in our example.
In Figure 4, the average price in each tier is charted over time for the same two events presented
in Figure 2. For ease of presentation, the selling period is divided into three stages. The spot
period represents the week of the performance. The late period represents the month prior to the
performance (excluding the spot period), and the early period represents all weeks prior to the
final month of sales. Since face values are set before the tickets are made available for sales and
remain unchanged throughout the selling period, any variation seen in prices over time are due
largely to price discounting. For the January event, tier-specific prices remain quite stable over
time, a fact that is lost in the aggregate event-level data (Figure 1). The April event, on the other
hand, exhibits slightly more price variation over time. Specifically, tickets in the low- and the
mid-priced tiers tend to get less expensive as the performance approaches. Ticket prices for the
high-priced tier indicate a more irregular pricing pattern. But these within-tier variations are still
quite modest compared to the aggregate patterns shown in Figure 1.
In this section, we have shown that aggregate performance-level trends in sales and
pricing often masks the more complex dynamics that occur due to the existence of price tiers.
Therefore, in the next section, we model ticket sales at the tier level. We hope to complement
the existing research that relates optimal pricing policies to buyer behavior by empirically
modeling and highlighting differences in behavior across tiers.
14
Figure 4. Average Price Paid by Tier
Average Price by Tier
Miami (January Event)
$-
$10.00
$20.00
$30.00
$40.00
$50.00
Low -Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Price
Ea r l y Late Spot
Average Price by Tier
Miami (April Event)
$-
$10.00
$20.00
$30.00
$40.00
$50.00
Low-Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Price
Ea r l y Late Spot
Model Development
Our proposed model has several important characteristics which we will develop in turn.
First, it explicitly models sales of tickets in each price tier. Second, it differentiates between the
advance selling market and the spot market. Finally, we capture the effects of face value and
week-to-week variations in price and measure their impact on the advance market as well as the
spot market.
The Advance Market
We start by modeling the timing of sales arrivals for each tier as a Weibull process. This
process governs when buyers in the advance market purchase their tickets. This may be as early
as several months prior to the performance or as late as a few days before the performance. We
choose the Weibull for its flexibility in accommodating a variety of shapes that are consistent
with what we see empirically in our data. The associated hazard function
)|( jth
i
, survival
15
function )|( jtS
i
and cumulative distribution function )|( jtF
i
for each event i and tier j are as
follows:
1
)|(
=
ij
c
ijiji
tcjth
λ
ij
c
t
ij
jt
i
h
i
eejtS
λ
==
)|(
)|(
ij
c
t
ij
ii
ejtSjtF
λ
== 1)|(1)|(
where t = advance selling week
λ
ij
= slope parameter for event i purchases in tier j (
λ
ij
> 0)
c
ij
= shape parameter for event i purchases in tier j (c
ij
> 0)
Modeling ticket sales is different from most other purchasing contexts in that all
purchases must be made by a predetermined time – the time of the performance. However, if
purchase timing were modeled to strictly follow a Weibull timing process, ticket sales could
theoretically extend beyond the performance date. Since the occurrence of the performance
effectively right censors the selling period, buyers who would have preferred to delay purchase
are forced to purchase at or before the time of the performance. To accommodate this, we
assume that the remainder of the cdf at the time of the performance is compressed and
materializes at the last minute.
(1)
ij
c
t
ij
ii
ejtSjtF
λ
== 1)|(1)|( if t < T
1)|(
=
jtF
i
if t = T
where T is the time of the performance.
16
The Spot Market
In addition to the advance-purchase market, there is also a substantial spot market that is
not fully captured by the model developed thus far. Therefore, we model the large number of
buyers who buy in the spot market by inflating the probability of purchase at t = T (i.e., the
performance week) in the same way that a zero-inflated Poisson inflates the probability at zero.
After accommodating both the spot market buyers and the discrete-time nature of our observed
data (i.e., weekly counts), we can write the probability of observing a tier j ticket purchase at
time t as:
(2)
]
)|1()|()1()|( jtFjtFIjtP
iiijtiji
+
=
φ
φ
where I
t
= 1 for t = T (I
t
= 0, otherwise),
φ
ij
represents the proportion of sales from strictly spot
buyers and
)|( jtF
i
is defined above in equation (1). Since the size of the spot market can be
influenced by the pricing policy, we will further define
φ
ij
in the next section.
