Florida State University Libraries
Electronic Theses, Treatises and Dissertations The Graduate School
2008
Conditional and Unconditional
Conservatism Following a Financial
Reporting Failure: An Empirical Study
William Delton LaGore
Follow this and additional works at the FSU Digital Library. For more information, please contact [email protected]
FLORIDA STATE UNIVERSITY
COLLEGE OF BUSINESS
CONDITIONAL AND UNCONDITIONAL CONSERVATISM FOLLOWING A
FINANCIAL REPORTING FAILURE: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY
By
WILLIAM DELTON LAGORE
A Dissertation submitted to the
Department of Accounting
in partial fulfillment of the
requirements for the degree of
Doctor of Philosophy
Degree Awarded:
Spring Semester, 2008
The members of the Committee approve the dissertation of William Delton LaGore
defended on January 11, 2008.
__________________________
Richard Morton
Professor Directing Dissertation
__________________________
Gary Benesh
Outside Committee Member
__________________________
Bok Baik
Committee Member
__________________________
Bruce Billings
Committee Member
Approved:
_________________________________________
Caryn L. Beck-Dudley, Dean, College of Business
The Office of Graduate Studies has verified and approved the above named committee
members.
ii
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
I thank and acknowledge God from whom all blessings flow.
I thank my mother and grandparents who have always believed in me, encouraged me
and supported me my entire life. I thank my father for his support and help during my
time at Florida State.
I thank the members of my dissertation committee, Rick Morton (Chair), Bruce
Billings, Bok Baik, and Gary Benesh. You have given me invaluable guidance and
assistance throughout this project and during my time at Florida State.
I especially want to acknowledge my chairman, Dr. Rick Morton, for his invaluable
guidance and assistance. Thank you very much for always being there to help and guide
me through this process.
I thank Rose McGorey for her research assistance in collecting data. I want to thank
Linwood Kearney and my fellow doctoral students for their friendship and
encouragement throughout this lengthy process.
Finally, I would like to thank the faculty members, Nancy LaPorte and Donna
Arnold, the accounting department, the College of Business, and the many people at
Florida State University for giving me the opportunity and assistance to earn a Ph.D.
from Florida State University.
iii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
LIST OF TABLES......................................................................................... vi
ABSTRACT................................................................................................... viii
1. INTRODUCTION AND MOTIVATION ............................................... 1
2. BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT................... 7
2.1 Conservatism and Contracting..................................................... 7
2.2 Financial Reporting Failures and Contracting ............................. 9
2.3 Hypotheses Development ............................................................ 12
3. RESEARCH DESIGN............................................................................. 21
3.1 Conditional Conservatism............................................................ 21
3.2 Test of H1 .................................................................................... 22
3.3 Unconditional Conservatism........................................................ 24
3.4 Tests of H2 and H3 ...................................................................... 24
3.5 Tests of H4 through H9................................................................ 29
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND ANALYSIS ........................................... 33
4.1 Sample Selection ......................................................................... 33
4.2 Descriptive Statistics.................................................................... 34
4.3 Tests of Hypothesis 1................................................................... 36
4.4 Unconditional Conservatism........................................................ 37
4.5 Tests of Hypotheses 2a and 2b..................................................... 38
4.6 Tests of Hypotheses 3a and 3b..................................................... 39
4.7 Tests of Hypotheses 4a and 4b..................................................... 41
4.8 Tests of Hypotheses 5a and 5b..................................................... 41
4.9 Tests of Hypotheses 6a and 6b..................................................... 42
4.10 Tests of Hypotheses 7a and 7b................................................... 42
4.11 Tests of Hypotheses 8a and 8b................................................... 43
4.12 Tests of Hypotheses 9a and 9b................................................... 43
4.13 Sensitivity Analysis ................................................................... 44
5. CONCLUSION........................................................................................ 93
5.1 Results ......................................................................................... 93
5.2 Contributions ............................................................................... 94
5.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Future Research ....................... 95
iv
TABLE OF CONTENTS
REFERENCES .............................................................................................. 98
BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH ......................................................................... 102
v
LIST OF TABLES
Table 4.1: Sample Attrition....................................................................................48
Table 4.2: Descriptive Statistics ............................................................................49
Table 4.3: Pearson (above the diagonal) and Spearman (below the diagonal)
Correlation Matrix for the Primary Variables......................................52
Table 4.4: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement for
the Period 1994–2004 ..........................................................................54
Table 4.5: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on the Demand for External Financing for the
Period 1994-2004.................................................................................56
Table 4.6: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Bonus Compensation for the Period 1994-2004.........59
Table 4.7: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Outside Directors for the Period
1994-2004 ............................................................................................62
Table 4.8: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Audit Committee Meetings for the
Period 1994-2004.................................................................................65
Table 4.9: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Independent Directors on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004 ..................................................68
Table 4.10: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Financial Experts on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004 .................................................71
Table 4.11: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Top Management for the
Period 1994-2004................................................................................74
Table 4.12: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Auditor for the Period 1994-2004..........77
vi
LIST OF TABLES
Table 4.13: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Separated into Pre- and Post-SOX Periods for the Period
1994–2004............................................................................................80
Table 4.14: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Outside Director Percentage for the Period
1994-2004 ...........................................................................................83
Table 4.15: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Audit Committee Meeting Variables for Year
t+3
for the Period 1994-2004 ....................................................................86
Table 4.16: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on the Financial Expert Percentage on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004 .................................................89
Table 4.17: Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Industry-Adjusted for the Period 1994-2004 for the Period
1994 – 2004.........................................................................................92
vii
viii
ABSTRACT
The quality of financial reporting has come under increased scrutiny in recent years
because of high-profile financial reporting failures, such as Enron and WorldCom, and
the significant increase in the number of financial restatements. While most of the
attention following these financial reporting failures has focused on the capital market
consequences and the negative impact on investor confidence, very little analysis has
adopted a contracting perspective. As accounting information is often used in contracts,
the reliability and quality of the accounting information plays a critical role. A financial
reporting failure casts doubt on the quality of the financial information, and consequently,
leads to greater contracting uncertainty. I posit one means of restoring credibility of the
accounting numbers following a financial reporting failure is to take a more conservative
approach in reporting firm performance. Therefore, this study investigates whether firms
report more conservatively following a financial restatement in order to restore the trust
and confidence of the contracting parties and to protect the interests of the contracting
parties.
I specifically examine whether firms report more conservatively in the three years
following a restatement announcement, and whether an increase in conservatism is
related to the extent of debt and compensation contracts. I then examine various
corporate governance variables as possible explanations for an increase in conservatism
following a restatement. I find restating firms significantly increase conditional
conservatism in the three year period following the restatement announcement year. In
addition, I find that both the level and change in conditional conservatism following a
restatement is greater for firms where debt and compensation contracting are more
important. These results are consistent with the contracting explanation of conservatism
provided in Watts (2003). Lastly, I find little support for corporate governance variables
as explanations for the increase in conservatism.
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION AND MOTIVATION
The quality of financial reporting has come under increased scrutiny in recent years
because of high-profile financial reporting failures, such as Enron and WorldCom, and
the significant increase in the number of financial restatements. An October 2002
General Accounting Office (GAO) report documents that the number of financial
restatements has increased 145 percent from 1997 to 2001 and that publicly traded
companies lost billions in market capitalization in the days and months following a
restatement announcement. The GAO report further concludes that the increase in
restatements has negatively impacted investor confidence. For example, the GAO’s
October 4, 2002 letter to Senator Paul Sarbanes states the following:
“The growing number of restatements and mounting questions about certain corporate
accounting practices appear to have shaken investors’ confidence in our financial
reporting system... empirical research studies and academic experts generally suggest
accounting issues have negatively affected overall investor confidence and raised
questions about the integrity of U.S. markets.”
While most of the attention has focused on the increased restatement activity from a
capital market perspective, very little analysis has adopted a contracting perspective.
Financial reporting serves an important role in contracting as accounting information is
often used in the contract terms and in monitoring of the contract terms (Watts and
Zimmerman 1986). For contracts to be enforceable, the accounting information used in
the contracts must be reliable (Watts 2003a). A financial reporting failure
1
undermines
the reliability of the accounting numbers leading to greater contracting uncertainty. Like
investors, contracting parties likely lose confidence in the firm’s financial reporting, and
may view future financial reports as less credible. This becomes a significant problem
1
I define a financial reporting failure as an accounting fraud or restatement. A fraud is defined as
“intentional non-GAAP financial reporting” (Palmrose, Richardson, and Scholz 2004). A restatement is an
admission that previously issued financial statements were not in accordance with GAAP (Palmrose and
Scholz 2004), and can occur for a variety of reasons, ranging from fraud to an honest mistake.
1
for the firm, as contracting parties need to have confidence and trust in a firm’s financial
reporting process.
I expect that firms will attempt to mitigate the increased contracting uncertainty
following a financial reporting failure. One means of restoring credibility of the
accounting numbers is to take a more conservative approach in reporting firm
performance. Therefore, this study investigates whether firms report more conservatively
following a financial reporting failure in order to restore the trust and confidence of
contracting parties and to protect their interests. Specifically, I examine accounting
conservatism for a sample of restatement firms using both “levels” and “changes”
analyses. I identify restatement firms from the GAO’s 2002 database of financial
statement restatements for the period 1997 - 2001.
Watts (2003a) suggests conservatism is beneficial to contracting parties because it
decreases the probability of distributions that violate contracts and reduce firm value.
Accordingly, managers of firms with reporting failures can voluntarily report
conservatively as a “signal” to contracting parties that their interests are protected and the
financial reports are credible. Alternatively, contracting parties may demand more
conservative reporting following a reporting failure in order to ensure their interests are
protected. Both alternatives lead to the same prediction – firms report more
conservatively following a financial reporting failure.
Recent studies describe two types of conservatism, conditional and unconditional
(e.g. Ball and Shivakumar 2005; Beaver and Ryan 2005). Beaver and Ryan (2005)
define unconditional conservatism as when net assets are understated due to
“predetermined aspects of the accounting process.” They define conditional
conservatism as when net assets are “written down under sufficiently adverse
circumstances, but not up under favorable circumstances.” Conditional conservatism
corresponds to the Basu (1997) notion of conservatism, that is, earnings reflect ‘bad
news’ more quickly than ‘good news’. Basu (2005) describes the key distinction between
the two forms of conservatism as follows: unconditional conservatism utilizes
information known at the inception of assets and liabilities; whereas, conditional
conservatism utilizes new information as it is received in future periods.
2
Ball and Shivakumar (2005) argue that unconditional conservatism does not enhance
contracting efficiency, as they state it is “inefficient or at best neutral in contracting.”
More specifically, unconditional conservatism is just a downward accounting bias that
investors and other contractual parties can adjust for ex ante; whereas, conditional
conservatism protects contracting parties as book values are written down when
economic losses become known. Therefore, conditional conservatism has the potential to
improve contract efficiency for both debt and compensation contracts. For debt
contracts, recognizing bad news in earnings sooner than good news protects lenders as it
more quickly triggers debt covenant violations. For compensation contracts, conditional
conservatism makes it less likely that managers receive excess compensation due to
upwardly biased financial information. Therefore, managers would likely be motivated
to increase conditional conservatism following a financial reporting failure in order to
reduce contracting uncertainty and restore credibility of the accounting numbers. In
addition, these incentives would likely depend on the extent of contracting and the
corporate governance environment.
Whereas conditional conservatism may have originated to facilitate contracting, Basu
(2005) suggests that unconditional conservatism arose mainly for regulatory or tax
reasons, such as accelerated depreciation for tax purposes or immediate expensing of
R&D expenses as required by FASB. The regulatory or GAAP-based rules that lead to
unconditional conservatism are not affected by a restatement; thus, it is unlikely that
unconditional conservatism would change following a financial reporting failure.
In contrast to the above arguments, there are still strong economic incentives for firms
to report aggressively, such as to meet or beat analyst forecasts or to increase
compensation. Thus, it is an empirical question whether or not firms report more
conservatively following a financial reporting failure. The first research objective of this
paper is to determine if there is a change in conditional and unconditional conservatism
following one type of financial reporting failure, a restatement. Given the need to restore
credibility to the reporting process, I predict that conditional conservatism increases
following a financial restatement. To test this prediction, I examine conditional
conservatism in restating firms for the three years before and after the announcement year
of a financial reporting failure. Conditional conservatism is calculated based on the Basu
3
(1997) asymmetric timeliness of earnings perspective of conservatism. Unconditional
conservatism is measured as the Basu (1997) regression intercepts, as suggested in Basu
(2005). I make no prediction regarding a change in unconditional conservatism as I
expect the restatement to have no effect on this type of conservatism.
I find restating firms significantly increase conditional conservatism in the three year
period following the restatement announcement. These findings suggest firms
proactively take steps to restore trust and confidence in their financial reporting following
a restatement. I find no change in unconditional conservatism following the restatement
announcement. This is consistent with unconditional conservatism being a downward
accounting bias not affected by a restatement.
As conditional conservatism has the potential to improve contract efficiency, the
second research objective of this paper is to examine whether the increase in conditional
conservatism following a restatement is related to a firm’s contracting. I find the increase
in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for firms where debt and
compensation contracting are more important. Based on sensitivity tests, the results
relating to compensation contracting are relatively weaker than the results for debt
compensation. Overall, these findings suggest firms report more conservatively in order
to reduce contracting uncertainty and restore the trust and confidence of the contracting
parties.
An increase in conditional conservatism following a financial reporting failure may
be linked to various intermediate changes in a firm’s financial reporting environment,
such as changes in management, board of directors, audit committee, or the auditor. For
example, Farber (2005) provides evidence that firms take actions to improve corporate
governance following a fraud; such as increasing the number of audit committee
meetings and the number and percentage of outside board members. However, very little
research examines whether these actions lead to an increase in conservatism. Therefore,
the third research objective of this paper is to examine the determinants of a change in
accounting conservatism following a restatement by including variables relating to
changes in management, board of directors, audit committee, and audit firm. This
analysis provides evidence on whether changes in corporate governance mechanisms
following a restatement are associated with an increase in conservatism.
4
Consistent with Farber (2005), I find firms take actions to improve corporate
governance following the restatement. However, I find these changes in corporate
governance mechanisms are not related to the increase in conservatism following a
restatement. Surprisingly, improving corporate governance mechanisms did not lead to a
change in how firms report financial performance following a restatement. Thus, my
findings suggest that greater levels of contracting, and not necessarily changes in
corporate governance, motivate an increase in conservatism following a restatement.
This study contributes to the literature on restatements and accounting conservatism
in several ways. First, the study provides a potential explanation for the findings in
Moore and Pfeiffer (2004). They find no change in conservatism following financial
statement restatements and conclude that restatement firms do not reform their financial
reporting. However, they use total accruals as their primary measure of conservatism and
make no attempt to isolate conditional conservatism. This study may help explain why
they find no change in conservatism following restatements, as I find it is only
conditional conservatism that changes following a restatement.
This study also contributes to the financial reporting failure literature as Farber (2005)
finds that fraud firms take measures to improve corporate governance following a fraud;
however, he does not address the issue of conservatism. I find no evidence that
improvements in corporate governance following a restatement affect a firm’s financial
reporting choices.
Finally, this study furthers our understanding of accounting conservatism in at least
three ways. First, this study provides evidence regarding the contracting explanation for
conservatism, as I examine the impact of debt and compensation contracting on firms’
financial reporting choices. My findings are consistent with the contracting explanation
of conservatism. Second, I empirically examine changes in the two types of
conservatism, conditional and unconditional, following a financial reporting failure. As
expected, I find only conditional conservatism changes following a restatement. Third,
this study provides insight into what may be the driving force(s) behind a change in
conservatism by examining changes in the financial reporting environment following a
financial reporting failure. Knowledge of which monitoring mechanisms (i.e. board of
directors, audit committee, and auditor) lead to increased conservatism is important to
5
regulators and contracting parties. Surprisingly, I find no relation between changes in
corporate governance and a change in conservatism following a restatement.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Chapter 2 reviews the literature and
develops hypotheses. Chapter 3 describes the research design, including the data sources,
methodology, and hypotheses testing. Chapter 4 presents the empirical results and
analysis. Chapter 5 offers concluding remarks, along with limitations and suggestions for
future research.
6
CHAPTER 2
BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT
2.1 Conservatism and Contracting
Although there is no agreed-upon formal definition of conservatism, there have been
several definitions of conservatism brought forth in the literature. Watts (2003a) notes
early accounting textbooks, such as Bliss (1924), define conservatism as “anticipate no
profit, but anticipate all losses.” Givoly and Hayn (2000) define conservatism as
selecting accounting principles that minimize “cumulative reported earnings by slower
revenue recognition, faster expense recognition, lower asset valuation, and higher
liability valuation.” Basu (1997) views conservatism as when earnings reflect ‘bad news’
more quickly than ‘good news’. Watts (2003a) ultimately defines conservatism as the
“differential verifiability required for recognition of profits versus losses,” which is
consistent with the Basu (1997) definition. This definition means there is a higher degree
of verification required for recognizing good news as gains than for recognizing bad
news as losses (Basu 1997). Even though there is no single agreed-upon definition of
conservatism, one common result arises from conservative reporting - conservatism leads
to a persistent understatement of net assets.
As for the reasons for the existence of accounting conservatism, Watts (2003a)
suggests four potential explanations: contracting, shareholder litigation, taxation, and
accounting regulation. He argues that contracting is the most likely explanation for the
origins of accounting and conservatism centuries ago because only contracting existed
centuries ago, whereas litigation, taxation, and accounting regulation have only occurred
more recently.
Penman (2003) describes the important role accounting serves in contracting as
follows:
“…accounting is concerned with the division of property rights between
shareholders and bondholders, between shareholders and management, and
7
between shareholders and auditors – and with the efficient contracting over those
property rights that is so essential for the functioning of an economy.”
