An analysis of ticket pricing 39
An analysis of ticket pricing in the primary and
secondary concert marketplace
Terrance Tompkins
1
Abstract
This paper examines the various factors and trends impacting ticket pricing in the
concert industry through a survey of literature published on the primary and sec-
ondary markets. It explores the primary market's motivation to price concert tickets
below the profit maximizing level and the role of the secondary ticket market in
capitalizing on excess demand by establishing a new price point for tickets in the
market. The paper researches recent tools developed by the primary and secondary
market stakeholders including the Ticketmaster Verified Fan Program and
SeatGeek's "Deal Ranking" algorithm. Legislation associated with scalping in the
secondary ticket market in the United States is reviewed. Finally, solutions are pro-
posed for the primary ticket market to marginalize the impact of the secondary
ticket market.
Keywords: Concert promotion, concert ticket pricing, dynamic pricing, touring,
secondary tickets, scalping
1 Introduction
A New York Post headline read "Shameless Sandy Outrage" with the
article arguing that scalpers should be ashamed for cashing in on a Hur-
ricane Sandy benefit concert, taking place at Madison Square Garden.
This concert featured performances by Bruce Springsteen, The Rolling
Stones, Paul McCartney, Billy Joel, Bon Jovi, Eddie Vedder, The Who and
the star-studded line-up sold out within minutes of going on sale. The
tickets instantly appeared on secondary ticket sites like StubHub, selling
at a minimum 273% mark-up on the face value of the ticket, charging
1
Terrance Tompkins is Program Director and Assistant Professor Music Industry at Hofstra Universi-
ty in Long Island, NY. Tompkins held positions as Senior Director of Artist Relations at PledgeMusic,
and Program Director/Instructor of Music Business at Bowling Green State University. Tompkins
spent seven years at Columbia Records working in A&R where he discovered the Grammy Award
winning multi-platinum recording artist John Legend. His experience in the touring industry includes
talent buying for a prestigious rock club as well as a Showcase Director for the Philadelphia Music
Conference, one of the largest music conferences in the United States at the time
(terran[email protected]du).
40 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
$560 per person for seats in the nose bleed section at Madison Square
Garden. The most expensive ticket sold for $3,700 and over 900 tickets
were available on reseller sites causing the promoter of the benefit
show to call out StubHub for their unfair practices (MacLeod 2012).
Ticket scalping has been part of the U.S. culture for the past century, but
technology has changed the nature of such ticket sales evolving from
scalpers hawking tickets outside an arena to sophisticated computer
programs snatching premium seats on the Internet. Economists suggest
that, despite the rising cost of concert tickets in the primary market-
place, they are priced below profit maximizing price levels, thus opening
the door for the secondary ticket market by establishing new price
points.
2 Primary revenue streams in the music industry
Concert revenue is one of the three primary revenue streams in the
North American live music industry. In 2017, the three primary revenue
streams in the music industry accounted for over $20 billion in North
America:
North American Music Publishing Revenues: $4.3 billion (2017)
2
North American Recorded Music Revenues: $8.7 billion (2017)
3
North American Live Music/Concert Revenues: $8.0 billion (2017)
4
In North America between 2000-2016, concert tickets sales in-
creased by 330%, growing the touring industry from $1.7 to $7.3 billion,
reaching an all-time high of $8.0 billion in 2017. During that time, con-
cert ticket prices increased from an average of $40.74 to $78.93 per
ticket.
2
http://www.crossroadstoday.com/story/38138746/music-publishing-market-2018-global-trends-
market-share-industry-size-growth-opportunities-and-forecast-to-2023
3
http://www.riaa.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/RIAA-Year-End-2017-News-and-Notes.pdf
4
https://www.pollstar.com/Chart/2018/01/2017YearEndBusinessAnalysis_634.pdf
An analysis of ticket pricing 41
Figure 1: Concert ticket sales North America, 1990-2017 (Pollstar 2018).
Figure 2: Average concert ticket price North America, 1996-2017 (Pollstar 2018).
42 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
3 The rising cost of concert tickets
In a September 23, 2005 lecture, "Rockonomics: Economics and Public
Policy in the Rock and Roll Industry," economist Alan Krueger described
his study of the economic causes and effects of the rising cost of concert
tickets. Using box office information maintained by Pollstar, Krueger
determined that concert ticket prices were growing significantly higher
than the Consumer Price Index (CPI). For example, in 2005, concert tick-
et prices rose 45% faster than the CPI. Krueger found that between
1975 and 1995, concert ticket pricing increased 2% over the rate of infla-
tion, and between 1996 and 2005 concert tickets doubled. Between
2005-2017, the average price of concert tickets increased 88%, from
$42.00 to $78.93, a record high.
5
4 The price of concert tickets in the primary ticket
marketplace
Despite the rising cost of concert tickets in the United States, tickets are
considered under-priced in the primary marketplace by not achieving
their profit maximizing potential. There are three primary considera-
tions for under-pricing tickets in the primary market:
ď‚· Ticket prices are set to accommodate the sale of comple-
mentary goods (parking fees, concessions and merchan-
dise).
ď‚· Ticket prices are set to maintain the popularity of the artist
and thus not negatively affect an artists' future income.
ď‚· Demand is uncertain and ticket prices vary based on the
date of the event, the type of venue and seat availability.
5
https://www.pollstar.com/Chart/2018/01/2017YearEndBusinessAnalysis_634.pdf
An analysis of ticket pricing 43
4.1 Ticket prices and complementary goods
The promoter generally pays a 'guarantee' to the artist in advance and
pays the rest of the net revenue from the show according to a 'split rate'
after the show. The split rate for artists is usually 85-90 % of the net
profits of the concert (Passman 2015). According to Live Nation's Vice
President of Marketing Jim Steen, "85 to 90 percent of the ticket price
goes towards artist fees."
6
Fans buy T-shirts, posters or other products
as souvenirs at a concert venue and the promoter will commission mer-
chandising profit as well as ticket sales profit. On average an artist on a
major tour receives most of a ticket's face value, while promoters earn
most of their profits from ticket surcharges, parking fees, merchandise
and concessions. Michael Rapino, CEO Live Nation states, "Live Nation
earns about $4 out of every $100 ticket on the ticket price and I lose $80
million at the door every year. … Every time a consumer walks in the
door I earn $12-$14 on the ancillary business" (ancillary includes parking,
merch, concessions).