The Role of Price
Our objective in this paper is to better understand the role of price in an advance market
1
.
This objective is partly satisfied by modeling the differences between price tiers as we have done
above. However, two other aspects of price remain: face value and week-to-week variations due
to discounting.
Sales in the advance market are modeled as a Weibull timing process. Incorporating
covariates in a Weibull hazard model is a relatively straightforward process. The first covariate
1
One potential concern is that pricing (i.e., discounting) strategies may not be independent of the expected market
response to price. Therefore, we also tested a model that treats price as non-random. Specifically, we followed the
approach taken by Manchanda, Rossi, and Allenby (2004) and simultaneously modeled price as a function of the
expected effect of price and expected baseline sales. None of these factors have a significant effect on price.
Therefore, for the remainder of the paper, we focus only on the model which treats price variations as exogenous
and random.
17
effect we consider is the effect of face value. Because there are some slight variations in face
value within a given price tier, we calculate the average face value (AFV) for each performance-
tier combination. This value is unchanged over time within a given performance-tier and
captures the primary impact of price level on advance buying behavior. The second covariate
effect we consider is that of week-to-week variations in price. The proportional hazards
framework allows us to easily incorporate time-varying covariates and provides coefficients that
reflect the effect of week-to-week changes in the covariates. However, the coefficients reflect
the overall level of the covariates as well. Therefore, to separate the effect of week-to-week
variations in price from the effect of overall price level, we use the average percentage discount
(DISCOUNT) instead of average price paid as a time-varying covariate. We also include the
number of advance selling weeks (PREWK) and seasonality variables (THANKS and XMAS) as
control covariates. We include all of these covariates through the Weibull hazard function as
follows:
{}
ijtij
Xβexp)|(
1
=
ij
c
ijiji
tcjth
λ
where
X
ijt
is a vector of covariates that includes:
THANKS
it
= an indicator variable for the week before Thanksgiving
XMAS
it
= an indicator variable for the week before Christmas
PREWK
i
= number of advance selling weeks
AFV
ij
= average face value of tickets sold in tier j for performance i
DISCOUNT
ijt
= the average percentage discount for a tier j ticket for performance i at
week t
Using standard proportional hazard methods, we fine-tune the cdfs shown in equations
(1) and (2) to incorporate these covariates as follows.
=
=
t
u
ij
c
ij
c
iji
euujtF
1
])1([exp1)|(
iju
X
ij
β
λ
, if t < T
18
Our modeling objective in the spot market is the same as that in the advance market: to
capture the effects of face value as well as week-to-week price variations in the weeks leading up
to the performance. To model the effect of face value, we again use the average face value
(AFV) as a covariate. However, to capture the effect of week-to-week variations in price, we
need to consider a new measure that compares the spot market price to earlier prices. As a time-
varying covariate in the advance-selling period, the DISCOUNT covariate reflects the effect of
week-to-week changes in price as well as the size of the discount. However, as a covariate for
spot market size, the DISCOUNT measure would not provide any comparison to earlier prices.
Therefore, in the spot market component of the model, we use Spot Price Index (SPI) as a
covariate and calculate it for each tier as the average price paid in the spot market (t=T) divided
by the average price paid in the advance market (t<T). If pricing strategies are unchanged
between the advance market and the spot market, we would have SPI=1. An SPI<1 indicates
additional discounting in the spot market. An SPI>1 indicates that spot market tickets are selling
at a premium relative to the tickets sold in earlier weeks.
To incorporate spot market covariates, we define the spot market parameter,
φ
ij
, from
equation (2) as follows:
ij
ij
ij
e
e
θ
θ
φ
+
=
1
where
ijij
Zγ
=
ij
θ
where Z
ij
is a vector of covariates that includes an intercept and the following
2
:
PREWK
i
= number of advance selling weeks
AFV
ij
= average face value
SPI
ij
= spot price index
2
We do not include Thanksgiving or Christmas as covariates since none of the events in our data set have scheduled
performances during those weeks.