Holthausen and Watts (2001) find empirical evidence consistent with the contracting
explanation of conservatism. They find conservatism existed before formal standard
setting and before litigation became a major factor in the late 1960’s.
Watts (2003a) explains why conservatism arose for contracting purposes as follows.
In debt contracts, conservatism makes it less likely that management upwardly biases
earnings and “make what is effectively a liquidating dividend payment to shareholders at
the expense of debt holders”. Ahmed, Billings, Morton, and Stanford-Harris (2002)
provide empirical evidence of the role conservatism plays in debt contracting. They
argue that conservatism mitigates the conflicts of interest over dividend policy between
shareholders and bondholders. They find that firms with more severe conflicts of interest
over dividend policy use more conservative accounting, and that conservatism is
associated with a lower cost of debt. For compensation contracts, conservatism reduces
the likelihood that management overstates financial measures in order to take excess
compensation. Conservative earnings tend to defer a manager’s earnings-based
compensation until the full effects of the manager’s actions are recognized in earnings
(Holthausen and Watts 2001). Therefore, this study focuses on two contracting reasons
for conservatism: debt and management compensation contracts.
Conditional and unconditional conservatism are two distinct types of conservatism
recognized in recent literature (Ball and Shivakumar 2005; Beaver and Ryan 2005).
Beaver and Ryan (2005) define unconditional conservatism as when net assets are
understated due to “predetermined aspects of the accounting process.” This type of
conservatism is also known as “ex ante” or “news-independent” conservatism. Beaver
and Ryan (2005) describe accelerated depreciation and immediate expensing of R&D as
examples of unconditional conservatism. The subsequent write-off of assets under this
type of conservatism will be independent of future events, thus the term “news-
independent.” They define conditional conservatism as when net assets are “written
down under sufficiently adverse circumstances, but not up under favorable
circumstances.” This type of conservatism is also known as “ex post” or “news-
8
dependent” conservatism. Examples of conditional conservatism given by Beaver and
Ryan (2005) are the lower of cost or market rule for inventory and impairment
accounting of long-term tangible and intangible assets, such as impairment accounting for
goodwill. The write-off of assets under conditional conservatism is triggered by future
events, thus the term “news-dependent.”
As for the two types of conservatism, Ball and Shivakumar (2005) argue that only the
conditional form of conservatism should affect contract efficiency because it incorporates
new information that could produce contracting responses. The unconditional form of
conservatism does not employ new information and is merely a downward accounting
bias that contracting parties can adjust for ex ante. Contract terms can be written to undo
the effect of accounting methods. For example, Ball and Shivakumar (2005) point out
that if book values of assets are systematically understated by a known amount, then debt
covenants can require an increase to the book values by this amount when determining
leverage and the amount a firm could borrow. Basu (2005) points out that historical
evidence suggests unconditional conservatism arose as a response to regulatory or tax
incentives. For example, Basu (2005) suggests the early development of conservative
depreciation methods was influenced by corporate income taxes as firms attempted to
maximize the depreciation deduction. In summary, unconditional conservatism serves a
different function than conditional conservatism from a contracting perspective, as only
conditional conservatism has the potential to improve contract efficiency. Conditional
conservatism allows for contracting responses to new information, such as bad news in
earnings triggering a debt covenant violation. Conversely, unconditional conservatism
does not allow for contracting responses to new information because it is a downward
accounting bias independent of new information.
2.2 Financial Reporting Failures and Contracting
Financial reporting failures include both frauds and restatements. For the purpose of
this study, I examine only accounting restatements. Restatements are an admission that
previously issued financial statements were not in accordance with GAAP (Palmrose and
Scholz 2004). Early research focused on characteristics of restating firms. For example,
Kinney and McDaniel (1989) find restatement firms are smaller, less profitable, have
9
higher debt, and are slower growing. DeFond and Jiambalvo (1991) find earnings
overstatements are more likely for firms with diffuse ownership and lower growth in
earnings, and less likely for firms with audit committees.
Recent studies document significant negative economic consequences related to
financial reporting failures. Palmrose et al. (2004) find a mean abnormal return of -9.2
percent in the two-day window (day 0, 1) around a restatement announcement, with more
negative returns for restatements involving fraud (-20 percent). Palmrose and Scholz
(2004) find the negative market reaction is greater for restatements of core earnings (i.e.
pre-tax earnings from primary operations) than for non-core earnings (i.e. all other
earnings). Anderson and Yohn (2002) document the long-term economic consequences
of restatements by finding average cumulative abnormal returns of -7.97 percent for the
period from three days before the restatement announcement through three days after the
restatement filing with the SEC.
There are also legal consequences to a financial reporting failure, as Palmrose and
Scholz (2004) find that 38 percent of the companies in their restatement sample
subsequently faced civil litigation. They find companies with restatements of core
earnings (primarily revenue restatements) and pervasive restatements (i.e. more than one
accounting item restated) are more likely to be subject to litigation.
A financial reporting failure also damages the reputation of the firm, auditors,
management, and the board of directors. For example, Srinivasan (2005) finds outside
board members experience significant reputational costs following accounting
restatements. Srinivasan finds significant turnover of board members in the three years
following the restatement, including director turnover for 48 percent of firms that restate
earnings downward. The likelihood of director turnover increases if the board member is
also on the audit committee. The study also finds outside directors lose positions on
other boards following a restatement.
Another study, Desai, Hogan, and Wilkins (2006) examines the reputational penalties
to managers of restating firms, and finds that 60 percent of restating firms experience
management turnover in the two years following a restatement as compared with 35
percent for a control sample. An audit firm’s reputation can be damaged by a financial
reporting failure, as evidenced by the demise of Arthur Andersen. Barton (2005)
10
examines the demand for auditor reputation by examining the client defections from
Arthur Andersen. Barton (2005) finds firms that are more visible in the capital markets
switched sooner to another Big 5 auditor, as they were concerned about their auditor’s
reputation and the credibility of their financial reporting.
As discussed above, accounting numbers used in contracts must be verifiable for the
contract to be enforceable in court (Watts 2003a). Based on prior literature, it is
reasonable to assume that a financial reporting failure leads to greater uncertainty about
the reliability and verifiability of the accounting numbers used in contracts. As a
restatement casts doubt on the quality of the financial reports and increases the risk to the
contracting parties, shareholders and lenders will demand an increased risk premium
following a reporting failure. For example, empirical studies find that frauds and
accounting restatements lead to an increased cost of capital (e.g. Dechow, Sloan and
Sweeney 1996; Hribar and Jenkins 2004). Investors demand a higher rate of return to
compensate for the perceived riskiness of the firm due to less reliable accounting
numbers following a reporting failure.
As for debt contracts, Sengupta (1998) suggests one factor likely used by lenders in
calculating default risk is the quality of financial reporting. Sengupta (1998) finds firms
with high disclosure quality ratings from financial analysts are charged a lower cost of
debt, and the importance of disclosure is greater when there is greater market uncertainty
as measured by the variance of stock returns. Thus, lenders likely demand a higher risk
premium following a reporting failure in part due to the perceived decrease in quality of
the accounting reports.
The risk premium demanded by shareholders and debt holders also increases
following a reporting failure because of the increased uncertainty about the future
profitability and economic prospects of restatement firms. Palmrose et al. (2004) find a
significant downward revision in earnings forecasts following restatements and find a
significant increase in analyst forecast dispersion (a proxy for uncertainty). Hribar and
Jenkins (2004) find accounting restatements lead to decreases in expected future
earnings.
In summary, restatements can have numerous negative effects. These include
economic losses to investors; damage to the reputations of the firm, auditors,
11
management, and the board of directors; an increase in the cost of capital; and a negative
impact on future earnings power.
2.3 Hypotheses Development
As discussed in the previous section, there are significant negative economic, legal,
reputational, and contractual consequences to a financial reporting failure. A financial
reporting failure is evidence that previously issued accounting reports were incorrect,
thus creating uncertainty about the credibility and verifiability of financial reports after
the reporting failure. This uncertainty likely increases the perceived information
asymmetry between contracting parties (i.e. management, debt holders, and
shareholders). Watts (2003a) suggests conservative accounting is one way to address the
moral hazard problem created by the information asymmetry between contracting parties.
This is because conservatism constrains management and protects the interests of the
contracting parties. In debt contracts, Watts (2003a) suggests conservatism decreases the
probability that management makes a “liquidating dividend payment to shareholders at
the expense of debt holders.” For compensation contracts, conservatism reduces the
likelihood that management overstates financial measures in order to take excess
compensation.
I take the Ball and Shivakumar (2005) view that only the conditional form of
conservatism affects contracting efficiency. They view unconditional conservatism as a
downward accounting bias that contracting parties can adjust for ex ante. When new
information comes along, this form of conservatism does not react to the news. Thus,
there is no advantage from an efficient contracting perspective for firms to become more
unconditionally conservative following a reporting failure. Therefore, I expect no change
in unconditional conservatism following a financial reporting failure.
However, under the conditional form of conservatism, firms exercise judgment in
how they react to and incorporate new information into their financial reporting, which
offers ex post protection to contracting parties. The primary example of conditional
conservatism is impairment accounting. Riedl (2004) models asset impairments as a
“function of economic factors and reporting incentives.” While the economic factors that
lead to asset impairments may be beyond the firms’ control, firms do exercise significant
12
judgment and discretion when reporting asset impairments. Managers can exercise
discretion over asset impairments because SFAS No. 144 (which superceded SFAS No.
121) requires firms to forecast future performance in order to estimate undiscounted
future cash flows. This estimation of future cash flows requires significant judgment,
estimates, and assumptions, which allows firms to behave more or less conservatively.
Therefore, firms have the ability to become more conservative and improve contract
efficiency following a reporting failure. For example, in debt contracting, conservatism
benefits borrowers as they can borrow at lower interest rates (Zhang 2004; Ahmed et al.
2002), and benefits lenders as conservatism more quickly triggers debt covenant
violations (Zhang 2004). Conservatism can lead to a lower cost of capital as
shareholders’ interests are more protected from managers taking excess compensation.
As discussed above, lenders and shareholders demand a greater risk premium
following a reporting failure because of the uncertainty surrounding the credibility of the
financial reports and the uncertainty about the future economic prospects of the firm. I
predict firms increase conditional conservatism following a financial reporting failure in
order to reduce contracting uncertainty, offset or minimize increases in the cost of debt
and capital, and to restore trust and confidence in their financial reports. This results in
the following hypothesis, stated in the alternate form:
H1: Restatement firms increase conditional conservatism following a financial
reporting failure.
Watts (2003b) summarizes the empirical literature on conservatism and finds results
consistent with all four explanations (i.e. contracting, litigation, taxation, and regulation),
but suggests contracting is the most important explanation for accounting conservatism.
This is because only contracting can explain the existence of conservatism centuries ago,
as litigation, taxation, and accounting regulation have only occurred more recently.
As for debt contracting, agency theory predicts a moral hazard problem created by the
information asymmetry between shareholders and debt holders (Jensen and Meckling
1976). Watts (2003a) suggests conservative accounting is one way to address this moral
hazard problem. Watts suggests that in debt contracts, conservatism reduces the
13
probability that management will “overstate earnings and assets, and make what is
effectively a liquidating dividend payment to shareholders at the expense of debt
holders.” Accounting conservatism reduces the earnings and net asset measures used in
debt contracts, and thus more quickly triggers debt covenant constraints. Therefore, debt
holders demand conservative accounting in order to protect their interests and ensure
payment of the loan. As a result, I expect that the more important debt contracting is to a
firm, the more conservative it will be following a reporting failure and the greater the
increase in conservatism relative to before the failure. This results in the following
hypotheses concerning both the level and change in conservatism:
H2a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms who have
more of a demand for debt contracting.
H2b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms who have more of a demand for debt contracting.
As for compensation contracts, agency theory predicts moral hazard problems related
to the separation of ownership and control (Jensen and Meckling 1976). This moral
hazard problem arises from the information asymmetry between the principal
(shareholders) and the agent (managers). The bonus hypothesis predicts managers of
firms with bonus plans are more likely to bias accounting numbers upward to increase
their compensation (Watts and Zimmerman 1986). Watts (2003a) suggests this upward
bias leads to excessive management compensation, which reduces shareholder value.
Watts (2003a) further suggests that in compensation contracts, conservatism reduces the
likelihood that management overstates earnings and net assets in order to take excess
compensation. Conservative earnings defer a manager’s earnings-based compensation
until the full effects of the manager’s actions are recognized in earnings (Holthausen and
Watts 2001). Consequently, I expect shareholders of firms with earnings-based
managerial compensation plans to demand more conservative accounting to offset this
upward bias. As a result, I predict the more important performance-related compensation
contracting is to a firm, the more conservative it will be following a reporting failure and
14
the greater the increase in conservatism relative to before the failure. This leads to the
following hypotheses concerning both the level and change in conservatism:
H3a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms with more
bonus compensation.
H3b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms with more bonus compensation.
To my knowledge there is only one study, Moore and Pfeiffer (2004), which
examines whether a firm reports more conservatively following a restatement. They
examine several measures to proxy for a firm’s financial reporting aggressiveness,
including total accruals, working capital accruals, patterns in earnings, and patterns in
analysts’ forecast errors. They measure these proxies before and after the restatement
and find no change in accounting aggressiveness. They conclude that firms do not
reform their financial reporting by reporting more conservatively following a restatement.
However, the Moore and Pfeiffer study does not mention the two types of conservatism
and does not use the Basu (1997) measure of conditional conservatism. Givoly, Hayn,
and Natarajan (2007) find the Basu measure of conservatism is negatively correlated with
other measures of conservatism, such as the market-to-book ratio, conservatism due to
investments in positive net present value projects and accounting rules (Easton and Pae
2004), and conservatism as measured as the sum of three reserve components: inventory,
R&D and advertising (Penman and Zhang 2002). Givoly et al. (2007) suggest the Basu
measure of conditional conservatism is capturing a unique aspect of conservatism not
captured by the other measures. This study may help explain Moore and Pfeiffer’s lack
of results as H1 predicts only conditional conservatism changes after a restatement. In
addition, this study views contracting as the primary explanation for conservatism, and
thus H2 and H3 provide more powerful tests by examining whether a change in
conservatism following a reporting failure is greater for firms where contracting is more
important.
15
Conservative reporting following a financial reporting failure may be the result of a
chain of events. It would be insightful to examine the antecedents to conservatism
following a restatement. Restatement firms typically receive increased scrutiny from
regulators and experience significant operational, structural, and corporate governance
changes, such as turnover in management, board members, audit committee, and auditors.
These changes may be mechanisms that constrain management’s opportunistic behavior
and lead to more conservative reporting. The importance of enhancing corporate
governance to improve financial reporting practices can be explicitly seen in the recent
passage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 (SOX). SOX contains many provisions to
advance corporate governance with the explicit purpose to “protect investors by
improving the accuracy and reliability of corporate disclosures made pursuant to the
securities laws, and for other purposes” (SOX 2002). Therefore, I next examine the
determinants of an increase in conditional conservatism following a financial reporting
failure.
Beasley (1996) finds that firms with more outside board members significantly
reduce the likelihood of fraud. So a likely response a firm can take following a financial
reporting failure is to increase the number of outside members on the board of directors.
This response can be seen in Farber (2005), who finds that fraud firms increase the
number and percentage of outside directors in the three years following the fraud.
Farber’s study does not examine accounting conservatism; therefore, it is still an open
empirical question as to whether an improvement in corporate governance mechanisms
following a reporting failure leads to an increase in conservatism.
The literature on board composition and financial reporting has primarily focused on
earnings management, and not conservatism. For example, Klein (2002) finds a negative
relation between board independence and abnormal accruals and concludes a more
independent board is more effective in monitoring financial reporting. One study,
Beekes, Pope, and Young (2004) directly examines the relation between board
composition and conditional conservatism in the U.K. They use the Basu (1997) method
to measure conditional conservatism and find that U.K. firms with a higher proportion of
outside board members report more conservatively. Based on the findings of these
studies, I expect firms that increase the number of outside directors following a reporting
16
failure report more conservatively and have a greater increase in conservatism relative to
before the failure. This leads to the following hypotheses:
H4a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms that increase
the number of outside directors.
H4b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms that increase the number of outside directors.
Abbott, Parker, and Peters (2004) examine how certain audit committee
characteristics are associated with both fraud and restatement companies. They find a
fraud/restatement is less likely when the audit committee is more independent, meets at
least four times a year, and includes at least one member with financial expertise. So a
likely response to a fraud or restatement is to improve the monitoring function of the
audit committee by having more independent members, meetings, and financial experts
on the committee.
Farber (2005) provides evidence of this as he finds fraud firms significantly increase
the number of audit committee meetings in the three years after the fraud. However,
Farber (2005) finds no significant change in the number of independent members or
financial experts on the audit committee following a fraud. This is surprising based on
the results of Abbott et al. (2004), who find fraud is less likely for firms with audit
committees that are more independent and have at least one financial expert.
Furthermore, DeFond, Hann, and Hu (2005) find a positive market reaction to the
appointment of accounting financial experts to the audit committee. Since the market
places value on audit committee members who are financial experts, it would be
reasonable to expect a firm to increase the number of financial experts following a
reporting failure in order to restore investor confidence. Therefore, I predict an audit
committee that is more diligent, more independent, and has more financial expertise
following a reporting failure demands more conservative financial reporting. These firms
will exhibit a greater level and greater change in conservatism following a restatement.
This leads to the following hypotheses:
17
H5a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms that increase
the number of audit committee meetings.
H5b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms that increase the number of audit committee meetings.
H6a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms that increase
the number of independent directors on the audit committee.
H6b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms that increase the number of independent directors on the audit
committee.
H7a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms that increase
the number of financial experts on the audit committee.