7
Sellers within the secondary ticket market gain no benefit on com-
plementary sales. Happel & Jennings (1995) claim the possible existence
of other sources of revenue such as complementary concessions sales
demonstrates one reason why concert ticket sales are priced below their
market price. Total profits are maximized when tickets are priced in the
inelastic section of the demand curve. The average ticket consumer buys
more complementary goods than the marginal ticket buyer (the one
who gets no surplus by attending the performance). Thus, promoters
increase the price of complementary goods above the marginal cost and
reduce the cost of tickets. By doing so, the promoter improves sales of
complementary goods but attracts marginal ticket buyers (Rosen &
Rosenfield 1995).
Conversely, the secondary ticket market sets prices according to
whatever secures the highest financial return because that market does
not have access to complementary profits. Economist James Swofford
compares the promoter's profit maximization problem with that of the
6
http://www.digitalmusicnews.com/stories/062811tickets
7
https://revenueanalytics.com/news/ticketonomics
44 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
reseller, suggesting that underpricing tickets in the primary market may
exist due to the promoter facing uncertainty over sales and being more
risk averse, whereas the scalper has a lower cost function. It could also
be a result of the promoter having a long-term revenue function in
mind, in contrast to the reseller maximising a one-time revenue function
(Swofford 1999).
Happel & Jennings (1995) suggest that promoters have a degree of
"monopoly power" for a live event due to its uniqueness. To maximize
profits a promoter wants a sell-out as this maximizes complementary
revenues and introduce the "crowd effect", meaning that consumers
who believe a concert will be a sell-out are more attracted to the event
and demand for tickets will intensify. According to Krueger, tickets are
set below the market clearing level to attract a larger crowd and create a
"buzz" that increases demand (Krueger 2009). This crowd effect increas-
es the sales of front row seats and private boxes. Setting the price of
certain seats low can help also to encourage demand and create a "tick-
et line". The creation of a "ticket line" when a concert is in high-demand,
with limited capacity events are part of the economic model that com-
pels ticket sales (Happel & Jennings 1995). Fans can quickly lose interest
in an artist whose performances do not meet expectations or are sus-
pected of price gouging.
4.2 Artists future income
If an artist believes the price of their ticket affects their popularity, thus
impacting future income, they will use that belief to set the price of tick-
ets. Therefore, an artist may price tickets below the market price to
maximize future profits (Byun 2008). Diamond (1982) and Swofford
(1999) argue that when artists and promoters consider their future re-
cording, tour or merchandising profits as well as their current ticket
profits, they may charge lower prices. According to Krueger, to build
loyalty from a large fan base (who will attend concerts in the future and
buy recorded music), the artist wishes to avoid being viewed as "gouging
fans" and will thus set prices below the profit maximizing level (Krueger
2005). To build long-rung popularity, the artist intends to provide fans
An analysis of ticket pricing 45
with a larger share of consumer surplus than would be the case if the
artist were simply maximizing short-run profit. With scalping, the new
middleman acts as an intermediary between the promoter and the fan,
capturing the surplus meant for the fan. Billy Joel explains it this way:
"The brokers [secondary market ticket brokers] that drive the prices
up are ripping me off because I'm not getting the money ... and they're
ripping off the customer because the customer wants the ticket and they
know that the market will bear a certain price."
If Billy Joel knows that "the market will bear a certain price," why
would he still underprice his tickets? The answer is that he wants to
maintain an image of being fair to his fans to prevent them from being
"ripped off" (Krueger 2009). On his 2017 tour, Garth Brooks set an 8-
ticket purchasing limit for the $60 ticket, which was set well below mar-
ket value. Every seat was listed at the same price, therefore the person
sitting in the front row paid the same as the person in the nose-bleed
section. Brooks performed several shows in each city to satisfy the de-
mand of fans interested to attend the tour. For example, Brooks per-
formed seven shows in Nashville at the Bridgestone Arena, five shows in
Indianapolis at Bankers Life Fieldhouse and seven shows in Kansas City
at the Sprint Center. Subsequently, he needed to perform 73 shows on
the 2017 tour to gross $101 million in box office receipts.
8
According to Fort (2003) and Krautmann & Berri (2006), concert
ticket prices do not capture the full cost of attending a concert. Artists
who set ticket prices higher would suffer revenue losses from merchan-
dise sales. Ahn & Lee (2003) suggest that if attendance is habit-forming
and fans substitution is small, artists are correct in considering non-
ticket (but attendance-dependent) revenue in setting their price while
also factoring in the effects of ticket price on future attendance. If a
lower price decreases current revenue, the act can make up for the loss
with future revenues.
8
http://www.kdlt.com/2017/07/18/garth-brooks-puts-fans-first-unique-ticket-sales-approach
46 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
4.3 Demand uncertainty
Concert ticket demand is uncertain as ticket prices vary according to the
date of the event, type of venue and seat availability. Demand may vary
in other unpredictable ways such as at outdoor sports events and con-
certs that are typically weather-dependant. The stochastic peak-load
pricing model deals with situations of aggregate demand uncertainty
(Crew, Frenando & Kleindorfer 1995). Aggregate demand uncertainty
occurs when demand depends on the weather whereas individual de-
mand uncertainty occurs because many consumers are not able to plan
ahead of time. Some consumers only buy their tickets at the last minute
when they are sure that they will be able to attend. Demand uncertain-
ty alone does not distinguish ticket markets from markets for other
goods and services. What makes this feature crucial is that tickets are
perishable goods and lose all value after the performance starts. In the-
ory, promoters could satisfy periods of high demand by holding large
inventories of seats as is typically done in many other industries. Be-
cause tickets are highly perishable goods, however, the costs of holding
large inventories can be quite high. Producers respond to these con-
straints by choosing venue capacities that may turn out to be too small
in some markets. Consequently, capacity constraints may bind, which is
illustrated by some performances selling out in minutes.