19
Heterogeneity across Events
To accommodate heterogeneity across events, we assume that both the slope (
λ
ij
) and
shape (c
ij
) parameters of the Weibull process governing sales within each performance-tier are
drawn from independent normal distributions as follows:
),(~)ln(
),(~)ln(
cjcjij
jjij
Normalc
Normal
σμ
σ
μ
λ
λλ
Additionally, we allow covariate effects to vary across events according to independent
normal distributions:
),(~
kj
s
kj
N
kij
ββ
and ),(~
rjrjrij
sN
γγ
where k indexes the covariates in the Weibull hazard model and r indexes the covariates
(including the intercept) in the spot market component of the model.
To complete the model specification, we choose appropriately diffuse and uninformative
priors for each of our parameters. We estimate this model using WinBUGS and run 20,000
iterations, discarding the first 15,000 for burn-in. Trace plots and Monte Carlo standard errors
were monitored to ensure convergence.
We also estimated a number of benchmark models, including one that allowed for
correlations among parameters and another that did not allow for parameter differences across
tiers. In the correlated model, we found that most correlations were statistically insignificant,
and most of the exceptions were not substantially different from zero (i.e., the largest correlation
was 0.0089). In the “homogeneous-tiers” model, all price tiers shared the same Weibull
parameters and price coefficients. This model performed far worse than the proposed model (as
indicated by the same fit measures described in the next section). Since our objective here is to
focus more on empirical regularities rather than model comparison, per se, we will limit our
20
discussion to the results of the proposed model alone, since it outperforms our benchmarks while
providing an accurate and parsimonious description of buyer behavior in this market.
3
Results
Model Validation
Figure 5 presents tracking plots for the same two events shown in Figure 1. It is clear
that the model fits the data quite well. In fact, because the week-to-week fit is so accurate, it is
difficult to distinguish the actual sales line from the estimated sales line.
Figure 5. Tracking Plots for Miami Events
Model Fit
Miami (January Event)
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
1234567Event
Week
Selling Week
Sales
ACTUAL ESTIMA TED
Model Fit
Miami (April Event)
0
500
1000
1500
2000
2500
1234567Event
Week
Selling Week
Sales
ACTUAL ES TIMA TED
To further illustrate the quality of the model, Figure 6 shows the model fit for the same
two events by tier. Again, for ease of presentation purposes, we divide the advance selling
period into early, late and spot periods.
3
Comparison measures between the models are available from the authors.
21
Figure 6. Model Fit by Tier for Miami Events
Model Fit by Tier
Miami (January Event)
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
Early Late Spot Early Late Spot Early Late Spot
Low -Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Sales
Actual
Est i ma t ed
Model Fit by Tier
Miami (April Event)
0
200
400
600
800
1000
1200
1400
1600
1800
Early Late Spot Early Late Spot Early Late Spot
Low -Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Sales
Actual
Estimated
Figures 5 and 6 show that the model provides a very good fit for the two events displayed
despite the earlier discussion that the two events exhibit slightly different sales patterns at the tier
level. For the January event, sales of tickets in the high-price tier increase as the performance
approaches
4
. In contrast, sales of tickets in the high-price tier decrease as the performance
approaches in April. Despite these differences, the model presented in this paper fits both events
very well.
To extend the analysis presented in Figure 6 to the complete set of events, we calculate
RMSE (root mean squared error) as an indicator of model fit and present the results in Table 3.
We use the selling period (i.e., spot, late, and early) as our unit of analysis and then average
across periods as follows:
3
)])([)((
},,{
2
=
earlylatespot
ijij
ij
SalesESales
RMSE
τ
ττ
4
While the number of tickets sold in the high-price tier increases as the event approaches, it represents a decreasing
percentage of all tickets sold since sales in the low- and mid-price tiers increase dramatically.
22
Table 3: Model Fit
Low-Priced Mid-Priced High-Priced Overall
RMSE 11.55 72.51 15.49 45.41
RMSE (% of sales) 1.25% 1.69% 2.35% 0.77%
# of performances with RMSE < 2.5% 20 17 16 21
# of performances with RMSE 2.5%-5.0% 1 4 4 1
# of performances with RMSE > 5.0% 1 1 2 0
Overall, the RMSE measures provided in Table 3 show that the model fits the data very well.