H7b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms that increase the number of financial experts on the audit committee.
.
Desai et al. (2006) find significant reputational penalties to managers of restatement
firms. They find that 60 percent of restatement firms experience turnover of at least one
top manager in the two years following the restatement, and they find 85 percent of
displaced managers are unable to find comparable employment. In addition, research
finds a change in top management is associated with write-offs or “big bath” charges
(Pourciau 1993; Francis, Hanna, and Vincent 1996). One interpretation of these findings
is that new management is taking big bath charges and attributing them to prior
management. Alternatively, Riedl (2004) suggests these write-offs “may reflect true
economic changes,” such as a change in business strategy or increased attention to
existing assets. Both alternatives suggest that a change in top management leads to more
conservative reporting. Based on these results, I predict new managers of restatement
18
firms report more conservatively in order to protect their reputations and “signal” to
contracting parties that their interests are protected and the financial reports are credible.
This prediction, with respect to both the level and change in conditional conservatism, is
hypothesized as follows:
H8a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms with a change
in top management.
H8b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms with a change in top management.
Farber (2005) finds that fraud firms are more likely than a control sample to switch
auditors following a fraud. It seems reasonable to believe that the new auditor of a
restatement firm brings increased skepticism over the reliability and credibility of the
firm’s financial reports. The new auditor may require more conservative reporting in
order to protect their reputation and to reduce the likelihood of litigation and the
reoccurrence of a fraud or restatement. For example, empirical studies find that auditors
can mitigate their litigation risk by requiring their clients to report more conservatively
(e.g. Cahan & Zhang 2006; Krishnan 2005). Specifically, Cahan and Zhang (2006) find
the former Arthur Andersen clients had lower levels of abnormal accruals and greater
decreases in abnormal accruals in the first year of being audited by the successor audit
firm. Francis and Krishnan (1999) find that auditors respond to the increased risk of
high-accrual firms by reporting more conservatively through the issuance of more
modified audit reports. DeFond and Subramanyam (1998) find that negative
discretionary accruals are greater for clients that pose the greatest litigation risk.
Therefore, I expect the new auditor of a restating firm to demand more conservative
reporting in order to protect their reputation and reduce the likelihood of litigation. This
leads to the following hypotheses concerning both the level and change in conservatism:
19
H9a: Post restatement, conditional conservatism is greater for firms with a change
in auditor.
H9b: An increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for
firms with a change in auditor.
In summary, Hypotheses 4 through 9 predict changes in several corporate governance
variables are related to both the level and change in conditional conservatism following a
restatement. The corporate governance variables included in this study are the number of
outside directors, the number of audit committee meetings, the number of independent
directors and financial experts on the audit committee, and the change in top management
and audit firm.
20
CHAPTER 3
RESEARCH DESIGN
This chapter presents the research design to test the hypotheses presented in the
previous chapter. Section 3.1 first describes the Basu (1997) methodology of capturing
conditional conservatism, which is a basis of my analysis. Section 3.2 describes an
alternative model to Basu’s model developed to test the first hypothesis. Section 3.3
describes the test of unconditional conservatism. Section 3.4 describes the tests of the
contracting hypotheses, H2 and H3. Finally, Section 3.5 describes the methodology used
to test hypotheses 4 through 9.
3.1 Conditional Conservatism
This study relies on a measure of conditional conservatism to investigate financial
reporting changes following a restatement. I adopt the Basu (1997) approach for
identifying conditional conservatism, under the assumption that earnings reflect ‘bad
news’ more quickly than ‘good news’. This approach is consistent with the Watts
(2003a) view of conservatism, which he defines as the “asymmetrical verification
requirements for gains and losses.” Therefore, conditional conservatism in this study is
based on the Basu (1997) model as follows:
X
it
/P
it-1
= α
0
+ α
1
D + β
0
R
it
+ β
1
D*R
it
, (Basu 1997) (1)
where X
it
/P
it-1
is current period earnings scaled by beginning of period price, R
it
is the 12-
month return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end to three months after fiscal
year end, and D is an indicator variable set equal to one when R
it
is negative, and zero
otherwise. Earnings are measured as earnings per share (Compustat data item 58). The
β
coefficients capture the mapping of news (returns) into current earnings. β
0
reflects the
mapping of good news into current earnings. β
1
captures the incremental effect of
earnings reflecting bad news relative to good news, and under conservative accounting,
21
β
1
is expected to be greater than zero. The ratio (β
0
+β
1
)/β
0
captures the sensitivity of
earnings to bad news relative to good news and is expected to be greater than one under
conservative accounting.
Givoly et al. (2007) examine the power and reliability of the Basu measure of
reporting conservatism and conclude its use “in different research settings should be more
selective and qualified.” They find the use of aggregated measures of earnings and
returns has an excessive influence on the magnitude of the Basu measure of
conservatism. They identify characteristics of the firm’s information environment that
are unrelated to conservatism that can affect the Basu measure; however, they freely
admit that controlling for these characteristics “are not easy to implement.” They also
find the Basu measure is negatively correlated with other measures of conservatism and
suggest it is only capturing one source or dimension of conservatism. However, an
express purpose of this study is to distinguish differential timeliness from other measures
of unconditional conservatism. Thus, while the criticisms of the Basu approach
expressed by Givoly et al. (2007) highlight limitations of the measure, they do not
invalidate this basic method of capturing conditional conservatism.
3.2 Test of H1
I predict in this study that firms increase conditional conservatism following a
restatement to help restore the credibility of their financial reports. With respect to
equation (1), this implies that the coefficient β
1
increases following a restatement. I
define the pre-restatement period to be the three years prior to the year the reporting
failure is announced. The post-restatement period includes the three years following the
year of the restatement announcement. I exclude the year of the restatement
announcement from my regression analyses because of the confounding effects of the
restatement announcement on the earnings/returns relationship.
I first consider the Basu (1997) approach and include incremental dummy variables
(e.g. bad news dummy) interacted with returns; however, preliminary data analysis
indicates a multicollinearity problem. The interaction of incremental dummy variables
with returns leads to much commonality among the independent variables. To mitigate
this multicollinearity problem, I instead define mutually exclusive dummy variables for
22
the conditional analysis throughout this study. I include separate PRE and POST dummy
variables to represent the pre/post-restatement periods. The PRE and POST variables are
interacted with returns and with dummy variables representing good and bad news
periods (POS and NEG). This results in mutually exclusive partitions of the sample and
the avoidance of repeated values among the explanatory variables. Preliminary data
analysis using this approach indicates lower standard errors and no multicollinearity
problem. Thus, I test H1 using the following pooled cross-sectional regression:
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*POS + β
1
PRE*NEG + β
2
POST*POS + β
3
POST*NEG
+ β
4
PRE*POS*R
it
+ β
5
PRE*NEG*R
it
+ β
6
POST*POS*R
it
+ β
7
POST*NEG*R
it
+ ε
it
, (2)
where
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end to three
months after fiscal year end;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t;
β
4
= good news in pre-restatement period earnings;
β
5
= bad news in pre-restatement period earnings;
β
6
= good news in post-restatement period earnings;
β
7
= bad news in post-restatement period earnings;
Conditional Conservatism – difference between bad news and good news
β
5
β
4
: Conditional conservatism in the pre-restatement period.
β
7
β
6
: Conditional conservatism in the post-restatement period.
23
H1: (β
7
β
6
) > (β
5
β
4
)
H1 predicts an increase in conditional conservatism in the period following a financial
reporting failure, which is the change in conditional conservatism from the pre- to post-
restatement periods. Therefore, H1 predicts (β
7
β
6
) > (β
5
β
4
).
3.3 Unconditional Conservatism
Basu (2005) suggests using the intercepts from the Basu (1997) asymmetric
regression as a measure of unconditional conservatism. Basu (2005) suggests that the
intercept can be used to measure unconditional conservatism since it reflects average
earnings. Since unconditional conservatism leads to a downward bias in earnings, then a
lower intercept provides evidence of unconditional conservatism. Therefore, the
intercepts from equation (2) are used as my measure of unconditional conservatism.
Even though the model from equation (2) allows for separate intercepts for good and bad
news, since unconditional conservatism is news independent, I am able to aggregate the
good and bad news intercepts into the pre- and post restatement periods as follows: (β
0
+
β
1
) and (β
2
+ β
3
). However, this is not a formal hypothesis test as I expect the null
condition to be true.
As discussed before, I expect to find no change in unconditional conservatism before
and after the restatement, because unconditional conservatism is just a downward
accounting bias that should not be affected by a reporting failure. Therefore, I expect an
insignificant shift in the post-fraud/restatement period intercepts
from equation (2), which
is tested as (β
0
+ β
1
) = (β
2
+ β
3
).
3.4 Tests of H2 and H3
Hypotheses 2 and 3 predict that the level and the increase in conditional conservatism
following a reporting failure are greater for firms where debt and compensation
contracting are more important. To measure the importance of debt contracting to a firm,
I use the ex ante demand for external financing measure from Dechow et al. (1996). An
alternative measure considered for the importance of debt contracting is a firm’s level of
debt or the debt-to-asset ratio. However, these measures do not capture a firm’s need for
24
external financing over the three-year period following a restatement announcement. It is
very important for potential investors/creditors of restating firms to have trust and
confidence in the financial reporting of these firms. Thus, I expect firms that require
external financing soon after a restatement are more motivated to restore the credibility of
their financial reports by reporting more conservatively. The use of the debt level or the
debt-to-asset ratio may not effectively capture this motivation to report conservatively
brought on by the desire to attract external financing at the lowest cost possible. Thus, I
consider the Dechow et al. (1996) measure to be a more powerful measure of the
importance of debt contracting following a restatement.
The Dechow et al. (1996) measure is expressed as follows:
FreeC
t-1
=
2-t
2- t to4-t1-t
AssetsCurrent
esexpenditur capital Average - operations fromCash
The intuition behind this measure is as follows. If cash from operations is insufficient
to cover a firm’s desired investment level (i.e. measured as average capital expenditures),
then additional financing is needed. Thus, a negative numerator represents the amount of
financing needed. The denominator represents current assets available to fund the
desired investment level. Once the internal funds are consumed, then external financing
is needed.
The absolute value of the ratio
1-t
FreeC
1
when FreeC
t-1
is negative indicates the
remaining years the firm can go without needing external financing. For example, if
FreeC
t-1
equals -0.5, then the absolute value of the ratio
1-t
FreeC
1
equals 2. This means a
firm will consume its current assets in two years and thus require external financing.
Dechow et al. (1996) set FreeC
t-1
equal to -0.5 as the cutoff point between firms that have
a greater (lesser) demand for external financing. They also point out that since firms can
not exist without current assets and their model assumes all current assets are converted
to cash, their measure likely understates the need for external financing. Therefore,
assuming this relation carries over to the post-restatement period, and following Dechow
25
et al. (1996), I code the variable EXTFINHI as 1 if FreeC
t-1
is less than -0.5, and 0
otherwise. I code EXTFINLO as 1 if is greater than or equal to -0.5, and 0 otherwise. I
use HI/LO variables for EXTFIN in order to partition the sample into mutually exclusive
groups, where the separate relations will be captured by the regression coefficients.
Finally, I measure FreeC
t-1
in the year prior to the restatement announcement to ensure
the measure is not affected by the restatement announcement.
One contracting theory of earnings manipulation brought forth in the literature is the
bonus hypothesis (Watts and Zimmerman 1986), which predicts managers of firms with
bonus plans are more likely to manipulate earnings upward to increase their
compensation. Therefore, I measure the importance of compensation contracting to a
firm by using the variable Bonus from the Compustat Executive Compensation database.
Compustat defines Bonus as “the dollar value of a bonus (cash and non-cash) earned by
the named executive officer during the fiscal year.” I aggregate the bonuses of all
executives of the firm and compute the average for each year in the sample period. I then
scale the firm’s average bonus by end-of-year total assets to control for firm size effects
on compensation. I use HI/LO variables for BONUS in order to partition the sample into
mutually exclusive groups, which helps avoid a multicollinearity problem. The variable
BONUSLO (BONUSHI) is set equal to 1 if a firm’s average bonus is less than (greater
than or equal to) the median bonus of all sample firms, otherwise BONUSLO
(BONUSHI) is set equal to 0. Finally, the use of the variable Bonus does have potential
limitations as some firms may use stock-based incentive plans rather than earnings-based
incentive plans. However, the failure to include other incentive plans works against me
finding significant results in support of H3, as my tests may not capture all of the
compensation contracting effects on conservatism following a restatement.
I extend equation (2) to include the EXTFIN and BONUS HI/LO variables and
estimate the following pooled cross-sectional regressions:
26
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*EXTFINHI*POS + β
1
PRE*EXTFINLO*POS
+ β
2
POST*EXTFINHI*POS + β
3
POST*EXTFINLO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*EXTFINHI*R*POS + β
5
PRE*EXTFINLO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*EXTFINHI*R*POS + β
7
POST*EXTFINLO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*EXTFINHI*NEG + β
9
PRE*EXTFINLO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*EXTFINHI*NEG + β
11
POST*EXTFINLO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*EXTFINHI*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*EXTFINLO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*EXTFINHI*R*NEG + β
15
POST*EXTFINLO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (3)
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*BONUSHI*POS + β
1
PRE*BONUSLO*POS
+ β
2
POST*BONUSHI*POS + β
3
POST*BONUSLO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*BONUSHI*R*POS + β
5
PRE*BONUSLO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*BONUSHI*R*POS + β
7
POST*BONUSLO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*BONUSHI*NEG + β
9
PRE*BONUSLO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*BONUSHI*NEG + β
11
POST*BONUSLO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*BONUSHI*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*BONUSLO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*BONUSHI*R*NEG + β
15
POST*BONUSLO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (4)
where
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
>=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
EXTFINHI = 1 if firm’s FreeC
t-1
is less than -0.5, and 0 otherwise. Where FreeC
t-1
is
defined as:
FreeC
t-1
=
2-t
2- t to4-t1-t
AssetsCurrent
esexpenditur capital Average - operations fromCash
27
EXTFINLO = 1 if firm’s FreeC
t-1
is greater than or equal to -0.5, and 0 otherwise;
BONUSHI = 1 if a firm’s dollar value of a bonus is greater than or equal to the median
bonus of all sample firms, otherwise BONUSHI = 0. A firm’s bonus is
measured as the average bonus of the firm’s executives scaled by end-of-
year total assets (Compustat Data 6). Bonus data is obtained from the
Compustat Executive Compensation database;
BONUSLO = 1 if a firm’s dollar value of a bonus is less than the median bonus of all
sample firms, otherwise BONUSLO = 0;
R
it
= the 12-month return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end to three
months after fiscal year end;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
I next describe what the coefficients in equations 3 and 4 are capturing; including the
specific coefficients I use to test H2a-b and H3a-b. The regression equations follow a
parallel structure such that the effect of high and low external financing needs in equation
3 correspond to the high and low bonus conditions in equation 4. Thus, for simplicity, I
describe the coefficients only once and note the alternative interpretations for equation
3(4) in the description.
Good news reflected in earnings
β
4
= good news in pre-restatement period earnings for high financing (bonus) firms;
β
5
= good news in pre-restatement period earnings for low financing (bonus) firms;
β
6
= good news in post-restatement period earnings for high financing (bonus) firms;
β
7
= good news in post-restatement period earnings for low financing (bonus) firms;
Bad news reflected in earnings
β
12
= bad news in pre-restatement period earnings for high financing (bonus) firms;
β
13
= bad news in pre-restatement period earnings for low financing (bonus) firms;
β
14
= bad news in post-restatement period earnings for high financing (bonus) firms;
β
15
= bad news in post-restatement period earnings for low financing (bonus) firms;
28
Conditional Conservatism – difference between bad news and good news
β
12
β
4
:
Conservatism for high financing (bonus) firms in pre-restatement period;
β
13
β
5
: Conservatism for low financing (bonus) firms in pre-restatement period;
β
14
β
6
:
Conservatism for high financing (bonus) firms in post-restatement period;
β
15
β
7
: Conservatism for low financing (bonus) firms in post-restatement period;
Change in Conditional Conservatism
(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
): Change in conditional conservatism from the pre- to post
restatement period for high financing (bonus) firms;
(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
): Change in conditional conservatism from the pre- to post-
restatement period for low financing (bonus) firms;
H2a (H3a): (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
)
H2b (H3b): [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)]
H2a (H3a) predicts that in the post-restatement period conditional conservatism for
high external financing (high bonus) firms is greater than conditional conservatism for
low external financing (low bonus) firms. Thus, (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
). H2b (H3b)
predicts that the increase in conditional conservatism from the pre- to post-restatement
periods is greater for high external financing (high bonus) firms as compared with low
external financing (low bonus) firms. Therefore, [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)].