Supply for concert tickets is limited due to the fixed number of tick-
ets available. The size of venue chosen to host the performance: club,
theatre, large theatre, arena, amphitheatre and stadium are all determi-
nant factors of supply by the promoter and artist. Some artists select a
venue to deliver intimacy to the ticket holder while a smaller show will
create excess demand and a market shortage. For example, in 2000, Paul
Simon toured the US playing in theatres (capacity 1,000) as promotion
for a new album release, "You're the One". Simon could have performed
at 2,500 to 5,000 capacity venues on this US tour. This is considered an
"underplay" in the concert industry as Simon underestimated the venue
capacity to create intimacy at the performance thereby creating a short-
age of supply in the marketplace.
An analysis of ticket pricing 47
Not all tickets are sold to the public, some tickets are held back from
sale to the public by the primary market. These tickets, referred to as
"holds" may go to news media, artist, managers, agents, the record
company, the fan club, the promoter and the tour sponsor. A few years
ago, an investigative team in Nashville unearthed the "holds" list for a
Taylor Swift show at the Bridgestone Arena, a venue with a capacity of
13,330 seats. After Swift's fan club, management, agents, record label
and opening acts' ticket allocation; after a radio-sponsored presale; and
after American Express card members had access to a presale, only
1,591 tickets were made available to the public.
9
Figure 3: Taylor Swift ticket allocation (NPR, June 2012).
The practice of "holds" is common at popular arena gigs and takes
place on a smaller scale at theatres and clubs. Seating location or type of
section (front row vs. nose bleeds) and how many days a ticket is pur-
chased before the date of the show are also important determinants of
demand and profit margin for promoters. Industry professionals refer to
"scaling the house" as the process of pricing the front rows (referred to
as the 'golden circle') at high prices and reducing prices all the way to
the nosebleed section. The practice of scaling the house varies from
performance to performance. Scaled seating arrangements were com-
9
http://www.npr.org/blogs/therecord/2012/06/04/154299904/theres-no-such-thing-as-a-sold-out-
concert-even-for-justin-bieber
48 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
monly employed at reserved seat rock shows during the sixties, but dis-
appeared for the more youthful pop scene, when promoters introduced
general admission tickets in the mid-seventies. Since the late eighties,
however, house-scaled seating arrangements were the blue print for
pop concerts (Giblin & Chadwell 1994). Artist fees can be covered with
highest price premium seats allowing for the rest of the house to be
more reasonably priced. For the Rolling Stones Bigger Bang Tour in 1996
top tiered seats went for $250-$500 per ticket. However, 50% of first 15
rows sold in secondary market. Ticket brokers rescale the house "15-
20% of best seats are empirically worth more than face value" (Waddell
2007). Jeff Fluhr, Co-CEO of StubHub says "[there are] over 1,000 ticket
brokers in the country, taking inventory off the hands of promoters."
Since the pricing model of promoters and artists is not to optimise
profits through ticket sales alone, Connolly & Krueger (2006: 676) state
that "this pricing results in excess demand for many concert performanc-
es, which leads to scalping". Live music is one of the few businesses in
which second-hand goods often sell for more than first hand goods. "As
soon as a show sells out, front-row seats appear on the web for more
than face value," says Rob Hallett of AEG Live (The Economist 2005).
Popular music concert tickets ordinarily resell at prices well above their
face values. For example, $39.50 tickets for Nickelback, a popular rock
band, concerts were traded at around $120 in the resale ticket market
(Byun 2008).
Primary ticket market outlets like Ticketmaster have tried to seize
some of the sales revenue of the secondary market by creating their
own ticket exchanges (Tickets Now), but this often confuses consumers
and creates buyer mistrust. It is not easy for a seller to take advantage
of both the primary and the secondary market. According to former
Ticketmaster CEO Nathan Hubbard:
"The resale market exists because ticket pricing is not perfectly effi-
cient; supply and demand change over time and some fans wait until the
last minute to make the decision as to if they can go to an event. The
local ticket brokerage model has been built on this, providing services for
An analysis of ticket pricing 49
niche groups of customers who seek unique experiences at various price
points that the market will bear at any given time."
10
5 The secondary ticket marketplace
In the past, many concert enthusiasts had to wait in line at a box office
for hours prior to tickets going on sale to ensure they could secure a
concert ticket. In 2009, StubHub revolutionized the way consumers pur-
chased tickets in the secondary market and its platform StubHub.com
was the first major online secondary ticket agent selling tickets exclu-
sively on-line as a ticket reseller. Since StubHub entered the secondary
ticket marketplace, secondary ticketing has grown into a multi-billion-
dollar industry that allows consumers to access ticket discounts or sold
out concerts (Harrington 2012). One-third of all popular concert tickets
are purchased in the secondary ticket market (Krueger 2008) and the
secondary ticket market has grown to a $15 billion-dollar industry with
thousands of ticket resellers on-line. The key sellers for this market are
StubHub.com and TicketsNow.com (Harrington 2012).
5.1 Secondary ticket market technology - "BOTS"
Some of these ticket resellers purchase tickets from the primary market
using technology to acquire large quantities of the best seats within sec-
onds of the tickets going on sale on the primary market. These "BOTS"
are computer programs that can acquire large amounts of tickets auto-
matically without human intervention (Harrington 2012). This process
bypasses the human consumer who selects a seat and then enters in
payment information through the traditional method within the primary
market. The "BOTS" in the secondary ticket market essentially remove
the supply of tickets from the typical fan or consumer resulting in a sell-
out of tickets. An example of this process was the Justin Bieber North
American tour which sold out in less than one hour at rate of more than
1,000 tickets per second (Ganz 2012).
10
Ticketmaster.com blog, 2011.
50 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
5.2 Secondary ticket market pros and cons
Advantages of the secondary ticket market includes the consumer's abil-
ity to obtain access to sold out concerts and the market becomes a one
stop shop for all sport games, concert and other events (Burgess 2012).