The overall fit for all performances, regardless of price tiers, generates an RMSE of 45.41. The
model fit by price tier is just as impressive with RMSE ranging from 11.55 for the low-priced
tier to 72.51 for the mid-priced tier. To better evaluate RMSE, we also provide in Table 3 the
percent of total performance-tier sales the RMSE represents. Given the volume of sales for each
performance-tier, the RMSE reported in Table 3 indicate an excellent fit with overall and tier-
specific errors falling within 2.5% of sales across performances.
Parameter Results: The Advance Market
We begin our discussion of results by examining the baseline Weibull parameters for
each price tier,
λ
j
and c
j
. These parameters represent the underlying purchase timing process
absent of any covariate or spot market effects (see Table 4 for all parameter estimates).
23
Table 4. Parameter Estimates
Low-Priced Mid-Priced High-Priced
Parameter Variable Tier Tier Tier
Baseline Weibull Parameters
μ(λ)
Slope parameter 0.0065 0.043
0.16
[0.0018, 0.029] [0.031, 0.058] [0.10, 0.26]
μ
(c) Shape parameter 4.16 2.94 2.12
[3.31, 5.23] [2.39, 3.63] [1.35, 3.22]
Advance-Market Parameters
THANKS
β
Thanksgiving effect 0.20 1.17 1.79
[-1.30, 1.36] [0.086, 2.08] [-0.33, 3.04]
XMAS
β
Christmas effect 0.69 0.78 0.90
[-1.83, 2.80] [-0.45, 1.97] [-0.75, 2.48]
PREWK
β
# of Adv. Selling Weeks -0.65 -0.33 -0.19
[-0.84, -0.44] [-0.46, -0.19] [-0.34, -0.039]
AFV
β
Average Face Value -0.074 -0.12 0.0069
[-0.19, 0.040] [-0.46, 0.15] [-0.21, 0.21]
DISCOUNT
β
Percent Price Discount 1.97 2.08 -0.59
[-2.31, 6.25] [-0.21, 4.30] [-4.88, 3.79]
Spot Market Parameters
INT
γ
Intercept -0.61 -0.17 2.00
[-5.06, 4.20] [-6.27, 4.96] [0.71, 3.54]
PREWK
γ
# of Adv. Selling Weeks -1.76 -3.05 -0.83
[-4.12, -0.032] [-5.86, -0.29] [-1.37, -0.35]
AFV
γ
Average Face Value -5.03 -3.82 -0.031
[-8.54, -1.89] [-7.31, -0.30] [-0.56, 0.39]
SPI
γ
Spot Market Index -0.25 0.14 -3.17
[-4.56, 4.41] [-4.67, 9.46] [-4.80, -0.65]
* Values in brackets represent the 90% confidence range
* Values in bold indicate parameters that are significant at
p = 0.10
24
Figure 7 plots the theoretical Weibull distributions that result from the parameter
estimates presented in Table 4. These distributions assume steady pricing in the advance selling
weeks and median values for the number of advance selling weeks, AFV, and SPI for each tier.
From this figure, we can see that tickets in the high-priced tier tend to sell earlier. In contrast,
buyers of the mid- or low-priced tickets tend to delay their purchase. This is the underlying
dynamic that results in the perception that prices decline as the performance approaches. This
result is also consistent with Desiraju and Shugan’s (1999) contention that for this class of
products (e.g., concerts, fashion, etc.), buyers who have the greatest value for the service buy
earlier in the advance selling period.
Figure 7. Baseline Weibull Process by Tier
0
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.1
0.12
0.14
0.16
0.18
0.2
12345678910
Selling Week
P(t)
Low-Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
For the most part, the seasonality covariates for Thanksgiving and Christmas have no
effect on the timing of ticket purchases for any tier of tickets. We see an effect of Thanksgiving
on the mid-priced tier that is marginally significant (the coefficient is significant at p=0.10 but
not at p=0.05). The number of advance selling weeks has a significant and negative effect on the
25
Weibull hazard across all three price-tiers. In other words, the earlier that the tickets are made
available for sale, the more gradual is the pattern of sales arrivals.
Interestingly, the price of the tickets also has no significant impact on sales in the early
market once price tiers are taken into account. Neither the face value nor any price discounting
influences the purchasing decision in the advance market. This suggests that price promotions in
the early market only serve to decrease margins.