3.5 Tests of H4 through H9
I next examine changes in the financial reporting environment as potential
explanations for an increase in conditional conservatism following a financial reporting
failure. I test hypotheses 4 – 9 by extending equation (2) to include variables relating to
changes in the board of directors, audit committee, management, and auditor. I test each
potential determinant separately by estimating a pooled cross-sectional regression that
takes the following general form:
29
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*detyes*POS + β
1
PRE*detno*POS
+ β
2
POST*detyes*POS + β
3
POST*detno*POS
+ β
4
PRE*detyes*R*POS + β
5
PRE*detno*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*detyes*R*POS + β
7
POST*detno*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*detyes*NEG + β
9
PRE*detno*NEG
+ β
10
POST*detyes*NEG + β
11
POST*detno*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*detyes*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*detno*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*detyes*R*NEG + β
15
POST*detno*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
where the variables detyes and detno represent the six potential determinants of a change
in conservatism as discussed for hypotheses 4 – 9. The other variables are defined as
before. detyes is coded as 1 when the determinant variable has increased or changed;
otherwise detyes is coded as 0. detno is coded as 1 when the specific determinant
variable has not increased or changed; otherwise detno is coded as 0. The pooled cross-
sectional regression in equation (5) is estimated six times for each of the six determinant
variables. The six determinant (det) variables partitioned into yes/no conditions are as
follows:
OutDirYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of outside directors from the year
prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
OutDirNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of outside directors from the year
prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACMeetYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of audit committee meetings from
the year prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACMeetNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of audit committee meetings from
the year prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACIndDirYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of independent members on the
audit committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement, 0 otherwise;
30
ACIndDirNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of independent members on the
audit committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACFinExpYes =1 if there is an increase in the number of financial experts on the audit
committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement; 0 otherwise;
ACFinExpNo =1 if there is no increase in the number of financial experts on the audit
committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement; 0 otherwise;
MgmtChgYes = 1 if there is a change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
MgmtChgNo = 1 if there is no change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
AudChgYes = 1 if there is a change in the auditor following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
AudChgNo = 1 if there is no change in the auditor following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
Following the same methodology discussed previously to test H2 and H3, H4-H9 are
tested as follows:
H4a, H5a, H6a, H7a, H8a, H9a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
);
H4b, H5b, H6b, H7b, H8b, H9b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)].
The interpretation of these test specifications is similar to Hypotheses 2 and 3. For
example, H4a specifies that in the post restatement period, conditional conservatism is
greater for firms that increase the number of outside directors. Thus, H4a predicts (β
14
-
β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
). H4b specifies that an increase in conditional conservatism following a
restatement is greater for firms that increase the number of outside directors. Thus, H4b
predicts [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)]. The remaining hypotheses, H5-
H9, are tested using the same methodology just described for H4.
31
In addition to the hypothesis tests described above, I perform some sensitivity
analysis on the data. First, I estimate the primary regression separated into the pre- and
post-SOX periods, as the increased regulatory attention and rules brought forth by SOX
may affect a firm’s decision to report more conservatively following a reporting failure. I
classify firms in the pre-SOX period if the year of the restatement announcement is 1999
or earlier. Thus for a restatement in 1999, the three-year period following the restatement
announcement ends in 2002. (Congress passed SOX in July of 2002.)
Second, in an attempt to increase the sample size, I set the pre and post-restatement
periods to be two years before and after the restatement announcement year. This
sensitivity test is a tradeoff because I sacrifice time-series data in order to increase the
number of sample firms. Sacrificing time-series data makes it more difficult to detect
changes in reporting behavior.
Third, I replace the dichotomous measures for an increase in the number of outside
directors, audit committee members, and financial experts on the audit committee with
dichotomous measures for the level of these variables compared to the sample median in
the third year following the restatement announcement. For example, the variable
OutDir%
is set equal to 1 if a firm’s outside director percentage in the third year
following the restatement announcement is greater than the median outside director
percentage for all samples firms over the same time period. This alternative approach
reflects the level of corporate governance following a restatement, rather than the change.
It is unclear whether a change in corporate governance or the level of corporate
governance following a restatement prompts a change in a firm’s financial reporting.
As a fourth sensitivity analysis, I test all hypotheses using market-adjusted returns in
addition to the raw returns indicated in the research design. Market-adjusted returns
controls for the overall market performance and better isolates the firm-specific news and
performance in returns which proxies for good and bad news periods in the model.
Finally, to control for economic events I use industry-adjusted measures with industry
defined as sample firms with the same two-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC)
code. I measure earnings and returns variables relative to their industry mean. The
industry-adjusted measures control for economic events that may vary across industries
and controls for conservatism that may arise from industry-specific GAAP or regulations.
32
CHAPTER 4
EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND ANALYSIS
This chapter provides a description of the empirical results. First, I describe the
sample selection process, sample attrition, and descriptive statistics of the primary
variables of interest. Next, I present the results of the hypotheses tests described in the
previous chapters. Last, I present the results of sensitivity tests.
4.1 Sample Selection
The initial restatement sample is obtained from the GAO-03-395R Financial
Statement Restatement Database. The GAO database identifies 919 restatements from
the period January 1, 1997 to June 30, 2002. The GAO database provides a
comprehensive list of restatements resulting from accounting irregularities, including
fraud, aggressive accounting, intentional and unintentional misuse of facts, and
misinterpretation or oversight of accounting rules. The GAO database excludes
restatements due to normal business activities, such as mergers and acquisitions, stock
splits, stock dividends, discontinued operations, currency-related issues, change in
business segment definitions, changes due to transfers of management, litigation
settlements, general accounting changes under GAAP, and general bookkeeping errors.
Thus, the GAO database of restatements due to accounting irregularities provides an
appropriate sample to study the impact of restatements on firms’ financial reporting
choices.
Stock return data is obtained from the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP)
data files. Financial data such as earnings, long-term debt, and total assets are obtained
from the Compustat 2004 annual database, which includes the PST, Full Coverage, and
Research files. I use proxy statements or SEC Form 10-K Annual Reports to obtain data
for variables relating to the board of directors, audit committee, management, and
auditor. Finally, a firm’s bonus data is obtained from the Compustat Executive
Compensation database.
33
I summarize sample attrition in Table 4.1. Of the initial sample of 919 restating
firms, 40 firms were eliminated because no ticker symbol or CNUM could be found.
Ninety-three firms were deleted because of multiple restatements. Approximately 72
percent (659 firms) of the initial restatement sample of 919 firms did not have sufficient
returns or financial data from CRSP and Compustat to be included in the final sample.
The missing data does not appear to be clustered in either the pre- or post-restatement
period. The number of firms with missing Compustat data in the pre-restatement period
is comparable to the post-restatement period, with 200 and 174 firms, respectively. In
addition, 48 firms were missing Compustat data in both the pre- and post-restatement
period. This study requires stock and financial data for the three years prior to and the
three years following the restatement announcement year. A likely explanation for the
loss of these firms is due to the fact that many restating firms declare bankruptcy or are
delisted following the restatements. This could potentially lead to a survivorship bias,
which may prevent the results from generalizing to the overall set of publicly traded
firms. Finally, 15 firms were eliminated because their returns and earnings data are
considered outliers with studentized residuals greater than the absolute value of three.
Outliers are observations that are extreme or appear inconsistent with the remaining data.
This leaves a final sample of 112 firms.
4.2 Descriptive Statistics
Table 4.2 presents descriptive data for the sample firms averaged over the six-year
sample period, three years pre and post the restatement announcement year. Panel A of
Table 4.2 provides descriptive statistics regarding the main explanatory variables, and
Panel B provides descriptive statistics for the corporate governance variables used to test
hypotheses 4 through 9.
As presented in Panel A of Table 4.2, the sample firms represent a wide cross-section
of performance and size, but the distribution appears to be skewed towards larger firms.
As for size, total assets range from $6.04 million to $208,504 million with a mean
(median) of $5,005 million ($713.93 million). This skewness towards large firms is
likely a result of the research design of this study where financial data is needed for the
three years prior to and following a restatement announcement, which requires seven
34
consecutive years of financial data. It stands to reason that larger firms are better able to
withstand the negative effects of a restatement and continue in business without being
delisted or declaring bankruptcy. However, this leads to a possible survivorship bias,
which may reduce the external validity of the results.
As presented in Table 4.2, Panel B, I find the mean number of outside directors
2
on
the board in the year prior to the restatement announcement is 6.28, and 6.54 in the third
year following the restatement announcement, a statistically significant difference (t =
1.65, p=0.05). This is consistent with Farber (2005), who finds fraud firms increase the
number of outside directors on the board.
Table 4.2, Panel B also provides descriptive statistics for audit committee variables
and auditor changes
3
. Results indicate that sample firms increased significantly the mean
number of audit committee meetings from 3.40 in the year prior to restatement
announcement to 7.55 in the third year following the restatement announcement (t =
27.23). Results in Table 4.2, Panel B also indicate the sample firms increased the
average number of audit committee members and the average number of outside directors
and financial experts
4
on the audit committee from the year prior to the third year
following the restatement announcement. The mean number of audit committee
members increased from 3.51 to 3.61 (t = 1.66), the mean number of outside directors on
the audit committee increased from 3.29 to 3.56 (t = 4.35), and the mean number of
financial experts on the audit committee increased from 0.74 to 1.38 (t = 11.52).
However, the median values for these variables did not change.
In summary, the changes in the financial reporting environment discussed above are
consistent with previous corporate governance research. However, it is still an empirical
question whether or not these corporate governance changes affect conservatism.
A potential problem with regression analysis is multicollinearity. Multicollinearity
occurs when some of the independent variables are highly correlated. Multicollinearity
produces coefficient estimates that are unstable and have large standard errors. I test for
2
Consistent with Farber (2005), an outside director is defined as a director who is not a present or former
firm employee and whose only formal connection to the firm is service as a director on the board.
3
The number of observations for the variable AudChg is different due to the inclusion of five additional
sample firms with available auditor change data.
4
Following Farber (2005), I define a financial expert as someone who has accounting or financial
management expertise (i.e., CPA, CFO, PFO, CAO, PAO, controller, auditor, accounting or finance
professor).
35
the presence of multicollinearity by examining correlations between the independent
variables and by using the variance inflation factor (VIF). The variance inflation factors
(untabulated) show no significant correlations between the independent variables. I
present the Pearson and Spearman correlation coefficients in table 4.3 for the primary
variables of interest
5
. The correlations between most of the independent variables are
insignificant. For the correlations that are statistically significant, the correlations are
very low. Based on the results of the correlation analysis and the variance inflation
factors, multicollinearity among the independent variables does not appear to be a
problem.
4.3 Tests of Hypothesis 1
Hypothesis 1 predicts that restatement firms increase conditional conservatism
following a financial reporting failure. This hypothesis is tested using a pooled cross-
sectional regression analysis of beginning-of-fiscal year price deflated earnings on
positive and negative returns with pre/post-restatement year interactions.
The regression results for equation (2), which tests hypothesis 1 for the restatement
sample, are presented in Table 4.4. Hypothesis 1 is tested using three alternative returns
measures. In addition to annual raw returns, I also examine equally weighted market-
adjusted and value weighted market-adjusted annual returns. I perform an F-test which
imposes a linear restriction on the coefficients and tests whether the sum of squared
residuals is significantly greater than the sum of squared residuals from the unrestricted
model. The F-test is a test of equality (e.g. (β
1
β
2
) = (β
3
β
4
), even though all of my
hypotheses are directional. Therefore, I present in the tables the differences in
coefficients for both sides of the equation to verify the difference is in the predicted
direction. In panel A, using annual raw returns, the results support hypothesis 1 as
conditional conservatism in the post-restatement period (coefficient = 0.194) is
significantly greater than in the pre-restatement period (coefficient = 0.048), (F-statistic =
8.84, p=0.003).
5
The variable BONUS is omitted from the table because the number of observations is much lower at 360.
I ran a separate correlation analysis including BONUS and find the correlations between BONUS and the
other variables in Table 4.3 are insignificant or very low.
36
Results presented in Panel B of Table 4.4 using equally weighted market-adjusted
annual returns also support hypothesis 1. The coefficients for conditional conservatism
in the pre- and post-restatement periods are 0.026 and 0.160, respectively. The difference
is statistically significant (F-statistic = 12.70, p=0.0004). In panel C of Table 4.4, using
value weighted market-adjusted returns, conditional conservatism in the post-restatement
period (coefficient = 0.203) is significantly greater than in the pre-restatement period
(coefficient = 0.040), (F-statistic = 13.88, p=0.0002). The use of market-adjusted returns
in the regressions provides higher F-statistics and stronger support for H1 than does the
use of annual raw returns. Basu (1997) finds a higher adjusted R
2
using market-adjusted
returns as compared to annual raw returns. I find a higher adjusted R
2
using value-
weighted market-adjusted returns, but not equal-weighted market-adjusted returns. The
use of value-weighted market-adjusted returns likely provides more explanatory power
because it controls for news events that affect overall market performance. As returns are
used to proxy for good and bad news periods, controlling for the overall market
performance will better isolate firm-specific news and performance and thereby reduce
measurement error for the good and bad news dummy variables. In summary, the results
presented in Table 4.4 provide strong support for the first hypothesis. Restating firms
significantly increase conditional conservatism in the three-year period following the
restatement announcement year. These results provide the basis for further investigation
into the underlying reasons or determinants of the increase in conservatism.
4.4 Unconditional Conservatism
As discussed in Chapter 3, I expect to find no change in unconditional conservatism
before and after the restatement, because unconditional conservatism is just a downward
accounting bias. Therefore, I expect managers to be less motivated to change
unconditional conservatism following a restatement. Following Basu (2005), the
intercepts from equation (2) are used as a measure of unconditional conservatism. Basu
(2005) suggests the intercept can be used to measure unconditional conservatism since it
reflects average earnings. Therefore, I expect an insignificant shift in the post-
fraud/restatement period intercepts
from equation (2), which is tested as (β
0
+ β
1
) = (β
2
+
β
3
).
37
As expected, the untabulated results show no significant intercept shift from the pre-
to post-restatement period using all three returns measures. For annual raw returns, (β
0
+
β
1
) = 0.066 and (β
2
+ β
3
) = 0.095, for which the difference is statistically insignificant (F-
statistic =1.84, p=0.18). For equally weighted market-adjust returns, (β
0
+ β
1
) = 0.064
and (β
2
+ β
3
) = 0.091, a statistically insignificant difference (F-statistic = 1.75, p=0.19).
For value weighted market-adjust returns, (β
0
+ β
1
) = 0.073 and (β
2
+ β
3
) = 0.084, a
statistically insignificant difference (F-statistic = 0.31, p=0.58). To the extent the
intercepts from equation (2) capture unconditional conservatism, the results appear
consistent with unconditional conservatism being unaffected by a restatement. This
supports the Ball and Shivakumar (2005) view that unconditional conservatism is just a
downward accounting bias that contracting parties can adjust for ex ante. Thus,
managers have less incentive to increase unconditional conservatism because it does not
enhance contracting efficiency. In contrast, conditional conservatism does have the
potential to improve contracting efficiency for both debt and compensation contracting,
which I test next.
4.5 Tests of Hypotheses 2a and 2b
The second hypothesis examines debt contracting as an explanation for the increase in
conditional conservatism following a restatement. This hypothesis predicts the level and
change in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for firms where
debt contracting is more important. To measure the importance of debt contracting to a
firm, I use the ex ante demand for external financing measure from Dechow et al. (1996).
Table 4.5 presents the regression results for equation (3) pertaining to hypothesis 2.
In Panel A, conditional conservatism for high financing firms in the post-restatement
period (coefficient = 0.456) is significantly greater than for low financing firms
(coefficient = 0.192) (F-statistic = 5.45, p=0.02). However, the results in Panel A do not
support H2b, as the change in conditional conservatism from the pre- to post restatement
period for high financing firms is not significantly different than the change for low
financing firms (F-statistic = 2.52, p=0.113). The results using annual raw returns
suggest the level, but not necessarily the change, in conditional conservatism is greater
for firms that have a stronger need for debt financing.
38
Panel B of Table 4.5 provides the results of testing hypothesis 2 using market-
adjusted returns. The results using market-adjusted returns provide strong support for
hypothesis 2. In Panel B using equal weighted market-adjusted returns, H2a is strongly
supported as conditional conservatism in the post-restatement period is significantly
greater for high financing firms (coefficient =0.484) than for low financing firms
(coefficient = 0.149). This difference is highly significant (F-statistic = 8.33, p=0.004).
H2b is also supported using equal weighted market-adjusted returns at the 10% level (F-
statistic = 2.89, p=0.09). The use of value weighted market-adjusted returns in the model
provides the strongest support for hypothesis 2. In Panel B, conditional conservatism
following a restatement is significantly greater for high financing firms (coefficient =
0.702) as compared with low financing firms (coefficient = 0.184). The difference is
highly significant (F-statistic = 13.76, p=0.0002). Furthermore, the change in conditional
conservatism from the pre- to post-restatement period for high financing firms is
significantly greater than for low financing firms (F-statistic = 13.33, p=0.0003).
The results in Table 4.5 provide strong support for the second hypothesis. The results
suggest that both the level and change in conditional conservatism following a
restatement is greater for firms where debt contracting is more important. These results
are consistent with the contracting explanation of conservatism brought forth in Watts
(2003). The results suggest restating firms attempt to restore the credibility of their
financial reports and the trust of the contracting parties by reporting more conservatively.
Conservative reporting constrains management’s opportunistic behavior and protects the
interests of the contracting parties.
4.6 Tests of Hypotheses 3a and 3b
Hypothesis 3 examines compensation contracting as an explanation for an increase in
conditional conservatism following a restatement. The third hypothesis predicts that the
more important compensation contracting is to a firm, the more conservative it will be
following a reporting failure. I measure the importance of compensation contracting to a
firm by using the variable Bonus from the Compustat Executive Compensation database.
I measure the variable BONUS used in equation (4) as the average bonus of the firm’s
executives scaled by end-of-year total assets (Compustat Data 6). The bonus hypothesis
39
predicts managers of firms with bonus plans are more likely to bias accounting numbers
upward to increase their compensation (Watts and Zimmerman 1986). Watts (2003a)
suggests that conservatism reduces the likelihood that management overstates earnings
and net assets in order to take excess compensation. Therefore, I predict restating firms
with earnings-based managerial compensation plans are more likely to report
conservatively in order to signal that the financial reports are reliable and trustworthy.
The regression results for equation (4) pertaining to hypothesis 3 are presented in
Table 4.6. Panel A of Table 4.6 presents the results using annual raw returns.
Surprisingly, neither H3a nor H3b are supported (F-statistic = 0.48 and 0.14). However,
in Panel B of Table 4.6, results based on market-adjusted returns provide strong support
for hypothesis 3. Using equal weighted market-adjusted returns, H3a is significant (F-
statistic = 7.41, p=0.007), and H3b is significant (F-statistic = 8.24, p=0.004). Using
value weighted market-adjusted returns, H3a and H3b are significant at the 5% and 1%
levels with F-statistic = 4.45 and 7.32, respectively.