Brokers may be good also for social surplus because they add liquidity to
the market (Leslie & Sorenson 2007). However, the secondary ticket
market has downsides in that brokers extract surplus for themselves,
reducing surplus available to the consumers and subsequently consum-
ers are worse off (ibid.). Ticket prices on the secondary market are sub-
ject to change as ticket prices can escalate and a discount may not be
obtainable (Burgess 2012). Websites in the secondary market also do
not provide any insight to the consumer on future price movements
(ibid.). In other words, the consumer is subject to the laws of supply and
demand in the secondary market. According to Leslie & Sorenson (2007),
seat quality is the key determinant of prices in both the primary and
secondary markets as resale prices vary significantly according to seat
quality. This is especially true for about twenty percent of the highest
quality seats, where resale prices are a particular determinant of seat
quality. However, consumers cannot evaluate the quality of the ticket
prior to purchase nor judge for themselves if the ticket is a fair price for
the seat location. Leslie & Sorenson (2007) cite numerous instances of
low-quality seats resold at a higher price than a higher quality seat (for a
given event) in their research on the secondary market. This is basic
evidence of inefficiencies in the resale market, where on the one hand,
the resale market allows price to be a more flexible function of seat
quality but on the other hand, some friction in the resale market causes
significant variance in price, conditional on seat quality. SeatGeek.com
is a website that offers the consumer the ability to compare multiple
secondary ticket market websites (Burgess 2012) to determine the best
ticket deal based on seat location and price.
5.3 Ticket prices in the secondary market
The primary ticket marketplace drives most of its revenue from compli-
mentary goods and therefore has created a market for alternatives that
An analysis of ticket pricing 51
maximize profit on ticket sales (Krueger 2008). As a result, consumers
are unable to purchase tickets at face value on the primary market, so
for consumers to purchase concert tickets, they must utilise the second-
ary ticket market and pay the true market value price of the ticket.
There are three major reasons that may determine the new market val-
ue price of a ticket on the secondary market. Firstly, consumers are
willing to purchase higher price tickets from reliable websites such as
StubHub or TicketsNow but are less likely to purchase tickets from
Craigslist or a street scalper because they are considered higher risk and
often do not run official businesses (Chan, Mathew & Ruggie 2009).
Secondly, consumers are afraid tickets will not be available in the
future, so they buy tickets early when prices are high (Chan 2009).
Thirdly, the supply of the tickets has been dramatically reduced to
only a few tickets per concert. This will drive up the price since they are
capturing the limited number of people willing to pay a price higher than
face value. The secondary market premium is higher for superstar per-
formers who charge the highest prices and tend to sell out in the prima-
ry market (Krueger 2009).
5.4 Superstar concerts survey
A survey was conducted by Princeton Survey Research Center on two
superstar concerts. The first event was a Bruce Springsteen and the E
Street Band "The Rising" tour date at the First Union Center (now Wells
Fargo Center) in Philadelphia on October 6, 2002 and the second was a
U2 "Vertigo" show at the Madison Square Garden in New York City on
November 22, 2005 (Krueger 2008). A total of 858 fans were inter-
viewed for the survey, which revealed that thirty percent (30%) of the
tickets were sold on the secondary market. The average face value price
of the ticket was $94 while the average ticket purchase price for the
secondary market was $245 (ibid.)
52 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
Figure 4: Primary vs. secondary market ticket price survey (Krueger 2008).
The mark up for the secondary market was 240% above face value
from the primary market. The Princeton Survey Research Center also
conducted a natural survey with a total of 300,000 consumers at 1,068
concerts interviewed for the poll. It was determined that 10% of the
tickets were obtained on the secondary market (Krueger 2008). The
average face value ticket was $81 and the average mark-up 36%, while
the average ticket purchase price for the secondary market was $122
(ibid.). Popular artists can demand higher prices on the secondary mar-
ket.
5.5 Secondary ticket market – consumer uncertainty
In a survey by Sorenson & Leslie (2007), the average mark-up in the sec-
ondary ticket marketplace was 40% over face value and 25% of resold
tickets obtained mark-ups above 66%. The downside for resellers
showed that 28% of tickets were sold below face value and 50% of re-
sale transactions occurred within 24 days of the event in the secondary
market. The consumer was not only uncertain about prices in the resale
An analysis of ticket pricing 53
market, they were also uncertain about which ticket (if any) they would
be able to buy in the resale market.
5.6 Timing of ticket sales
The price of secondary market tickets falls as the concert date ap-
proaches, because the tickets are a perishable good (Chan, Mathew &
Ruggie 2009). As time passes, the challenge of finding a buyer to pur-
chase a ticket well above face value increases, therefore sellers have to
drop their prices to find a buyer, otherwise, the ticket is worth nothing
(ibid.). The strategy for the secondary ticket market seller is to start with
a high price, peak about nine to ten days prior to the concert and drop
the price below face value, which increases the number of willing buyers
(ibid.). Some of the lowest price tickets can be found within one hour of
the concert because the reseller needs to unload the ticket (ibid.).
5.7 SeatGeek and the secondary ticket market
The website SeatGeek.com provides consumers with comparison infor-
mation to determine if a ticket on the secondary market is a good value
(Harrington 2012). This website, like Kayak within the airline industry,
gathers ticket prices and seat location on many secondary ticket market
websites; it has developed an algorithm to predict the price of the ticket
based on three variables: the quantity of supplied tickets on the second
ticket market, the location of the seat and the popularity of the concert.
SeatGeek compares the asking price of each of ticket to the predicted
price and assigns a "deal ranking".
54 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
Figure 5: SeatGeek Deal Score (Harrington 2012).
SeatGeek sorts the tickets by their "deal" score which reflects the
gap between the asking price and the predicted market price (Harring-
ton 2012). If there are only one or two seats for sale on the secondary
ticket market, the predicted price will be higher than if fifty or sixty are
for sale for the same show. SeatGeek allows consumers to purchase
concert tickets without assuming a high-priced ticket is the only availa-
ble option. SeatGeek also makes the demand for listing (resell) tickets
more elastic (Harrington 2012). Although many consumers purchase
tickets exclusively at StubHub which dominates the secondary ticket
market with a 25% share, SeatGeek allows smaller secondary ticket mar-
ket sellers with less popularity than StubHub to gain visibility to con-
sumers, which forces StubHub to keep their prices and fees aligned with
the price of the ticket market (ibid.).