Parameter Results: The Spot Market
In contrast to the results for the advance market, several covariates influence the size of
the spot market. The number of advance selling weeks has a significantly negative effect on the
size of the spot market for all three price tiers. In other words, the longer tickets for an event
have been available for sales, the smaller the spot market. This makes intuitive sense since the
longer selling period prior to the scheduled performance provides more opportunities for
consumers to buy early.
Pricing, unlike in the advance market, has a significant effect in the spot market. The
face value of the ticket influences the size of the spot market in the low- and mid-priced tiers
while the spot price (SPI) has an influence on the size of the spot market in the high-priced tier.
Figure 8 summarizes the pricing policies in the spot market across performances for each
of the three price tiers. The figure illustrates that additional price discounting in the final selling
week (SPI<1) is a common practice in all three tiers with the most severe discounting occurring
in the mid-price tier. However, there are also instances of tickets selling at a price premium in
the spot market (SPI>1). In our sample of 22 performances, all of them had one or more price
tiers selling at a price discount in the spot market. Fourteen performances had one or more price
26
tiers selling at a price premium in the spot market. (Perhaps these events had discount coupons
that expired before the performance date, but other fees that continued to apply.)
Figure 8. Summary of Spot-Market Pricing
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1
1.1
1.2
Low-Priced Tier
(median=0.98)
Mid-Priced Tier
(median=0.96)
High-Priced Tier
(median=0.97)
SPI
Despite all the price variability shown in Figure 8, spot-market prices have very little
impact on the relative size of the spot market in the low- and mid-priced tiers. For these two
tiers, the only facet of price that has an impact on purchasing is the ticket’s face value, which
remains unchanged throughout the selling period. The model results (
LOWAFV,
γ
=-5.03,
MIDAFV,
γ
=-3.82) indicate that face value has a significant and negative effect in both the low-
and the mid-priced tiers, suggesting that higher face values encourage consumers to buy in the
advance market rather than in the spot market. This could be because higher prices require a
bigger commitment (and more advance planning) by the consumer. The Spot Price Index (SPI),
however, has no significant effect on the relative size of the spot market in these two tiers. This
result, coupled with the Weibull parameter estimates, indicates that price discounting, and the
27
week-to-week price variations that result, appear to have no impact on ticket buying behavior in
either the advance or the spot market for the low- and mid-priced tiers.
Customer behavior in the high-priced tier presents a sharp contrast to that seen in the
other two tiers. In the high-priced tier, face value has no significant impact on the size of the
spot market while a discounted spot market price can significantly increase the relative size of
the spot market (
HIGHSPI,
γ
=-3.17). This result is consistent with the asymmetric price effects
found by Blattberg and Wisniewski (1988) who showed that price discounts are more effective
when applied to high quality products than when applied to low quality products. In the context
of event tickets, discounting spot market prices for high-priced (and high-quality) tickets expand
the spot market more effectively than if the same discounts were applied to the other tiers.
Summary of Pricing Effects
Overall, there seem to be significant differences in purchasing behavior between price
tiers (see Table 5 for a summary). High-priced tier consumers tend to buy earlier while low- and
mid-priced tier consumers are more likely to delay their purchase.
In addition to difference across tiers, the prices themselves also have effects that vary
across tiers. While none of the pricing covariates have an impact on when tickets are purchased
in the advance market, we do see significant effects in the spot market. While the face value of
the tickets affects the spot market for the low- and mid-priced tiers, the spot price
premium/discount (SPI) is what influences buying behavior in the high-priced tier. Overall, it
appears to be difficult to influence sales in the low- and mid-priced tiers once a face value has
been set. Sales of tickets in the high-priced tier can, however, be influenced by discounting in
28
the spot market, but this has a limited impact due to the smaller number of consumers in this tier,
particularly as the performance gets closer..