The use of market-adjusted returns in the model testing H3 appears to provide a better
fit and higher explanatory power. The adjusted R
2
s in Panel B of Table 4.6 using the two
measures of market-adjusted returns are 25.71% and 25.74%, while the adjusted R
2
using
annual raw returns is 22.6%. As discussed previously, the use of market-adjusted returns
in testing H1 and H2 provides higher F-statistics and stronger support than does the use
of annual raw returns. Overall, it appears that market-adjusted returns are better at
capturing the level and changes in conditional conservatism for the sample firms. This is
likely because removing the effect of news that affects overall market performance better
isolates firm-specific news in returns which reduces the measurement error in the good
and bad news dummy variables used in the model.
Thus, to the extent that using market-adjusted returns captures the Basu (1997)
measure of conditional conservatism, hypothesis 3 is supported. The results suggest that
both the level and change in conditional conservatism following a restatement are greater
for firms where compensation contracting is more important. The results for both
hypotheses 2 and 3 appear to be consistent with the contracting explanation of
conservatism put forth by Watts (2003).
40
4.7 Tests of Hypotheses 4a and 4b
Hypotheses 4 through 9 examine several corporate governance variables as possible
explanations for an increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
Hypothesis 4 posits firms with more outside directors following a reporting failure report
more conservatively.
The results of equation (5) pertaining to hypothesis 4 are presented in Table 4.7. In
Panel A using annual returns, the F-test is significant at the 10% level (F-statistic = 3.11,
p=0.078), but is not in the predicted direction. Therefore, H4a is not supported. Panel A
also shows no support for H4b (F-statistic = 1.04, p=0.308). In Panel B using market-
adjusted returns, neither H4a nor H4b are supported.
Therefore, the results from Table 4.7 do not support hypothesis 4. I am unable to
document any consistent relationship between an increase in the number of outside
directors on the board and the level or change in conditional conservatism following a
restatement. This is not too surprising since the increase in the average number of
outside directors following a restatement was very small. As reported in Table 4.2, the
average number of outside directors increased from 6.28 to 6.54 following the
restatement. In addition, the median number of outside directors remained at 6 following
the restatement.
4.8 Tests of Hypotheses 5a and 5b
Hypotheses 5 through 7 examine whether certain audit committee characteristics
explain a change in conditional conservatism following a restatement. Specifically, I
predict an audit committee that meets more frequently, is more independent, and has
more financial expertise following a reporting failure demands more conservative
financial reporting.
Hypothesis 5 predicts that the level and change in conditional conservatism following
a restatement is greater for firms that increase the number of audit committee meetings
following a restatement. The results for equation (5) pertaining to hypothesis 5 are
presented in Table 4.8. In Panel A, the results do not support hypotheses 5a or 5b as the
F-statistics are 0.33 and 0.29, respectively. In Panel B, the results using equal weighted
market-adjusted returns also do not support hypotheses 5a or 5b as the F-statistics are
41
0.32 and 1.54, respectively. However, the results in Panel B of Table 4.8 using value
weighted market-adjusted returns do strongly support hypothesis 5. H5a and H5b are
both significant at the 5% level, with F-statistic =5.19 for H5a and F-statistic =4.25 for
H5b.
In summary, the results are mixed for hypothesis 5 concerning the relation between
conservatism and the frequency of audit committee meetings. This hypothesis is strongly
supported using value weighted market-adjusted returns; however, the results using equal
weighted market-adjusted and annual returns do not support hypothesis 5.
4.9 Tests of Hypotheses 6a and 6b
The sixth hypothesis predicts the level and change in conditional conservatism
following a restatement is greater for firms that increase the number of independent
directors on the audit committee. Table 4.9 presents the regression results pertaining to
the tests of hypothesis 6. In Panel A using annual returns, the results are insignificant and
do not support hypotheses 6a or 6b. Panel B using market-adjusted returns also yields
insignificant results.
The results from Table 4.9 do not support hypothesis 6. There is no significant
relationship between an increase in the number of outside directors on the audit
committee and the level or change in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
The lack of results may be explained by the small increase in the mean number of outside
directors on the audit committee following a restatement. The mean number of outside
directors on the audit committee as presented in Panel B of Table 4.2 increased from 3.29
to 3.56, while the median remained the same at 3.
4.10 Tests of Hypotheses 7a and 7b
The seventh hypothesis predicts the level and change in conditional conservatism
following a restatement is greater for firms that increase the number of financial experts
on the audit committee.
The results of equation (5) pertaining to hypothesis 7 are presented in Table 4.10. In
Panel A using annual returns, both H7a and H7b are not supported. Likewise, in Panel B
using equal weighted market-adjusted returns, both H7a and H7b are not supported with
42
F-statistics of 1.48 and 2.17, respectively. However, Panel B using value weighted
market-adjusted returns does provide support for hypothesis 7. Both H7a and H7b are
supported at the 5% level with F-statistics of 5.18 and 4.55, respectively.
These results are similar to the results for hypothesis 3, in that annual returns provide
insignificant results, but market-adjusted returns provide strong support for the
hypothesis. As discussed previously, it appears using market-adjusted returns
(particularly with the value weighted index) in the model improves the fit and increases
the explanatory power of the model. This can be seen in Table 4.10 where the value
weighted model has the highest adjusted R
2
(17.10%).
4.11 Tests of Hypotheses 8a and 8b
The eighth hypothesis examines a change in top management
6
as a potential
explanation for a change in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
Approximately 63% (64 out of 102 firms) of the sample firms experienced a change in
top management. This change in top management is consistent with Desai et al. (2006),
who find that 60 percent of restatement firms experience turnover of at least one top
manager in the two years following the restatement.
Table 4.11 presents the regression results that test hypothesis 8. In Panel A using
annual returns, neither H8a (F-statistic = 2.00, p=0.158) nor H8b are supported (F-
statistic = 1.18, p=0.278). In Panel B of Table 4.11 using market-adjusted returns, the
results are all insignificant. Therefore, the results from Table 4.11 do not support
hypothesis 8. There appears to be no significant association between a change in top
management and a change in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
4.12 Tests of Hypotheses 9a and 9b
The ninth hypothesis examines a change in auditor as a potential explanation for the
level and change in conditional conservatism following a restatement. Empirical studies
find that auditors can mitigate their litigation risk by requiring their clients to report more
conservatively (e.g. Cahan & Zhang 2006; Krishnan 2005). Therefore, I predict the new
6
Following Desai et al. (2006), top management is defined as Chairman, CEO, and/or President.
43
auditor of a restating firm to demand more conservative reporting in order to protect their
reputation and reduce the likelihood of litigation.
I find approximately 32% (34 out of 107 firms) of the sample firms experienced a
change in auditor. This is comparable to Farber (2005), who finds 25 percent of fraud
firms switch audit firms. The results from Table 4.12 are all statistically insignificant and
do not support hypothesis 9. Thus, I find no evidence of an association between a change
in auditor and the level or change in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
4.13 Sensitivity Analysis
As a sensitivity analysis, I estimate equation (2) for the pre- and post-SOX periods, as
the increased regulatory attention and rules brought forth by SOX may affect a firm’s
decision to report more conservatively following a reporting failure. I classify firms in
the pre-SOX period if the year of the restatement announcement is year 1999 or earlier.
Thus for a restatement in 1999, the third year following the restatement announcement is
2002. Since Congress passed SOX in July of 2002, the majority of the three year period
following a 1999 restatement is pre-SOX.
The results of separating the equation (2) regression into pre- and post-SOX periods
are presented in Table 4.13. Of the 112 sample firms, 45 firms (270 observations) are in
the pre-SOX period and 67 firms (402 observations) are in the post-SOX period. In Panel
A using annual returns, hypothesis one is supported in the pre-SOX period with F-
statistic = 3.59 (p=0.059). In Panels B and C using equally and value weighted market-
adjusted returns, hypothesis one is strongly supported in the pre-SOX period with F-
statistics of 6.79 and 5.38, respectively. These results suggest that firms significantly
increase conditional conservatism in the three year period following the restatement
announcement prior to the passage of SOX. As for the post-SOX period, I find mixed
results as hypothesis one is only supported with the use of value weighted market-
adjusted returns (F-statistic = 3.41, p = 0.066). Importantly, the primary results of the
study do not appear to be driven by the passage of SOX.
In an attempt to increase the sample size, I set the pre and post-restatement periods to
be two years before and after the restatement announcement year. This results in an
additional 84 sample firms, bringing the total sample firms to 196. This robustness test is
44
a tradeoff because I sacrifice time-series data in order to increase the number of sample
firms. Sacrificing time-series data makes it more difficult to detect changes in reporting
behavior. I retest the first two hypotheses using the larger sample size of 196 firms. In
untabulated results, both hypotheses are still supported using market-adjusted returns.
For the test of H1, the F-statistics using both industry-adjusted and market-adjusted
returns are statistically significant (Equal weighted: F-statistic = 5.97, p=0.015; Value
weighted: F-statistic = 7.02, p=0.008). H2a is supported at the 10% significance level
using equal-weighted market-adjusted returns (F-statistic = 3.09, p=0.079) and at the 5%
level using value-weighted market-adjusted returns (F-statistic = 4.62, p=0.032). H2b is
supported at the 10% significance level using equal-weighted market-adjusted returns (F-
statistic = 3.62, p=0.058) and at the 5% level using value-weighted market-adjusted
returns (F-statistic = 6.32, p=0.012).
I set the pre and post-restatement periods to be two years before and after the
restatement announcement year to test hypothesis 3. This results in 29 additional firms
for a total of 89 firms. Surprisingly, the untabulated results are statistically insignificant
for the tests of H3a and H3b. Therefore, the results for H3 appear to be less robust.
As another sensitivity test, I replace the variable OUTDIR which is set equal to 1 if
there is an increase in the number of outside directors from the year prior to the third year
following the restatement with a measure of the firm’s outside director percentage. The
variable OUTDIR% is set equal to 1 if a firm’s outside director percentage in the third
year following the restatement announcement is greater than the median outside director
percentage for all sample firms over the same time period. This alternative measure tests
the relative level of this variable, rather than the absolute change. The level may be a
better measure as a firm with a large number of outside directors on the board may be
forced to report more conservatively following a restatement, even if the number of
outside directors did not increase.
The results of using the outside director percentage variable in equation (5) are
presented in Table 4.14. The results in Table 4.14 are all insignificant and do not support
hypothesis 4. This is consistent with the results from Table 4.7 using the variable
OUTDIR. Thus, results still fail to support a relationship between outside directors on
the board and the level or change in conditional conservatism following a restatement.
45
I also test hypothesis 5 using an alternative measure for audit committee meetings.
Instead of using a dichotomous variable for an increase in the number of meetings, I
measure the variable ACMEET
t+3
, which is set equal to 1 if the firm’s number of audit
committee meetings in the third year following the restatement announcement is greater
than the median number of audit committee meetings for all sample firms over the same
time period. The results using this alternative measure of audit committee meetings are
presented in Table 4.15. The results are all insignificant except for the test of hypothesis
5a using equal weighted market-adjusted return (F-statistic = 9.54, p<0.001). However,
this significant result is not in the predicted direction. Thus, the results using this
alternative measure for audit committee meetings do not support hypothesis 5.
I also test the seventh hypothesis by using an alternative measure for the financial
expertise of the audit committee. I set the variable ACFINEXP% equal to 1 if the firm’s
percentage of audit committee members who are financial experts during the third year
following the restatement is greater than the median percentage for all sample firms for
the same time period. The results using this alternative measure are presented in Table
4.16. The results using all three returns measures are insignificant. Thus, the results
using this alternative measure for financial expertise on the audit committee provide no
support for hypothesis 7.
Finally, I use industry-adjusted earnings and returns variables to control for economic
events that may vary across industries. This approach also controls for conservatism that
may arise from industry-specific GAAP or regulations. I measure earnings and returns
variables relative to industry mean for all sample firms in the firm’s industry. I define
industry using the two-digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code.
The results using the industry-adjusted measures are reported in Table 4.17. The first
hypothesis is still supported using industry-adjusted EPS and annual returns (F-statistic =
5.97, p<0.007). However, the explanatory power of the model decreases significantly
with an Adjusted R
2
of 3.93%. The same model without adjusting for industry effects
has an Adjusted R
2
of 13.28% (Table 4.4, Panel A). In untabulated results using equal
and value weighted market-adjusted returns, hypothesis one is not supported after
adjusting for industry. Adjusting for both the market and industry produces a model with
insignificant explanatory power. The F-statistics for the models using both industry-
46
adjusted and market-adjusted returns are insignificant (Equal weighted: F-statistic = 0.54,
p=0.8274; Value weighted: F-statistic = 0.58, p=0.7964).
47
Table 4.1
Sample Attrition
No. of Firms
Initial Restatement Sample
919
Less:
Firms with no Ticker Symbol or CNUM 40
Firms with more than one restatement 93
Firms with missing Compustat data 138
Firms with missing Compustat data in post-restatement period 174
Firms with missing Compustat data in pre-restatement period 200
Firms with missing Compustat data in both pre- and post-
restatement periods 48
Firms with missing CRSP data 99
Outliers – firms with studentized residuals greater than +/-3 15
(807)
Final Restatement Sample
112
The initial restatement sample is obtained from the GAO-03-395R Financial Statement
Restatement Database. The GAO database identifies 919 restatements from the period
January 1, 1997 to June 30, 2002.
A significant portion of the missing data items results from the need to obtain stock and
financial data for the three years prior to and the three years following the restatement
announcement year. In addition, capital expenditures from the fourth year prior to the
restatement announcement year are needed to compute the ex ante demand for external
financing measure from Dechow et al. (1996).
48
Table 4.2
Descriptive Statistics
Panel A: Main Explanatory Variables
Standard
Variable
a
n Mean Deviation Median Min. Max.
Earnings ($million) 672 151.043 501.751 18.019 -4,895.0 4,220.0
Earnings per share 672 0.899 2.816 0.740 -9.0 35.83
EPS/Price 672 0.022 0.092 0.035 -0.421 0.352
Return 672 0.220 0.899 0.099 -0.860 14.192
EWMAR 672 0.065 0.860 -0.061 -1.293 13.646
VWMAR 672 0.117 0.874 -0.015 -1.039 13.930
Total Assets ($million) 672 5,005 12,773 713.93 6.04 208,504
Debt ($million) 672 1,224 2,614 79.23 0 22,792
Bonus ($thousand) 360 333.441 403.387 211.225 0 4,584.00
Bonus/Total Assets 360 0.242 0.776 0.072 0 9.295
FreeC
t-1
112 -0.030 0.848 0.055 -7.904 1.850
Panel B: Corporate Governance Variables
Standard
Variable
a
n Mean Deviation Median Min. Max.
Board of Directors
Dir
t-1
102 8.98 3.07 9.0 4.0 17.0
Dir
t+3
102 9.04 2.66 8.5 4.0 16.0
OutDir
t-1
102 6.28 2.88 6.0 1.0 15.0
OutDir
t+3
102 6.54 2.53 6.0 2.0 13.0
Audit Committee
ACMeet
t-1
102 3.40 1.68 3.0 1.0 9.0
ACMeet
t+3
102 7.55 3.37 7.0 1.0 18.0
ACMem
t-1
102 3.51 1.22 3.0 2.0 8.0
ACMem
t+3
102 3.61 0.81 3.0 3.0 6.0
ACIndDir
t-1
102 3.29 1.26 3.0 1.0 8.0
ACIndDir
t+3
102 3.56 0.82 3.0 2.0 6.0
ACFinExp
t-1
102 0.74 0.85 1.0 0 3.0
ACFinExp
t+3
102 1.38 1.05 1.0 0 5.0
MgmtChg 102 0.627 0.484 1.0 0 1.0
AudChg 107 0.318 0.466 0 0 1.0
49
Table 4.2 (Continued)
a
Variables are averaged over the six-year sample period (three years before and after
restatement announcement year) and are defined as follows:
Earnings are net income before extraordinary items (Compustat Data 18);
Earnings per share (EPS) is Compustat Data 58;
Price is beginning of fiscal year stock price;
Returns are the compounded monthly returns beginning nine months prior to fiscal year
end to three months after fiscal year end;
EWMAR are computed as the difference between the annual return and the mean return of
all firms from the CRSP equally-weighted market index.
VWMAR are computed as the difference between the annual return and the mean return of
all firms from the CRSP value-weighted market index.
Total Assets is Compustat Data 6;
Debt is total long-term debt (Compustat Data 9);
Bonus is measured as the average bonus of the firm’s executives in each sample year
scaled by end-of-year total assets (Compustat Data 6). Bonus data is obtained from the
Compustat Executive Compensation database and is defined by Compustat as “the dollar
value of a bonus (cash and non-cash) earned by the named executive officer during the
fiscal year”;
Bonus/Total Assets is variable Bonus divided by end-of-year total assets (Compustat Data
6);
FreeC
t-1
=
2-t
2- t to4-t1-t
AssetsCurrent
esexpenditur capital Average - operations fromCash
Dir
t-1
is the number of directors on the board in the year prior to the restatement year;
Dir
t+3
is the number of directors on the board in the third year following the restatement
year;
OutDir
t-1
is the number of outside directors on the board in the year prior to the
restatement year. An outside director is defined as a director who is not a present or
former firm employee and whose only formal connection to the firm is service as a
director on the board;
OutDir
t+3
is the number of outside directors on the board in the third year following the
restatement year;
ACMeet
t-1
is the number of audit committee meetings in the year prior to the restatement
year;
ACMeet
t+3
is the number of audit committee meetings in the third year following the
restatement year;
ACMem
t-1
is the number of audit committee members in the year prior to the restatement
year;
ACMem
t+3
is the number of audit committee members in the third year following the
restatement year;
50
Table 4.2 (Continued)
a
Variable definitions are as follows (continued):
ACIndDir
t-1
is the number of outside directors on the audit committee in the year prior to
the restatement year.