An analysis of ticket pricing 55
6 Proposed solutions for the primary ticket market to
compete with the secondary market
Secondary ticket legislation has been prominent for the past hundred
years. In 1927, the United States Supreme court upheld a law forbidding
the resale of tickets at more than fifty cents in excess of the face price of
a ticket (W.F.D, 1927, The Yale Law Journal Review). Despite this
judgement, the presiding Supreme Court Justice Sutherland stated that
"ticket scalpers may not be controlled." Ticket scalping has evolved over
the course of the past century; from individual sellers outside of arenas
and stadiums to on-line resellers. The secondary ticket has grown to a
multi-billion-dollar industry and has been met with opposition from var-
ious organizations including the government and primary ticket market-
place sellers.
The current laws around scalping are inconsistent and cannot
achieve industry compliance. Anti-scalping laws vary from state to state
given there is no federal law that prohibits the resale of concert tickets.
Gaining access to tickets, the cost of distribution and fraud are the key
challenges that preoccupy regulators (Vascellaro 2005). Massachusetts'
ticket resale law allows a maximum ticket mark-up of only two dollars
(ibid.), while Pennsylvania allows brokers to resell tickets with a maxi-
mum mark-up price of twenty-five percent. New York, Connecticut and
Minnesota require a resale license, a fee that is paid to the state. Over
time, state laws have recognised the benefits of ticket resales and
amended ticket legislation to improve the economic wealth of the state.
The barriers to entry in the secondary ticket market have evolved
beyond state legislation. In 2007, Ticketmaster filed a lawsuit against
eBay and named StubHub the subsidiary of eBay as a co-defendant. The
suit primarily focused on the profit of sales that StubHub gained for a
Lynyrd Skynyrd/Hank Williams Jr. "Rowdy Frynds" tour. A Wall Street
Journal article explains that StubHub violated Ticketmaster's exclusive
right to sell tickets to events at the venues on the tour, including the
Conseco Fieldhouse in Indianapolis and the Palace of Auburn Hills, Mich-
igan.
56 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
6.1 Paperless ticketing
Primary ticker sellers have attempted to circumvent the secondary mar-
ket through paperless ticketing technology, which acts as a tool to en-
sure that the individual attending the event is the same person who
purchased the ticket from the primary market. The ticket purchaser is
required to show identification at the ticket window of the event, mean-
ing the secondary ticket reseller cannot re-sell tickets from the primary
ticket marketplace. In 2009, Miley Cyrus offered a paperless ticket as the
only option for her tour (eliminating the ability of the secondary market
to gain access to resell tickets for the tour) and Don Vaccaro, CEO of
StubHub, claimed that paperless ticketing violated antitrust laws.
The Live Nation/Ticketmaster platform Verified Fan is an attempt to
circumvent secondary ticket sales. Vulture.com states:
"In March 2017, Live Nation and Ticketmaster announced their Veri-
fied Fan presale technology where fans can register ahead of sale dates
by providing personal information that's vetted by the companies. Fans
receive a code that allows them to purchase tickets and beat the scalpers
at their own game. To date, more than one million users have registered
for Verified Fan services. … In addition to partnering with acts like the
1975 and Ed Sheeran, Live Nation/Ticketmaster most recently promoted
shows with Twenty One Pilots for five homecoming dates in Columbus,
Ohio, taking place at venues of varying sizes between June 20 and 25,
2017, all of them sold out. The spill over to the secondary market was
almost non-existent by industry standards, as there were no tickets
available for the first three shows on StubHub, and, according to Live
Nation/Ticketmaster, the subsequent pair of shows had resales on the
secondary market of just 4.1 percent and 3.7 percent. As at the date of
the article, available options hovered around 350 tickets per show at
arenas that seated up to 18,500 patrons. By using the Verified Fan pro-
gram, the company had reduced scalping on the secondary market by 90
percent."
11
11
http://www.vulture.com/2017/05/everyone-wants-concert-tickets-but-no-one-is-getting-
them.html
An analysis of ticket pricing 57
According to Live Nation CEO Michael Rapino: "Music has account-
ed for about 80% of Ticketmaster's growth in recent years, making it
imperative for us to extend our focus from venues to those artists who
are filling the venues." He estimates that 80 artists utilized Ticketmas-
ter's Verified Fan platform, selling 3 million tickets.
12
The verified fan platform has not been without issues. Digital Music
News wrote in January 2018 about "a serious misfire on Swift's 'Verified
Fan' program." That program gave priority access to certain Taylor Swift
fans. Fans were required to build up points — oftentimes by purchasing
Taylor Swift products including purchases of Swift's latest album, a snake
bracelet and more which theoretically gave fans priority access. Once
tickets went on sale, however, that prioritization seemed spotty. Some
"prioritized" fans got lucky, but many others were left waiting. Most
were given 'special access' to high-priced tickets, while others were
forced into the general sales bucket a few days later. Of course, none of
that went over well with fans — or their parents. As a result, Digital Mu-
sic News headlined: "Taylor Swift's 'Reputation' Tour is a Flop: Half-Filled
Stadiums, Thousands of Unsold Seats, 0 Sellouts."
13
6.2 Dynamic pricing
Dynamic pricing, also known as time-based pricing, is one method of
price discrimination and is the practice of charging different prices to
different consumers for similar goods thus dividing customers into two
or more groups with separate demand curves and different prices
charged to each group. When successful price discrimination can in-
crease the firm's profits by enabling it to capture consumer surplus. This
is part of the seller's aim to capture what economists label "consumer
surplus" – the difference between what a consumer is willing to pay for
a good and the amount they must pay. The price that a consumer is will-
ing to pay is the "reservation price". The secondary ticket marketplace
has thrived on the concept of dynamic pricing.