Table 5. Summary of Pricing Effects
Low-Priced Tier Mid-Priced Tier High-Priced Tier
Advance Market Effects
Higher Face Values -- -- --
Larger Price Discounts -- -- --
Spot Market Effects
Higher Face Values smaller spot mkt smaller spot mkt --
Spot Market Discounts -- -- larger spot mkt
CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION
In this paper, we model the effects of pricing on advance purchases of event tickets. Our
findings show that there are significant differences in buying behavior across price tiers, even
within a given performance. In fact, the differences across price tiers are far greater than any
variation within tier. Overall, buyers of high-priced tickets tend to purchase earlier in the selling
period than buyers of low- and mid-priced tickets. This is in contrast to the airline industry
where high-value customers tend to arrive later than low-value customers. One possible
explanation for this pattern of behavior is that high-value customers purchase earlier in the
selling period to avoid capacity constraints (Desiraju and Shugan 1999, Leslie 2004). However,
we examined an environment where capacity tends not to be a constraint. An alternative
explanation is that high-value customers are less sensitive to scheduling uncertainty and have
lower relative costs associated with committing to a future event. The idea that customers have
different costs of commitment is one that has been raised in previous research (Desiraju and
29
Shugan 1999) but not fully explored. Our findings suggest that this would be an important issue
to study further.
Not only do the expected purchase times vary across tiers, but consumer response to face
value prices and week-to-week variations in price also differ across tiers. With the exception of
spot-price discounting in the high-priced tier, event marketers have little ability to influence sales
with price once face values are set and tickets are made available for sale. In the spot market for
tickets in the high-priced tier, spot-price discounting can increase the number of buyers in the
spot market. The same effect is not seen in the other tiers.
Overall, advance purchasing continues to be a promising area of research in marketing.
In addition to the purchase timing and pricing issues discussed in this paper, several significant
opportunities remain for future research. In this paper, we examined only a sample of events and
treated each independently. However, event marketers often face the decision of scheduling a
series of performances in a given market rather than just offering one performance. This
schedule of performances has an impact on the advance-selling market that we do not yet
understand. Likewise, there is often a broader marketing campaign surrounding this schedule
(i.e., beyond price tactics alone) that has generally been overlooked as well. Overall, the advance
purchasing environment is rich with research questions that can provide a significant impact on
how event managers and ticket sellers make decisions, yet only a few of these questions have
been addressed in this paper and previous ones.
30
References
Biyalogorsky, E., Carmon, Z., Fruchter, G., and Gerstner, E. (1999), “Overselling and
Opportunistic Cancellations,” Marketing Science, (18), pp. 605–610.
Blattberg, Robert C. and Kenneth J. Wisniewski (1988), “Priced-Induced Patterns of
Competition,” Marketing Science, 8 (4), 291-309.
Borenstein, S., and Rose, L.R. (1994), “Competition and Price Dispersion in the U.S. Airline
Industry,” Journal of Political Economy, (102), pp. 653–683.
Cachon, Gerard P. (2004), “The Allocation of Inventory Risk in a Supply Chain: Push, Pull, and
Advance Purchase Discount,” Management Science, 50 (2), 222-238.
Dana, J.D. (1998), “Advance-Purchase Discounts and Price Discrimination in Competitive
Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, (106), pp. 395–422.
Desiraju, Ramarao and Steven M. Shugan (1999), “Strategic Service Pricing and Yield
Management,” Journal of Marketing, 63 (January), 44-56.
Knowledge @ Wharton (2007), “New Products (Like the iPhone): Announce Early or Go for the
Surprise Rollout?” June 13, http://knowledge.wharton.upenn.edu/article.cfm?articleid=1752.
Leslie, Philip (2004), “Price Discrimination in Broadway Theater,” RAND Journal of
Economics, 35 (3), 520-541.
McCardle, Kevin, Kumar Rajaram and Christopher S. Tang (2004), “Advance Booking Discount
Programs Under Retail Competition,” Management Science, 50 (5), 701-708.
McGill, J.I., and van Ryzin, G.J. (1999), “Revenue Management: Research Overview and
Prospects,” Transportation Science, (33), pp. 233–256.
Moe, Wendy W. and Peter S. Fader (2002), “Using Advance Purchase Orders to Forecast New
Product Sales,” Marketing Science, 21 (3), 347-364.
Shugan, Steven M. and Jinhong Xie (2000), “Advance Selling for Services,” California
Management Review, 46 (3), 37-54.
Tang, Christopher S., Kumar Rajaram, Aydin Alptekinoglu and Jihong Ou (2004), “The Benefits
of Advance Booking Discount Programs: Model and Analysis,” Management Science, 50 (4),
465-478.
Xie, Jinhong and Steven M. Shugan (2001), “Electronic Tickets, Smart Cards, and Online
Prepayments: When and How to Advance Sell,” Marketing Science, 20 (3), 219-243.