ACIndDir
t+3
is the number of outside directors on the audit committee in the third year
following the restatement year;
ACFinExp
t-1
is the number of financial experts on the audit committee in the year prior to
the restatement year. A financial expert is defined as someone who has accounting or
financial management expertise (i.e. CPA, CFO, PFO, CAO, PAO, controller, auditor,
accounting or finance professor);
ACFinExp
t+3
is the number of financial experts on the audit committee in the third year
following the restatement year;
MgmtChg is coded 1 if there is a change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise. Top management is defined as Chairman, CEO, and/or President;
AudChg is coded 1 if there is a change in auditor following the restatement, 0 otherwise.
51
Table 4.3
Pearson (above the diagonal) and Spearman (below the diagonal) Correlation
Matrix for the Primary Variables
a
(n=612)
EPS/
Price
Return EXT
FIN
OutDir AC
Meet
AC
IndDir
AC
FinExp
Mgmt
Chg
Aud
Chg
EPS/Price
0.141
0.001
-0.177
<0.0001
0.051
0.206
0.063
0.121
-0.010
0.797
0.045
0.270
-0.006
0.884
0.008
0.852
Return
0.307
<0.0001
0.013
0.744
0.027
0.508
0.001
0.985
0.034
0.407
0.020
0.617
-0.034
0.395
-0.034
0.409
ExtFin
-0.124
0.002
0.028
0.487
-0.134
0.001
-0.029
0.468
-0.030
0.457
0.064
0.114
-0.152
0.000
0.004
0.931
OutDir
0.026
0.520
-0.043
0.290
-0.134
0.001
0.036
0.373
0.355
<0.0001
0.209
<0.0001
0.016
0.692
-0.144
0.000
ACMeet
0.077
0.056
0.015
0.715
-0.029
0.468
0.036
0.373
-0.115
0.005
0.178
<0.0001
-0.112
0.006
0.060
0.140
ACIndDir
-0.001
0.978
-0.015
0.718
-0.030
0.457
0.355
<0.0001
-0.115
0.005
0.058
0.154
-0.004
0.920
-0.003
0.941
ACFinExp
0.025
0.534
0.011
0.793
0.064
0.114
0.209
<0.0001
0.178
<0.0001
0.058
0.154
0.101
0.012
-0.041
0.312
MgmtChg
-0.006
0.875
0.013
0.747
-0.152
0.000
0.016
0.692
-0.112
0.006
-0.004
0.920
0.101
0.012
-0.025
0.532
AudChg
0.013
0.752
-0.022
0.596
0.004
0.931
-0.144
<0.0001
0.060
0.140
-0.003
0.941
-0.041
0.312
-0.025
0.532
The p-values are reported below each correlation coefficient.
a
Variable definitions are as follows:
EPS = Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58);
Price = beginning of fiscal year stock price;
Returns = the compounded monthly returns beginning nine months prior to fiscal
year end to three months after fiscal year end;
EXTFIN = 1 if firm’s FreeC
t-1
is less than -0.5, and 0 otherwise. Where FreeC
t-1
is
defined as:
FreeC
t-1
=
2-t
2- t to4-t1-t
AssetsCurrent
esexpenditur capital Average - operations fromCash
OutDir = 1 if there is an increase in the number of outside directors from the year
prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise. An outside
director is defined as a director who is not a present or former firm
employee and whose only formal connection to the firm is service as a
director on the board.
52
Table 4.3 (Continued)
a
Variable definitions are as follows (continued):
ACMeet = 1 if there is an increase in the number of audit committee meetings from
the year prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACIndDir = 1 if there is an increase in the number of independent members on the
audit committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACFinExp= 1 if there is an increase in the number of financial experts on the audit
committee from the year prior to the third year following the restatement;
0 otherwise. A financial expert is defined as someone who has accounting
or financial management expertise (i.e. CPA, CFO, PFO, CAO, PAO,
controller, auditor, accounting or finance professor);
MgmtChg = 1 if there is a change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise. Top management is defined as Chairman, CEO, and/or
President;
AudChg = 1 if there is a change in auditor following the restatement, 0 otherwise.
53
Table 4.4
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement for
the Period 1994–2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*POS + β
1
PRE*NEG + β
2
POST*POS + β
3
POST*NEG
+ β
4
PRE*POS*R
it
+ β
5
PRE*NEG*R
it
+ β
6
POST*POS*R
it
+ β
7
POST*NEG*R
it
+ ε
it
, (2)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 672)
β
0
β
1
β
2
β
3
β
4
β
5
β
6
β
7
Adj. R
2
Coefficients 0.027 0.039 0.038 0.057 0.015 0.063 -0.004 0.190
13.28%
(t-value)
3.29* 3.00* 5.15* 4.19*
1.70*** 1.79***
-0.78 5.79*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.194
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.048
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 8.84 p=0.003
Panel B: Equally Weighted Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 672)
β
0
β
1
β
2
β
3
β
4
β
5
β
6
β
7
Adj. R
2
Coefficients 0.022 0.042 0.037 0.054 0.022 0.048 -0.003 0.157 12.43%
(t-value)
2.53** 3.72* 4.25* 5.12* 2.19** 1.99** -0.45 6.04*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.160
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.026
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 12.70 p=0.0004
54
Table 4.4 (Continued)
Panel C: Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 672)
β
0
β
1
β
2
β
3
β
4
β
5
β
6
β
7
Adj. R
2
Coefficients 0.031 0.042 0.038 0.046 0.015 0.055 -0.003 0.200 13.72%
(t-value) 3.23* 3.70* 5.17* 3.95* 1.48 2.10** -0.63 6.00*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.203
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.040
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 13.88 p=0.0002
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
55
Table 4.5
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on the Demand for External Financing for the
Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*EXTFINHI*POS + β
1
PRE*EXTFINLO*POS
+ β
2
POST*EXTFINHI*POS + β
3
POST*EXTFINLO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*EXTFINHI*R*POS + β
5
PRE*EXTFINLO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*EXTFINHI*R*POS + β
7
POST*EXTFINLO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*EXTFINHI*NEG + β
9
PRE*EXTFINLO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*EXTFINHI*NEG + β
11
POST*EXTFINLO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*EXTFINHI*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*EXTFINLO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*EXTFINHI*R*NEG + β
15
POST*EXTFINLO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (3)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 672)
Adj. R
2
Coefficient t-value
β
0
-0.065 -1.77*** 20.62%
β
1
0.032 4.02*
β
2
0.157 3.29*
β
3
0.042 5.72*
β
4
0.006 0.16
β
5
0.018 2.05**
β
6
-0.275 -5.49*
β
7
-0.001 -0.20
β
8
-0.041 -0.83
β
9
0.044 3.42*
β
10
0.025 0.59
β
11
0.059 4.35*
β
12
0.032 0.25
β
13
0.065 1.87***
β
14
0.181 1.89***
β
15
0.191 5.75*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for high financing firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.456
Conservatism for high financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.026
Conservatism for low financing firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.192
Conservatism for low financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.047
Test H2a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 5.45 p=0.02
H2b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 2.52 p=0.113
56
Table 4.5 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 672)
Equal Weighte
d
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
-0.144 -4.21* 20.66% -0.126 -2.35** 21.84%
β
1
0.034 3.86* 0.037 4.05*
β
2
-0.025 -0.54 0.072 2.04**
β
3
0.045 5.42* 0.043 6.00*
β
4
0.080 2.11** 0.061 1.18
β
5
0.021 2.05** 0.018 1.82***
β
6
-0.191 -3.17* -0.245 -5.24*
β
7
-0.002 -0.28 -0.001 -0.17
β
8
0.051 0.91 -0.055 -1.31
β
9
0.042 3.83* 0.048 4.32*
β
10
0.092 2.35** 0.135 2.49**
β
11
0.052 4.95* 0.042 3.65*
β
12
0.145 1.22 -0.025 -0.27
β
13
0.044 1.87*** 0.061 2.35**
β
14
0.293 3.06* 0.457 3.58*
β
15
0.147 5.75* 0.183 5.54*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for high financing firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.484
Conservatism for high financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.065
Conservatism for low financing firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.149
Conservatism for low financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.023
Test H2a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 8.33 p=0.004
H2b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 2.89 p=0.090
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for high financing firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.702
Conservatism for high financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.086
Conservatism for low financing firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.184
Conservatism for low financing firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.043
Test H2a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 13.76 p=0.0002
H2b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 13.33 p=0.0003
57
Table 4.5 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
EXTFINHI = 1 if firm’s FreeC
t-1
is less than -0.5, and 0 otherwise. Where FreeC
t-1
is
defined as:
FreeC
t-1
=
2-t
2- t to4-t1-t
AssetsCurrent
esexpenditur capital Average - operations fromCash
EXTFINLO = 1 if firm’s FreeC
t-1
is greater than or equal to -0.5, and 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
58
Table 4.6
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Bonus Compensation for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*BONUSHI*POS + β
1
PRE*BONUSLO*POS
+ β
2
POST*BONUSHI*POS + β
3
POST*BONUSLO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*BONUSHI*R*POS + β
5
PRE*BONUSLO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*BONUSHI*R*POS + β
7
POST*BONUSLO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*BONUSHI*NEG + β
9
PRE*BONUSLO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*BONUSHI*NEG + β
11
POST*BONUSLO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*BONUSHI*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*BONUSLO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*BONUSHI*R*NEG + β
15
POST*BONUSLO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (4)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 360)
Adj. R
2
Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.032 3.01* 22.6%
β
1
0.037 3.53*
β
2
0.070 5.77*
β
3
0.024 1.82***
β
4
0.020 1.67***
β
5
-0.005 -0.26
β
6
-0.023 -1.26
β
7
-0.026 -1.31
β
8
0.022 0.97
β
9
0.013 0.68
β
10
0.028 1.43
β
11
0.039 2.34**
β
12
-0.050 -0.67
β
13
0.022 0.44
β
14
0.047 0.91
β
15
0.097 2.08**
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for high bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.070
Conservatism for high bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.070
Conservatism for low bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.123
Conservatism for low bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.027
Test H3a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.48 p=0.489
H3b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.14 p=0.710
59
Table 4.6 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 360)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.026 2.30** 25.71% 0.035 2.97* 25.74%
β
1
0.044 3.73* 0.044 3.55*
β
2
0.060 4.62* 0.071 5.89*
β
3
0.024 1.41 0.017 1.40
β
4
0.028 2.01** 0.022 1.59
β
5
-0.022 -1.11 -0.022 -1.08
β
6
-0.020 -0.90 -0.028 -1.39
β
7
-0.029 -1.17 -0.018 -0.86
β
8
0.045 2.34** 0.033 1.98**
β
9
0.029 2.05** 0.036 2.42**
β
10
0.095 6.52* 0.076 4.64*
β
11
0.016 1.37 0.030 1.92***
β
12
0.007 0.15 -0.009 -0.19
β
13
0.039 1.37 0.055 1.54
β
14
0.187 5.38* 0.240 4.48*
β
15
0.019 0.57 0.078 1.43
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for high bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.207
Conservatism for high bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.021
Conservatism for low bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.048
Conservatism for low bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.061
Test H3a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 7.41 p=0.007
H3b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 8.24 p=0.004
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for high bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.268
Conservatism for high bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.031
Conservatism for low bonus firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.096
Conservatism for low bonus firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.077
Test H3a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 4.45 p=0.036
H3b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 7.32 p=0.007
60
Table 4.6 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
BONUSHI = 1 if a firm’s dollar value of a bonus is greater than the median bonus of all
sample firms, otherwise BONUSHI = 0. BONUS is measured as the
average bonus of the firm’s executives scaled by end-of-year total assets
(Compustat Data 6). Bonus data is obtained from the Compustat
Executive Compensation database and is defined by Compustat as “the
dollar value of a bonus (cash and non-cash) earned by the named
executive officer during the fiscal year”;
BONUSLO = 1 if a firm’s dollar value of a bonus is less than the median bonus of all
sample firms, otherwise BONUSLO = 0;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
61
Table 4.7
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Outside Directors for the Period
1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*OUTDIRYES*POS + β
1
PRE*OUTDIRNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*OUTDIRYES*POS + β
3
POST*OUTDIRNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*OUTDIRYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*OUTDIRNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*OUTDIRYES*R*POS + β
7
POST*OUTDIRNO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*OUTDIRYES*NEG + β
9
PRE*OUTDIRNO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*OUTDIRYES*NEG + β
11
POST*OUTDIRNO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*OUTDIRYES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*OUTDIRNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*OUTDIRYES*R*NEG + β
15
POST*OUTDIRNO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.034 2.82* 15.48%
β
1
0.025 2.23**
β
2
0.052 4.73*
β
3
0.024 2.01**
β
4
0.017 1.48
β
5
0.010 0.71
β
6
-0.008 -1.35
β
7
0.017 1.23
β
8
0.046 2.29**
β
9
0.040 2.09**
β
10
0.025 1.18
β
11
0.077 4.26*
β
12
0.068 1.25
β
13
0.076 1.46
β
14
0.102 2.02**
β
15
0.245 5.78*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.110
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.051
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.228
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.066
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 3.11 p=0.078
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.04 p=0.308
62
Table 4.7 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.031 2.22** 15.54% 0.027 1.75*** 16.50%
β
1
0.018 1.51 0.037 2.95*
β
2
0.044 3.42* 0.040 3.70*
β
3
0.016 1.20 0.029 2.52**
β
4
0.021 1.68*** 0.023 1.81***
β
5
0.022 1.33 0.001 0.08
β
6
-0.007 -1.21 -0.006 -1.08
β
7
0.040 2.60* 0.022 1.60
β
8
0.044 2.59* 0.052 3.22*
β
9
0.050 3.22* 0.039 2.41**
β
10
0.050 2.91* 0.046 2.58*
Β
11
0.062 4.53* 0.050 3.26*
Β
12
0.035 1.03 0.055 1.51
Β
13
0.082 2.31** 0.066 1.75***
Β
14
0.123 2.85* 0.154 3.07*
Β
15
0.193 5.94* 0.246 5.70*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.130
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.014
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.153
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.060
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.17 p=0.682
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.09 p=0.759
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.160
Conservatism for OutDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.032
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.224
Conservatism for OutDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.065
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.88 p=0.348
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.12 p=0.724
63
Table 4.7 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
OutDirYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of outside directors from the year
prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise. An
outside director is defined as a director who is not a present or former
firm employee and whose only formal connection to the firm is service
as a director on the board;
OutDirNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of outside directors from the year
prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
64
Table 4.8
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Audit Committee Meetings for the
Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*ACMEETYES*POS + β
1
PRE*ACMEETNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*ACMEETYES*POS + β
3
POST*ACMEETNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*ACMEETYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*ACMEETNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*ACMEETYES*R*POS + β
7
POST*ACMEETNO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*ACMEETYES*NEG + β
9
PRE*ACMEETNO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*ACMEETYES*NEG + β
11
POST*ACMEETNO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*ACMEETYES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*ACMEETNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*ACMEETYES*R*NEG + β
15
POST*ACMEETNO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.036 1.85*** 14.79%
β
1
0.048 1.68***
β
2
0.055 2.86*
β
3
0.038 1.13
β
4
0.023 1.20
β
5
0.066 0.89
β
6
-0.013 -0.92
β
7
0.213 2.61*
β
8
-0.002 -0.29
β
9
-0.002 -0.81
β
10
-0.004 -0.60
β
11
0.002 0.70
β
12
-0.002 -0.24
β
13
0.002 0.51
β
14
0.002 0.09
β
15
-0.004 -0.40
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.015
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.025
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= -0.217
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= -0.064
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.33 p=0.568
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.29 p=0.588
65
Table 4.8 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.023 2.47** 14.77% 0.034 3.42* 16.36%
β
1
0.018 0.69 -0.001 -0.02
β
2
0.041 4.38* 0.041 5.25*
β
3
0.022 0.85 0.030 1.26
β
4
0.022 2.16** 0.014 1.35
β
5
0.019 0.50 0.042 0.94
β
6
-0.003 -0.44 -0.003 -0.51
β
7
0.015 0.80 0.006 0.33
β
8
0.046 3.83* 0.045 3.73*
β
9
0.049 1.27 0.045 1.35
β
10
0.061 5.41* 0.056 4.50*
β
11
0.036 1.03 -0.007 -0.21
β
12
0.041 1.57 0.050 1.77***
β
13
0.149 1.93** 0.132 1.72***
β
14
0.171 6.33* 0.235 6.70*
β
15
0.131 1.36 0.016 0.18
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.174
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.019
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.116
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.130
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.32 p=0.572
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.54 p=0.215
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.238
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.036
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.010
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.090
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 5.19 p=0.023
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 4.25 p=0.04
66
Table 4.8 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
ACMeetYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of audit committee meetings from
the year prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
ACMeetNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of audit committee meetings from
the year prior to the third year following the restatement, 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
67
Table 4.9
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Independent Directors on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*ACINDDIRYES*POS + β
1
PRE*ACINDDIRNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*ACINDDIRYES*POS + β
3
POST*ACINDDIRNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*ACINDDIRYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*ACINDDIRNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*ACINDDIRYES*R*POS + β
7
POST*ACINDDIRNO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*ACINDDIRYES*NEG + β
9
PRE*ACINDDIRNO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*ACINDDIRYES*NEG + β
11
POST*ACINDDIRNO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*ACINDDIRYES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*ACINDDIRNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*ACINDDIRYES*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*ACINDDIRNO*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.035 2.49** 14.61%
β
1
0.024 2.41**
β
2
0.045 3.98*
β
3
0.040 3.51*
β
4
0.009 0.64