12
https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/8221386/live-nation-104-billion-record-revenue-
2017-q4-earnings-drop-report
13
https://www.digitalmusicnews.com/2018/01/02/taylor-swift-reputation-tour-flop
58 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
Today, internet-based companies can gather large amounts of con-
sumer information through click loggers, ad sites, and search engines
operating in many common web functions. Now primary market ticket
sellers can compete with the secondary market and utilize dynamic pric-
ing whereas in the past it was more difficult for primary markets ticket
sellers to judge individual consumers' reservation prices. Price discrimi-
nation is more about separating consumers into groups than aiming at
individual consumers. Essentially the process of dynamic pricing is one
of "price discovery" where the buyer and seller actively engage in activi-
ties that identify the exact highest amount that the consumer would pay
for the good before walking away, therefore capturing the entire con-
sumer surplus.
Zach Cross, VP Revenue Analytics states "Understanding customer
buying patterns allows companies to develop price points that meet the
needs of price-sensitive customers, the key is making sure you do not
displace the high paying demand". It is possible for 75% of revenue to be
derived from 25% of seats, sourcing VIP packages + Premium Seats.
14
The key is demand forecasting by sourcing variables such as genre, ven-
ue, event, section, row and customer segment as well as making optimal
inventory allocation decisions. Bill Zysblat of RZO Productions says, "The
idea is to have exactly one person wanting a ticket at every sold-out
show". Dynamic Pricing can significantly improve ticket sale volume for
events where interest is low and reduce the number of tickets resold on
the secondary market. According to Billboard
"the sales for JAY-Z's 4:44 Tour represents a paradigm shift in con-
cert tickets, by aggressively pricing front row seats, VIP experiences and
platinum tickets, concert promoters are getting increasingly more skilled
at commanding high prices and record grosses from their best seating
inventory. … That's bad news for ticket resellers — by pricing tickets clos-
14
https://revenueanalytics.com/news/ticketonomics
An analysis of ticket pricing 59
er to actual market value, JAY-Z and Live Nation are capturing more rev-
enue and creating little room for brokers to mark up the best seats."
15
Ticketmaster has recently rolled out dynamic ticket pricing to adjust
prices of available tickets based on sales and other metrics pertaining to
demand such as StubHub prices, artist popularity and days until the
event. They have established that dynamic pricing is a group pricing ac-
tivity.
In order to understand the effects dynamic pricing has on price,
Kauffman & Wang (2001) stated: "Even though different functional
forms have been proposed for the demand-price relationship, there is a
consensus that at the aggregate level demand for a product decreases as
the price increases under both monopoly and competitive settings." As a
result, we expect that there will be a high demand when the price drops
in the group-buying context. The former is a movement along a single
demand curve. The latter emphasizes the role of expectations in deci-
sion-making and exists by the construction of the group-buying market
microstructure. Demand externalities are realised through the upward
shift of the demand curve due to potential adopters' high willingness-to-
pay. As a result, in the context of group-buying, a price effect is reflect-
ed in an increase in orders due to a price drop, while demand externali-
ties are associated with the current group size. Thus, when the current
group size increases, demand externalities capture the fact that poten-
tial buyers are more likely to place an order due to the expected larger
final group size, even though the current price remains the same. With
this behaviour in mind they anticipate that when a buyer develops an
expectation that the price will drop in the near future, they expect that
the likelihood of purchasing the product will increase in a group buying
setting.
In the short run, because the price will only drop to the next lower
price-tier, a consumer will only be motivated to make a purchase when
the reservation price is less than the current price but greater than or
equal to the next lower one. In this case, when the price drops to the
15
https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/8023168/jay-z-444-tour-highest-grossing-tickets-
stubhub
60 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
next level, which is no greater than the reservation price, the consumer
will get a non-negative surplus from this purchase. In the group-buying
setting, when an individual perceives that the price is likely to drop to
the reservation price or lower – and the purchase action can facilitate
this process – the consumer is more likely to place the order if the con-
sumer is risk-seeking. By contrast, a risk-averse person may wait until
the price changes to make the purchase, even if the consumer expected
that the price would change. As a result, they expect more orders to be
placed right before and right after the price drop point.
Artists are also offering dynamic ticket pricing for concerts through
to the primary ticket marketplace. Wilco partnered with concert pro-
moter Higher Ground to offer tickets for a concert sold through a unique
combination of "name your own price" auction and lottery. The first 500
tickets were sold to bidders who make the highest offers. Those cus-
tomers whose bid did not score one of the first 500 tickets were part of
an exclusive random lottery. Bidders drawn from a hat were offered the
opportunity to purchase a pair of tickets at whatever price they named
on their original bid. "It's an experiment, which we hope proves to be
more civilized, fair, and more fun than the standard mode of ticket
sales," said director Joseph Thompson.
16
A case study by McAfee & Vera te Velde (2007) of the California In-
stitute of Technology researched dynamic pricing in the airline industry.
They classified dynamic pricing as a revenue yield/revenue management
tool, a set of pricing strategies aimed at increasing profits. Most yield
management research deals with how to maximize revenue. One ap-
proach is to assume that customers arrive to request a flight, state the
price they will pay, and then the firm decides if to serve them. As you
see the interaction between seller and buyer in the airline industry uti-
lizes a system of "Price Discovery". Although this is the broad theory the
pricing tools are adjusted to ensure maximum profitability. According to
McAfee & Vera te Velde (2007: 4), one variance is that "within the airline
industry rather than dynamically changing prices to maximize revenue,
16
http://www.hypebot.com/hypebot/2012/04/jeff-tweedy-wilco-experiment-with-dynamic-
concert-ticket-prices.html
An analysis of ticket pricing 61
some authors ration capacity with price classes to ensure that high-
paying customers are served, effectively implementing a mark-up policy
based on remaining capacity and if seat allocation between classes is
dynamically controlled, remaining time." This can be accomplished by
classifying the high-paying customers as a separate group hence ac-
counting for their needs and utilizing price discover tools on this group
separately. The same rule follows through for the economy class travel-
lers this method enables the industry to capture the entire consumer
surplus. Thus, the conclusion from the research stating; "dynamic price
discrimination is primarily driven by customer dynamics rather than price
discrimination over an existing set of customers" (ibid.: 33). Dynamic
pricing of concert ticket pricing is receiving increasing attention in the
industry today because it holds the potential to significantly improve the
ticket sale volume for events where interest is low. Secondly, the im-
plantation of dynamic pricing will reduce the number of tickets resold on
the secondary market. As adjustments are made on the primary market
utilizing consumer information and behaviour to adjust the price on the
primary market more efficiently the secondary market may be rendered
obsolete. Randy Phillips, CEO of AEG Live states it best, "dynamic pricing
puts the fan on an even playing field with the broker, in terms of access
to the best seats in the house, where the market more than greed de-
termines the price of a ticket. It's the ultimate example of laissez-faire
economics at work" (Waddell 2007).