β
5
0.017 1.55
β
6
-0.004 -0.61
β
7
-0.006 -0.46
β
8
0.019 0.88
β
9
0.059 3.25*
β
10
0.041 1.81***
β
11
0.065 3.70*
β
12
0.027 0.50
β
13
0.103 1.99**
β
14
0.150 3.04*
β
15
0.214 4.86*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.154
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.018
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.220
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.086
Test H6a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.97 p=0.325
H6b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.00 p=0.994
68
Table 4.9 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.027 1.78*** 14.09% 0.027 1.60 15.46%
β
1
0.020 1.84*** 0.033 2.84*
β
2
0.046 3.57* 0.050 4.20*
β
3
0.029 2.17** 0.033 3.12*
β
4
0.017 1.05 0.017 1.01
β
5
0.025 1.99** 0.014 1.18
β
6
-0.004 -0.60 -0.004 -0.65
β
7
0.011 0.79 0.002 0.17
β
8
0.049 2.59* 0.049 2.78*
β
9
0.044 2.99* 0.040 2.65*
β
10
0.066 3.26* 0.029 1.52
β
11
0.056 4.38* 0.061 4.10*
β
12
0.074 1.97** 0.073 1.95***
β
13
0.037 1.12 0.045 1.19
β
14
0.193 4.04* 0.149 2.97*
β
15
0.156 4.97* 0.248 5.68*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.197
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.057
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.145
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.012
Test H6a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.75 p=0.387
H6b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.01 p=0.933
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.153
Conservatism for ACIndDirYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.056
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.246
Conservatism for ACIndDirNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.031
Test H6a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 1.87 p=0.172
H6b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.78 p=0.182
69
Table 4.9 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
ACIndDirYes = 1 if there is an increase in the number of independent members on the
audit committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement, 0 otherwise. An independent director is defined as a
director who is not a present or former firm employee and whose only
formal connection to the firm is service as a director on the board;
ACIndDirNo = 1 if there is no increase in the number of independent members on the
audit committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement, 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
70
Table 4.10
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Financial Experts on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*ACFINEXPYES*POS + β
1
PRE*ACFINEXPNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*ACFINEXPYES*POS + β
3
POST*ACFINEXPNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*ACFINEXPYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*ACFINEXPNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*ACFINEXPYES*R*POS + β
7
POST*ACFINEXPNO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*ACFINEXPYES*NEG + β
9
PRE*ACFINEXPNO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*ACFINEXPYES*NEG + β
11
POST*ACFINEXPNO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*ACFINEXPYES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*ACFINEXPNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*ACFINEXPYES*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*ACFINEXPNO*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.025 2.23** 15.05%
β
1
0.031 2.59*
β
2
0.046 4.73*
β
3
0.023 1.70***
β
4
0.017 1.26
β
5
0.013 1.08
β
6
-0.007 -1.30
β
7
0.021 1.44
β
8
0.052 2.89*
β
9
0.029 1.34
β
10
0.057 3.05*
β
11
0.053 2.61*
β
12
0.088 1.76***
β
13
0.045 0.78
β
14
0.163 3.68*
β
15
0.210 4.40*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.170
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.071
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.189
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.032
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.07 p=0.785
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.30 p=0.581
71
Table 4.10 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.019 1.57 15.15% 0.020 1.56 17.10%
β
1
0.026 1.99** 0.042 3.05*
β
2
0.041 3.44* 0.039 3.92*
β
3
0.022 1.49 0.031 2.57**
β
4
0.027 1.83*** 0.025 1.72***
β
5
0.018 1.36 0.007 0.53
β
6
-0.006 -0.95 -0.006 -0.98
β
7
0.033 2.07** 0.020 1.45
β
8
0.044 2.86* 0.046 3.10*
β
9
0.051 2.94* 0.043 2.42**
β
10
0.073 5.19* 0.077 5.21*
β
11
0.039 2.36** 0.004 0.20
β
12
0.041 1.29 0.051 1.46
β
13
0.079 2.02** 0.066 1.68***
β
14
0.179 5.22* 0.254 6.00*
β
15
0.150 3.74* 0.125 2.45**
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.185
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.014
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.117
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.061
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 1.48 p=0.225
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 2.17 p=0.142
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.260
Conservatism for ACFinExpYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.026
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.105
Conservatism for ACFinExpNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.059
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 5.18 p=0.023
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 4.55 p=0.033
72
Table 4.10 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
ACFinExpYes =1 if there is an increase in the number of financial experts on the audit
committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement; 0 otherwise. A financial expert is defined as someone who
has accounting or financial management expertise (i.e. CPA, CFO, PFO,
CAO, PAO, controller, auditor, accounting or finance professor);
ACFinExpNo =1 if there is no increase in the number of financial experts on the audit
committee from the year prior to the third year following the
restatement; 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
73
Table 4.11
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Top Management for the
Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*MGMTCHGYES*POS + β
1
PRE*MGMTCHGNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*MGMTCHGYES*POS + β
3
POST*MGMTCHGNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*MGMTCHGYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*MGMTCHGNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*MGMTCHGYES*R*POS
+ β
7
POST*MGMTCHGNO*R*POS + β
8
PRE*MGMTCHGYES*NEG
+ β
9
PRE*MGMTCHGNO*NEG + β
10
POST*MGMTCHGYES*NEG
+ β
11
POST*MGMTCHGNO*NEG + β
12
PRE*MGMTCHGYES*R*NEG
+ β
13
PRE*MGMTCHGNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*MGMTCHGYES*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*MGMTCHGNO*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.031 3.10* 14.64%
β
1
0.022 1.51
β
2
0.038 3.59*
β
3
0.043 3.57*
β
4
0.009 0.78
β
5
0.025 1.70***
β
6
0.001 0.10
β
7
-0.005 -0.83
β
8
0.039 2.24**
β
9
0.049 2.13**
β
10
0.067 3.75*
β
11
0.040 1.85***
β
12
0.058 1.20
β
13
0.092 1.53
β
14
0.229 5.32*
β
15
0.128 2.57**
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.228
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.049
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.133
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.067
Test H8a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 2.00 p=0.158
H8b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.18 p=0.278
74
Table 4.11 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.031 2.86* 14.82% 0.040 3.50* 15.76%
β
1
0.005 0.32 0.010 0.60
β
2
0.027 2.12** 0.036 3.50*
β
3
0.044 3.20* 0.039 3.26*
β
4
0.010 0.78 0.003 0.25
β
5
0.044 2.70* 0.037 2.28**
β
6
0.020 1.46 0.008 0.67
β
7
-0.005 -0.89 -0.004 -0.73
β
8
0.039 2.74* 0.033 2.31**
β
9
0.062 3.09* 0.063 3.33*
β
10
0.065 4.98* 0.050 3.35*
β
11
0.042 2.14** 0.044 2.31**
β
12
0.038 1.24 0.033 0.94
β
13
0.087 2.13** 0.095 2.39**
β
14
0.184 6.12* 0.216 5.48*
β
15
0.120 2.27** 0.181 3.00*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.164
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.028
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.125
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.043
Test H8a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.38 p=0.537
H8b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.41 p=0.523
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.208
Conservatism for MgmtChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.030
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.185
Conservatism for MgmtChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.058
Test H8a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.10 p=0.755
H8b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.30 p=0.585
75
Table 4.11 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
MgmtChgYes = 1 if there is a change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise. Top management is defined as Chairman, CEO, and/or
President;
MgmtChgNo = 1 if there is no change in top management following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
76
Table 4.12
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on a Change in Auditor for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*AUDCHGYES*POS + β
1
PRE*AUDCHGNO*POS
+ β
2
POST*AUDCHGYES*POS + β
3
POST*AUDCHGNO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*AUDCHGYES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*AUDCHGNO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*AUDCHGYES*R*POS + β
7
POST*AUDCHGNO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*AUDCHGYES*NEG + β
9
PRE*AUDCHGNO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*AUDCHGYES*NEG + β
11
POST*AUDCHGNO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*AUDCHGYES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*AUDCHGNO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*AUDCHGYES*R*NEG + β
15
POST*AUDCHGNO*R*NEG
+ ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 642)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.028 1.61 14.34%
β
1
0.026 2.75*
β
2
0.008 0.59
β
3
0.046 5.00*
β
4
0.015 0.57
β
5
0.015 1.58
β
6
0.038 3.10*
β
7
-0.013 -2.13**
β
8
0.050 2.35**
β
9
0.031 1.74***
β
10
0.075 3.14*
β
11
0.052 3.00*
β
12
0.091 1.67***
β
13
0.038 0.75
β
14
0.226 3.53*
β
15
0.178 4.46*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.188
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.076
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.191
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.023
Test H9a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.00 p=0.965
H9b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.25 p=0.614
77
Table 4.12 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 642)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.022 1.14 13.55% 0.021 0.96 15.06%
β
1
0.021 2.00** 0.033 2.95*
β
2
0.022 1.43 0.028 2.15**
β
3
0.040 3.59* 0.040 4.32*
β
4
0.037 1.25 0.034 1.06
β
5
0.021 1.91*** 0.013 1.18
β
6
0.036 2.70* 0.030 2.49**
β
7
-0.010 -1.65*** -0.011 -1.83***
β
8
0.042 2.14** 0.060 3.03*
β
9
0.043 3.05* 0.033 2.29**
β
10
0.057 2.84* 0.026 1.09
β
11
0.061 4.65* 0.056 4.06*
β
12
0.051 1.23 0.088 2.11**
β
13
0.048 1.53 0.033 0.96
β
14
0.187 3.17* 0.179 2.26**
β
15
0.165 5.43* 0.216 5.77*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.151
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.014
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.175
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.027
Test H9a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.13 p=0.722
H9b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.01 p=0.908
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.149
Conservatism for AudChgYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.054
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.227
Conservatism for AudChgNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.020
Test H9a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.80 p=0.371
H9b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.07 p=0.302
78
Table 4.12 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
AudChgYes = 1 if there is a change in the auditor following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
AudChgNo = 1 if there is no change in the auditor following the restatement, 0
otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
79
Table 4.13
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Separated into Pre- and Post-SOX Periods for the Period
1994–2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*POS + β
1
PRE*NEG + β
2
POST*POS + β
3
POST*NEG
+ β
4
PRE*POS*R
it
+ β
5
PRE*NEG*R
it
+ β
6
POST*POS*R
it
+ β
7
POST*NEG*R
it
+ ε
it
, (2)
Panel A: Annual Returns
PRE-SOX (n=270) POST-SOX (n=402)
Adj. R
2
=14.5% Adj. R
2
=13.6%
Coefficient t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.028 2.32** 0.026 2.38**
β
1
0.035 1.51 0.041 2.63*
β
2
0.021 1.64 0.041 4.10*
β
3
0.041 2.17** 0.060 3.07*
β
4
0.010 0.71 0.019 1.62
β
5
0.061 0.91 0.065 1.58
β
6
-0.006 -0.97 0.005 0.49
β
7
0.199 4.70* 0.139 2.60*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
PRE-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.205
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.051
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 3.59 p=0.059
POST-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.134
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.046
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 1.61 p=0.205
80
Table 4.13 (Continued)
Panel B: Equally Weighted Market-Adjusted Annual Returns
PRE-SOX (n=270) POST-SOX (n=402)
Adj. R
2
=18.3% Adj. R
2
=13.0%
Coefficient t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.029 2.28** 0.017 1.46
β
1
0.040 2.01** 0.044 3.20*
β
2
0.030 2.33** 0.033 2.83*
β
3
0.045 2.51** 0.048 3.70*
β
4
0.009 0.59 0.032 2.41**
β
5
0.053 1.03 0.049 1.78***
β
6
-0.007 -1.12 0.016 1.37
β
7
0.209 5.49* 0.067 1.84***
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
PRE-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.216
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.044
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 6.79 p=0.010
POST-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.051
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.017
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 0.46 p=0.496
81
Table 4.13 (Continued)
Panel C: Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Annual Returns
PRE-SOX (n=270) POST-SOX (n=402)
Adj. R
2
=13.7% Adj. R
2
=14.5%
Coefficient t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.034 2.47** 0.028 2.15**
β
1
0.034 1.86*** 0.047 3.28*
β
2
0.025 1.97*** 0.039 4.07*
β
3
0.019 1.04 0.060 3.70*
β
4
0.007 0.41 0.020 1.57
β
5
0.036 0.83 0.067 2.04**
β
6
-0.006 -0.95 0.009 0.83
β
7
0.172 3.93* 0.181 3.16*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
PRE-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.178
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.029
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 5.38 p=0.021
POST-SOX:
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.172
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= 0.047
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) = (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 3.41 p=0.066
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
82
Table 4.14
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Outside Director Percentage for the Period
1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*OUTDIR%YES*POS + β
1
PRE*OUTDIR%NO*POS
+ β
2
POST*OUTDIR%YES*POS + β
3
POST*OUTDIR%NO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*OUTDIR%YES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*OUTDIR%NO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*OUTDIR%YES*R*POS + β
7
POST*OUTDIR%NO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*OUTDIR%YES*NEG + β
9
PRE*OUTDIR%NO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*OUTDIR%YES*NEG + β
11
POST*OUTDIR%NO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*OUTDIR%YES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*OUTDIR%NO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*OUTDIR%YES*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*OUTDIR%NO*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.032 2.44** 15.38%
β
1
0.031 2.85*
β
2
0.030 2.25**
β
3
0.049 5.03*
β
4
-0.011 -0.56
β
5
0.019 1.95***
β
6
0.000 0.01
β
7
-0.005 -0.90
β
8
0.011 0.52
β
9
0.067 3.65*
β
10
0.065 3.14
β
11
0.048 2.58**
β
12
-0.001 -0.02
β
13
0.128 2.60*
β
14
0.208 4.07*
β
15
0.169 4.01*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.208
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.010
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.174
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.109
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.24 p=0.622
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.59 p=0.209
83
Table 4.14 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.018 1.34 14.63% 0.042 2.79* 16.42%
β
1
0.034 2.72* 0.032 2.46**
β
2
0.029 1.68*** 0.036 2.64*
β
3
0.042 3.88* 0.042 4.36*
β
4
0.002 0.10 -0.026 -1.17
β
5
0.023 2.04** 0.023 2.10**
β
6
0.013 0.52 0.005 0.23
β
7
-0.002 -0.35 -0.003 -0.50
β
8
0.038 2.08** 0.018 1.07
β
9
0.054 3.54* 0.065 4.30*
β
10
0.047 3.27* 0.036 2.15**
β
11
0.073 4.51* 0.060 3.74*
β
12
0.034 0.98 0.012 0.30
β
13
0.077 2.20** 0.096 2.81*
β
14
0.145 3.81* 0.190 3.58*
β
15
0.194 5.30* 0.224 5.32*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.132
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.032
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.196
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.054
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 1.17 p=0.279
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.27 p=0.603
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.185
Conservatism for OutDir%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.038
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.227
Conservatism for OutDir%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.073
Test H4a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.35 p=0.554
H4b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.01 p=0.932
84
Table 4.14 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
OUTDIR%YES = 1 if a firm’s outside director percentage in the third year following
the restatement announcement is greater than the median outside
director percentage for all sample firms over the same time period,
and 0 otherwise. An outside director is defined as a director who is
not a present or former firm employee and whose only formal
connection to the firm is service as a director on the board;
OUTDIR%NO = 1 if a firm’s outside director percentage in the third year following
the restatement announcement is less than or equal to the median
outside director percentage for all sample firms over the same time
period, and 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
85
Table 4.15
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on Audit Committee Meeting Variables for Year
t+3
for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*ACMEETYES
t+3
*POS + β
1
PRE*ACMEETNO
t+3
*POS
+ β
2
POST*ACMEETYES
t+3
*POS + β
3
POST*ACMEETNO
t+3
*POS
+ β
4
PRE*ACMEETYES
t+3
*R*POS + β
5
PRE*ACMEETNO
t+3
*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*ACMEETYES
t+3
*R*POS
+ β
7
POST*ACMEETNO
t+3
*R*POS + β
8
PRE*ACMEETYES
t+3
*NEG
+ β
9
PRE*ACMEETNO
t+3
*NEG + β
10
POST*ACMEETYES
t+3
*NEG
+ β
11
POST*ACMEETNO
t+3
*NEG + β
12
PRE*ACMEETYES
t+3
*R*NEG
+ β
13
PRE*ACMEETNO
t+3
*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*ACMEETYES
t+3
*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*ACMEETNO
t+3
*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.022 1.90*** 15.31%
β
1
0.031 2.69*
β
2
0.045 3.42*
β
3
0.044 4.21*
β
4
0.031 2.17**
β
5
0.005 0.47
β
6
-0.016 -0.90
β
7
-0.003 -0.50
β
8
0.060 2.92*
β
9
0.029 1.53
β
10
0.054 2.83*
β
11
0.055 2.76*
β
12
0.099 1.84***
β
13
0.047 0.90
β
14
0.141 3.01*
β
15
0.215 4.77*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.157
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.068
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.218
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.042
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) = (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.81 p=0.368
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] = [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.73 p=0.395
86
Table 4.15 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.012 0.91 16.17% 0.029 2.26** 16.16%
β
1
0.029 2.38** 0.030 2.17**
β
2
0.033 2.09** 0.032 2.60*
β
3
0.040 3.46* 0.048 4.51*
β
4
0.048 2.98* 0.030 1.93***
β
5
0.007 0.59 0.007 0.53
β
6
0.010 0.48 0.003 0.16
β
7
-0.002 -0.33 -0.003 -0.62
β
8
0.046 2.99* 0.040 2.47**
β
9
0.048 2.83* 0.048 3.04*