7 Conclusion
Despite the rising costs of concert tickets in the US over the past fifteen
years, concert tickets prices in the primary ticket marketplace are not
optimized for profit maximization. The three main reasons for not meet-
ing the profit maximizing price point are the benefit of sales from com-
plimentary goods, the artist not gouging the fan to enhance future con-
cert ticket sales and demand uncertainty. Under-priced concert tickets
create opportunities for the secondary market to re-establish the mar-
ket price. Tickets sold on the secondary market are impacted by several
62 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
factors: access to best seats, the popularity of the artist and the timing
and date of the event. Solutions to battle scalping include legislation,
technological advances and dynamic ticket pricing. Dynamic pricing
assists the primary market in establishing a profit maximizing ticket
price, providing an opportunity to sell tickets at variable prices based on
the aggregate demand and lessens the impact of tickets sold in the sec-
ondary marketplace.
8 References
Ahn, S. C. & Young, H. L. (2003) Life-Cycle Demand for Major League Baseball, Working
Paper, July 2003.
Bergman, B. (2012) "Game on: Secondary ticket sellers score | Different philosophies,
similar goals put two CT entrepreneurs on fast track", Hartford Business.com, last modi-
fied 1 June 2012. Available at
http://www.hartfordbusiness.com/article/20110328/PRINTEDITION/303289982/game-
on-secondary-ticket-sellers-score--different-philosophies-similar-goals-put-two-ct-
entrepreneurs-on-fast-track (11 April 2019).
Brooks, D. (2017) "Why JAY-Z's 4:44 Tour Will Be His Highest Grossing Solo Run Ever
Despite Cheap Tickets on StubHub", Billboard, 6 November. Available at
https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/8023168/jay-z-444-tour-highest-grossing-
tickets-stubhub (11 April 2019).
Brooks, D. (2018) "Live Nation Posts $10.4B Record Revenues in 2017, Q4 Earnings Drop
Following Songkick Settlement", Billboard, 7 February. Available at
https://www.billboard.com/articles/business/8221386/live-nation-104-billion-record-
revenue-2017-q4-earnings-drop-report (11 April 2019).
Burgess, C. (2017) "Guide to The Secondary Ticketing Market", SeatGeek, March 2017.
Available at: https://seatgeek.com/tba/articles/secondary-ticket-market-and-resellers/
(11 April 2019).
Byun, H. W. (2008) "Empirical Studies of Microeconomic Agents' Behavior", doctoral
dissertation, Pennsylvania State University, 2008.
Chan, T., Anju M. & Ruggie, A. (2009) "Dynamic Pricing in the Secondary Ticket Market",
2BL.ORG, 19 June 2009. Available at: http://gettogreen.blogspot.com/2009/06/dynamic-
pricing-in-secondary-concert.html (11 April 2019).
An analysis of ticket pricing 63
Connolly, M. & Krueger, A. B. (2006) "Rockonomics: The Economics of Popular Music", in
Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, vol. 1, eds. V. A. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby,
North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 667-719.
Crew, M. A., Chitru S. F. & Kleindorfer, P. R. (1995) "The Theory of Peak-load Pricing: A
Survey", Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 8, no. 3, pp. 215-248.
https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01070807.
Diamond, T. A. (1982) "Ticket Scalping: A New Look at an Old Problem", University of
Miami Law Review, vol. 37, pp. 71-92.
Fort, R. (2004) "Inelastic Sports Pricing", Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 25, no.
2, pp. 87-94. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1108.
Friedlander, J. P. 2018, News and Notes on 2017 RIAA Revenue Statistics. Available at:
http://www.riaa.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/RIAA-Year-End-2017-News-and-
Notes.pdf (11 April 2019).
Ganz, J. (2012) "There's No Such Thing As A Sold Out Concert (Even For Justin Bieber)",
NPR Music, 4 June 2012. Available at:
https://www.npr.org/sections/therecord/2012/06/04/154299904/theres-no-such-thing-
as-a-sold-out-concert-even-for-justin-bieber (11 April 2019).
Giblin, P. & Chadwell, T. (1994) "Rock Concert Costs Boom for Boomers: Eagles Take it to
the Limit on Ticket Price", Business Journal-Phoenix, vol. 14, no. 32.
Happel, S. K. & Jennings, M. M. (1995) "The Folly of Anti-Scalping Laws", The Cato Jour-
nal, vol. 15, no. 1, pp. 65-80. Available at: http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/cj15n1-
4.html (11 April 2019).
Harrington, D. E. & Harrington, E. K. "Scalping Scalpers--or Consumers? The Proposed
BOSS Act Threatens the Consumer-friendly Evolution of Secondary Ticket Markets",
Regulation, vol. 35, no. 3, pp. 18-25.
Horowitz, S. J. (2017) "The Concert Ticket Industry Is Still Broken", Vulture.com, 2 May.
Available at: http://www.vulture.com/2017/05/everyone-wants-concert-tickets-but-no-
one-is-getting-them.html (11 April 2019).
Houghton, B. (2012) "Jeff Tweedy & Wilco Experiment with Dynamic Concert Ticket
Prices", Hypobot.com, 10 April. Available at:
http://www.hypebot.com/hypebot/2012/04/jeff-tweedy-wilco-experiment-with-
dynamic-concert-ticket-prices.html (11 April 2019).
Hubbard, N. (2011) "Open Letter to Fans and Partners on Ticket Reselling", Ticketmas-
ter.com, August 2011. No longer available.
Karp, L. & Perloff J. M. (2005) "When Promoters Like Scalpers", Journal of Economics &
Management Strategy, vol. 14, no. 2, pp. 477-508.
64 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
Kauffman, R. J. & Wang B. (2001) "New Buyers' Arrival Under Dynamic Pricing Market
Microstructure: The Case of Group-Buying Discounts on the Internet", Journal of Man-
agement Information Systems, vol. 18, no. 2, pp. 157-188.
Krautmann, A. C. & Berri, D. J. (2007) "Can We Find It at the Concessions? Understanding
Price Elasticity in Professional Sports", Journal of Sports Economics, vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 183-
191. https://doi.org/10.1177/1527002505275093.
Krueger, A. B. & Connolly, M. (2008) "Evidence on the Secondary Market for Concert
Tickets", Working paper, May 29, 2008. Available at:
http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.313.9567&rep=rep1&type=p
df (11 April 2019).
Krueger, A. B. & Connolly, M. (2005) Rockonomics: The Economics of Popular Music,
NBER Working Paper Series 11282. Available at:
http://www.nber.org.ezproxy.neu.edu/papers/w11282 (11 April 2019).
Leslie, P. & Sorensen, A. T. (2007) The Welfare Effects of Ticket Resale, NBER Working
Paper Series 15476. Available at:
https://www.ssc.wisc.edu/~sorensen/papers/resale_november_2007.pdf (11 April
2019).
Lynch, J. (2015) "Check Out These Surprising Stats About U.S. Music Festivals", Billboard,
22 April. Available at: https://www.billboard.com/articles/columns/music-
festivals/6539009/music-festival-statistics-graphic (11 April 2019).
Macleod, D. (2012) "$uperscalp Sandy Outrage", Newyorkpost.com, 7 December. Availa-
ble at: https://nypost.com/2012/12/07/uperscalp-sandy-outrage/ (11 April 2019).
McAfee R. P. & te Velde, V. (2007) "Dynamic Pricing in the Airline Industry", California
Institute of Technology working paper. Available at:
https://vita.mcafee.cc/PDF/DynamicPriceDiscrimination.pdf (11 April 2019).
Passman, D. S. (2015) All You Need to Know About the Music Business, 9
th
edition, Simon
& Schuster, New York.
Pollstar (2017) 2017 Pollstar Year End Business Analysis. Available at:
https://www.pollstar.com/Chart/2018/01/2017YearEndBusinessAnalysis_634.pdf (11
April 2019).
Resnikoff, P. (2011) "Live Nation: 90% of a Ticket Price Goes to Artist Fees…", Digital
Music News, 28 June. Available at:
https://www.digitalmusicnews.com/2011/06/28/ticketprice/ (11 April 2019).
Rosen, S. & Rosenfield, A. (1995) "Ticket Pricing", George G. Stigler Center for Study of
Economy and State, working paper no. 120, University of Chicago.
An analysis of ticket pricing 65
Rosen, S. & Rosenfield, A. (1997) "Ticket Pricing", Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 40,
no. 2, pp. 351-76.
Sisario, B. (2012) "Full Album Sales Showed a Little Growth in 2011", New York Times, 4
January. Available at: https://www.nytimes.com/2012/01/05/business/media/complete-
album-sales-showed-slight-growth-in-2011.html (11 April 2019).
Swofford, J. L. (1999) "Arbitrage, Speculation, and Public Policy Toward Ticket Scalping",
Public Finance Review, vol. 27, no. 5, pp. 531-540.
https://doi.org/10.1177/109114219902700504.
The Economist (2011) "Pricing the Piper; Live Music (The Trouble with Live Music)", US
print version, no. 8717, p. 79.
Toay, A. (2017) "Garth Brooks Puts Fans First with Unique Ticket Sales Approach", KDLT
News, 18 July. Available at: https://www.kdlt.com/2017/07/18/garth-brooks-puts-fans-
first-unique-ticket-sales-approach/. (11 April 2019).
Vascellaro, J. E. (2005) "Scoring World Series Tickets Gets Easier, New Laws Loosen Re-
strictions on Reselling Over the Internet; A Timely Change for Sox Fans", Wall Street
Journal, 20 October. Available at:
https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB112976871662973892 (11 April 2019).
Vie, R. (2010) "Who Sets the Prices for Concert Tickets?", The Rock and Roll Guru, March
15. Available at: http://rockandrollguru.blogspot.com/2010/03/who-sets-prices-for-
concert-tickets.html (11 April 2019).
Waddell, R. (2009) "Miley Strikes Back", Billboard, 27 June, pp. 7-8. Available at:
https://books.google.com/books?id=48SZ4YlqhgEC&pg=PT6&lpg=PT6&dq=ray+waddell+
june+27+2009&source=bl&ots=aOOCTh3IUa&sig=Zs-
Mx3ifr7n6WLWspIZYjwtAQyI&hl=en&sa=X&ved=2ahUKEwj3p5_l3b_dAhWGct8KHfwGD
oQQ6AEwAnoECAgQAQ#v=onepage&q=ray%20waddell%20june%2027%202009&f=false
(11 April 2019).
Waddell, R. (2006) "What Am I Bid?", Billboard, 4 March, p. 25.
https://books.google.com/books?id=4xQEAAAAMBAJ&pg=PA25&lpg=PA25&dq=%22dyn
am-
ic+pricing+puts+the+fan+on+an+even+playing+field+with+the+broker%22&source=bl&o
ts=M_lSnr1C1S&sig=gSN2ybyC2c887P1gP-hU-
G8SNKA&hl=en&sa=X&ved=2ahUKEwjHt6Xr37_dAhXMmOAKHa6RA3QQ6AEwAHoECAA
QAQ#v=onepage&q=%22dynamic%20pricing%20puts%20the%20fan%20on%20an%20ev
en%20playing%20field%20with%20the%20broker%22&f=false (11 April 2019).
Waddell, R. D., Barnet, R. & Berry, J. (2007) This Business of Concert Promotion and
Touring: A Practical Guide to Creating, Selling, Organizing, and Staging Concerts, Bill-
board Books, New York.
66 International Journal of Music Business Research, April 2019, vol. 8 no. 1
W. F. D. (1927), "Ticket Scalping and Due Process of Law", The Yale Law Journal, vol. 36,
no. 7, pp. 985-88.