β
10
0.039 2.67* 0.073 3.78*
β
11
0.076 4.92* 0.030 2.05**
β
12
0.037 1.11 0.040 1.05
β
13
0.074 2.06** 0.074 2.08**
β
14
0.078 2.06** 0.233 3.94*
β
15
0.241 6.74* 0.190 4.82*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.068
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= -0.011
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.243
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.067
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 9.54 p=0.002
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.54 p=0.215
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.230
Conservatism for ACMeetYes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.010
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.193
Conservatism for ACMeetNo firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.067
Test H5a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.25 p=0.615
H5b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.04 p=0.309
87
Table 4.15 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
ACMEETYES
t+3
= 1 if the firm’s number of audit committee meetings in the third
year following the restatement announcement is greater than the
median number of audit committee meetings for all sample firms
over the same time period, 0 otherwise;
ACMEETNO
t+3
= 1 if the firm’s number of audit committee meetings in the third
year following the restatement announcement is less than or equal
to the median number of audit committee meetings for all sample
firms over the same time period, 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
88
Table 4.16
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Conditional on the Financial Expert Percentage on Audit
Committee for the Period 1994-2004
X
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*ACFINEXP%YES*POS + β
1
PRE*ACFINEXP%NO*POS
+ β
2
POST*ACFINEXP%YES*POS + β
3
POST*ACFINEXP%NO*POS
+ β
4
PRE*ACFINEXP%YES*R*POS + β
5
PRE*ACFINEXP%NO*R*POS
+ β
6
POST*ACFINEXP%YES*R*POS + β
7
POST*ACFINEXP%NO*R*POS
+ β
8
PRE*ACFINEXP%YES*NEG + β
9
PRE*ACFINEXP%NO*NEG
+ β
10
POST*ACFINEXP%YES*NEG + β
11
POST*ACFINEXP%NO*NEG
+ β
12
PRE*ACFINEXP%YES*R*NEG + β
13
PRE*ACFINEXP%NO*R*NEG
+ β
14
POST*ACFINEXP%YES*R*NEG
+ β
15
POST*ACFINEXP%NO*R*NEG + ε
it
, (5)
Panel A: Annual Returns (n = 612)
Coefficient Adj. R
2
t-value
β
0
0.023 2.09** 16.68%
β
1
0.030 2.52**
β
2
0.046 4.99*
β
3
0.013 0.98
β
4
0.030 2.27**
β
5
0.002 0.15
β
6
-0.010 -1.86***
β
7
0.037 2.77*
β
8
0.061 3.60*
β
9
0.004 0.15
β
10
0.045 2.65*
β
11
0.070 3.14*
β
12
0.095 2.01**
β
13
0.010 0.17
β
14
0.155 3.74*
β
15
0.230 4.50*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.165
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.065
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.193
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.008
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.17 p=0.681
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.65 p=0.419
89
Table 4.16 (Continued)
Panel B: Market-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 612)
Equal Weighted
Value Weighted
Coefficient Adj. R
2
Adj. R
2
t-value Coefficient t-value
β
0
0.013 1.05 16.25% 0.022 1.70*** 17.49%
β
1
0.028 2.15** 0.035 2.54**
β
2
0.040 3.84* 0.037 4.09*
β
3
0.012 0.71 0.027 2.01**
β
4
0.045 3.10* 0.034 2.32**
β
5
0.004 0.28 0.001 0.05
β
6
-0.007 -1.23 -0.007 -1.31
β
7
0.043 2.83* 0.034 2.47**
β
8
0.057 3.99* 0.054 3.84*
β
9
0.031 1.60 0.030 1.56
β
10
0.054 3.74* 0.062 4.10*
β
11
0.060 3.75* 0.030 1.70***
β
12
0.053 1.77*** 0.056 1.75***
β
13
0.058 1.38 0.060 1.35
β
14
0.143 4.04* 0.227 5.17*
β
15
0.189 5.01* 0.185 3.80*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Equal Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.150
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.008
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.146
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.054
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 0.01 p=0.936
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 0.42 p=0.515
Value Weighted Market-Adjusted Returns
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in post-restatement period, β
14
β
6
= 0.234
Conservatism for ACFinExp%Yes firms in pre-restatement period, β
12
β
4
= 0.022
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in post-restatement period, β
15
β
7
= 0.151
Conservatism for ACFinExp%No firms in pre-restatement period, β
13
β
5
= 0.059
Test H7a: (β
14
- β
6
) > (β
15
- β
7
), F-statistic 1.53 p=0.217
H7b: [(β
14
- β
6
) – (β
12
- β
4
)] > [(β
15
- β
7
) – (β
13
- β
5
)], F-statistic 1.81 p=0.179
90
Table 4.16 (Continued)
where
X
it
/P
it-1
= Earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of fiscal year
stock price;
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
ACFINEXP%YES = 1 if the firm’s percentage of audit committee members who are
financial experts during the third year following the restatement is
greater than the median percentage for all sample firms for the
same time period; 0 otherwise. A financial expert is defined as
someone who has accounting or financial management expertise
(i.e. CPA, CFO, PFO, CAO, PAO, controller, auditor, accounting
or finance professor);
ACFINEXP%NO = 1 if the firm’s percentage of audit committee members who are
financial experts during the third year following the restatement is
less than or equal to the median percentage for all sample firms for
the same time period; 0 otherwise;
R
it
= the 12-month compounded return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end
to three months after fiscal year end. Equally weighted market-adjusted returns
are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual return R
it
and the
mean return on an equally-weighted market portfolio. Value weighted market-
adjusted returns are calculated as the difference between the firm’s annual
return R
it
and the mean return on a value-weighted market portfolio;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
91
Table 4.17
Tests of Conditional Conservatism, Pre and Post Restatement,
Industry-Adjusted for the Period 1994-2004 for the Period
1994 – 2004
IndX
it
/P
it-1
= β
0
PRE*POS + β
1
PRE*NEG + β
2
POST*POS + β
3
POST*NEG
+ β
4
PRE*POS*IndR
it
+ β
5
PRE*NEG*IndR
it
+ β
6
POST*POS*IndR
it
+ β
7
POST*NEG*IndR
it
+ ε
it
, (2)
Panel A: Industry-Adjusted Annual Returns (n = 460)
β
0
β
1
β
2
β
3
β
4
β
5
β
6
β
7
Adj. R
2
Coefficients 0.006 -0.012 -0.002 0.007 0.020 0.010 -0.005 0.046
3.93%
(t-value)
0.46 -1.19 -0.14 0.56*
1.63 0.75
-0.81 2.71*
* Significant at 0.01. ** Significant at 0.05. *** Significant at 0.10.
Conditional Conservatism Post-restatement, β
7
β
6
= 0.051
Conditional Conservatism Pre-restatement, β
5
β
4
= -0.010
Test H1: (β
7
β
6
) > (β
5
β
4
), F-statistic = 5.97 p=0.015
where
IndX
it
/P
it-1
= firm i’s earnings per share (Compustat Data 58) divided by beginning of
fiscal year stock price minus the mean X
it
/P
it-1
for all samples firms in the same
industry. Industry is defined using the 2-digit SIC code.
PRE = 1 if the year is before the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POST = 1 if the year is after the restatement announcement year, and 0 otherwise;
POS = 1 if R
it
is >=0, and 0 otherwise;
NEG = 1 if R
it
is <0, and 0 otherwise;
IndR
it
= firm i’s 12-month return beginning nine months prior to fiscal year end to three
months after fiscal year end minus the mean return for all sample firms in the
same industry;
ε
it
= error term;
it = subscript for firm i in year t.
92
CHAPTER 5
CONCLUSION
This chapter concludes the dissertation with a discussion of the results, contributions,
limitations and possible extensions.
5.1 Results
This study examines whether firms report more conservatively in the three years
following a restatement announcement, and whether an increase in conservatism is
related to the extent of debt and compensation contracts. I find restating firms
significantly increase conditional conservatism in the three year period following the
restatement announcement year. The results are unchanged using three alternative
returns measures, controlling for the passage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, and
controlling for industry effects. The results suggest that firms attempt to restore the
credibility of their financial reporting by taking a more conservative approach in
reporting firm performance following a restatement.
As expected, I find no change in unconditional conservatism from the pre- to post-
restatement period. The results appear consistent with the Ball and Shivakumar (2005)
view that unconditional conservatism is simply a downward accounting bias that
contracting parties can adjust for ex ante.
The results also suggest that the increase in conditional conservatism is related to the
importance of debt and compensation contracting to a firm. I find that both the level and
change in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for firms that have
a greater demand for external financing. Thus, debt contracting plays a role in
determining a level of conservatism. I find weaker evidence that both the level and
change in conditional conservatism following a restatement is greater for firms where
compensation contracting is more important. Specifically, I find very strong results using
market-adjusted returns, but insignificant results using raw returns. In addition,
sensitivity analysis shows the compensation contracting results to be less robust as
93
compared to the debt contracting results. Overall, these results appear to be consistent
with the contracting explanation of conservatism provided in Watts (2003).
I examine several corporate governance variables as possible explanations for an
increase in conditional conservatism following a restatement. Specifically, I examine the
number of outside directors and audit committee meetings, the number of independent
directors and financial experts on the audit committee, and a change in top management
and/or audit firm. I find that firms do take steps to improve corporate governance
following a restatement; however, I fail to find consistent support that the improved
corporate governance is associated with a change in conservatism.
Overall, the results suggest that firms do change their financial reporting following a
restatement by reporting more conservatively and this change is more likely for firms
where debt and compensation contracting are more important. I find no consistent
support for an improvement in corporate governance being associated with the increase in
conservatism. Thus, it appears the contracting explanation is the most likely reason for
the increase in conservatism. This suggests that firms report more conservatively
following a financial reporting failure in order to restore the trust and confidence of the
contracting parties and to protect the interests of the contracting parties.
5.2 Contributions
This study furthers our understanding of how firms respond to a financial reporting
failure and contributes to the restatement, corporate governance, and accounting
conservatism literature. This study contributes to the conservatism literature in three
ways. First, I extend the literature that distinguishes between the two types of
conservatism, conditional and unconditional, and make distinct predictions about
expected changes following a specific event, a reporting restatement. As expected, I find
only conditional conservatism changes following a restatement as firms increase
conditional conservatism. The results may provide an explanation to the findings in
Moore and Pfeiffer (2004). They find no change in conservatism following restatements;
however, their study did not use the Basu (1997) measure of conditional conservatism.
This study may help explain their lack of results as I find it is only conditional
conservatism that changes following a restatement. Second, this study provides evidence
94
regarding the contracting explanation for conservatism, as I examine the impact of debt
and compensation contracting on firms’ financial reporting choices. I find the increase in
conditional conservatism following a restatement is significantly associated with the
extent of debt and compensation contracting. This is consistent with the contracting
explanation of conservatism provided in Watts (2003) and provides insight by explaining
variation within firms after a restatement.
This study’s third contribution to the conservatism literature is to examine various
corporate governance variables as determinants of an increase in conditional
conservatism following a reporting failure. It is important for regulators, financial
analysts, investors and contracting parties to know what mechanisms in the financial
reporting environment lead to more conservative reporting. Does an improvement in
corporate governance following a reporting failure lead to more conservative reporting?
Does a new auditor require more conservative reporting following a restatement? Does
new management report more conservatively to “signal” to financial statement users and
contracting parties that the financial statements are reliable and trustworthy? This study
finds that firms do improve their corporate governance variables in the three years
following a restatement announcement. This is consistent with Farber (2005), who uses a
fraud sample and finds firms improve their corporate governance mechanisms in the three
years following fraud detection. However, this study finds no consistent relationship
between the changes in corporate governance following a restatement and the increase in
conservatism.
5.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Future Research
This study does have potential limitations. The primary focus of this study is to
examine changes in conditional and unconditional conservatism following a financial
reporting failure. Therefore, the results are based on how well my measures capture the
two types of conservatism. Givoly et al. (2007) find the Basu measure may not be
appropriate in all research setting because of some limitations of the measure. For
example, they find characteristics of the firm’s information environment that are
unrelated to conservatism may unduly affect the Basu measure. In addition, they find the
Basu measure is negatively correlated to other measures of conservatism, so they suggest
95
using multiple measures of conservatism in studies. I recognize in this study that the
Basu measure is capturing a unique dimension of conservatism apart from other
measures. As one of the purposes of this study is to examine two different dimensions of
conservatism (conditional and unconditional) following restatements, it is necessary to
use the Basu measure to capture the conditional dimension of conservatism. I leave the
use of alternative measures of conservatism to future research. In addition, the Basu
(1997) approach to measure conservatism has been widely used and accepted in the
literature; therefore, I believe this is an appropriate measure of conservatism for this
study. However, the limitations of the measure as pointed out in Givoly et al. (2007)
need to be considered when interpreting the results of this study.
A second limitation is that I do not test the interactions between the two types of
conservatism nor the specific predictions as modeled in Beaver and Ryan (2005). For
example, they point out that conditional conservatism resets the cost bases of net assets
when assets are written down, which then affects subsequent unconditional conservatism.
As this is an initial study on the change in conservatism following a reporting failure, I
leave these other issues to future research.
Another limitation is the external validity of the study as the results may not
generalize to the overall population of publicly traded companies. There are some
possible selection biases in my final sample of restatement firms. This is because of the
research design which requires each sample firm to have data for a consecutive 7-year
period, the three years prior and after the restatement announcement. Thus, the final
sample tends to include surviving and larger firms that maybe perceived as more reliable.
On the other hand, larger firms receive more media coverage and regulatory attention
than smaller firms and therefore may be under more pressure to change financial
reporting following a restatement in order to restore the public’s trust in their financial
reporting.
Givoly et al. (2007) find the use of aggregated data over longer time periods may
unduly affect the magnitude of the Basu measure. As this study uses annual data, future
research could use quarterly data to control for this “aggregation effect.” In addition,
future research can examine specific acts of conditional conservatism following a
restatement, such as asset impairment accounting and the lower of cost or market rule for
96
inventory. It would be interesting to determine if the way conditional conservatism is
manifested has an affect on a firm’s financial reporting choices following a financial
reporting failure.
Finally, future research can explore different aspects of compensation and debt
contracting to further refine our understanding of the contracting effects on financial
reporting choices following a restatement. For example, Beatty, Ramesh, and Weber
(2002) find a wide variation in the use of GAAP in debt covenants, with many requiring
the use of GAAP in existence at the contract date, and others allowing accounting
flexibility with the use of mandatory and/or voluntary accounting changes after the
contract date. It would be interesting to know if the inclusion or exclusion of mandatory
or voluntary accounting changes in debt covenants affects a firm’s conservatism
following a restatement.
97
REFERENCES
Abbott, L., S. Parker and G. Peters. 2004. Audit committee characteristics and
restatements.
Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory, v. 23(1): 69-87.
Ahmed, A., B. Billings, R. Morton and M. Stanford-Harris. 2002. The role of
accounting conservatism in mitigating bondholder-shareholder conflicts over dividend
policy and in reducing debt costs.
The Accounting Review, v. 77(4): 867-890.
Anderson, K. and T. Yohn. 2002. The effect of 10-K restatements on firm value,
information asymmetries, and investors’ reliance on earnings. Working Paper,
Georgetown University.
Ball, R. and L. Shivakumar. 2005. Earnings quality in UK private firms: comparative
loss recognition timeliness.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 39(1): 83-128.
Barton, J. 2005. Who cares about auditor reputation?
Contemporary Accounting
Research, v. 22(3): 549-586.
Basu, S. 1997. The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 24(1): 3-37.
Basu, S. 2005. Discussion of “Conditional and Unconditional Conservatism: Concepts
and Modeling.”
Review of Accounting Studies, v. 10: 311-321.
Beasley, Mark. 1996. An empirical analysis of the relation between the board of director
composition and financial statement fraud.
The Accounting Review, v. 71(4): 443-465.
Beatty, Anne, K. Ramesh, and Joseph Weber. 2002. The importance of accounting
changes in debt contracts: the cost of flexibility in covenant calculations.
Journal of
Accounting and Economics, v. 33: 205-227.
Beaver, W. and S. Ryan. 2005. Conditional and unconditional conservatism: Concepts
and modeling.
Review of Accounting Studies, v. 10: 269-309.
Beekes, W., P. Pope and S. Young. 2004. The link between earnings timeliness,
earnings conservatism and board composition: evidence from the U.K.
Corporate
Governance, v. 12 (1): 47-59.
Bliss, J.H. 1924. Management through accounts. The Ronald Press Company, New
York, NY.
Bonner, S., Z. Palmrose and S. Young. 1998. Fraud type and auditor litigation: An
analysis of SEC Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases.
The Accounting
Review, v. 73(4): 503-532.
98
Cahan, S. and W. Zhang. 2006. After Enron: Auditor conservatism and ex-Andersen
clients.
The Accounting Review, v. 81(1): 49-82.
Dechow, P., R. Sloan and A. Sweeney. 1996. Causes and consequences of earnings
manipulations: An analysis of firms subject to enforcement actions by the SEC.
Contemporary Accounting Research, v. 13(1): 1-36.
DeFond, M. and J. Jiambalvo. 1991. Incidence and circumstances of accounting errors.
The Accounting Review, v. 66(3): 643-655.
DeFond, M. and Subramanyam. 1998. Auditor changes and discretionary accruals.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 25: 35-67.
DeFond, M., R. Hann and X. Hu. 2005. Does the market value financial expertise on
audit committees of boards of directors?
Journal of Accounting Research, v. 43(2): 153-
193.
Desai, H., C. Hogan, and M. Wilkins. 2006. The Reputational Penalty for Aggressive
Accounting: Earnings Restatements and Management Turnover.
The Accounting Review,
v. 81(1): 83-112.
Easton, P. and J. Pae. 2004. Accounting conservatism and the relation between returns
and accounting data.
Review of Accounting Studies, v. 9: 495-521.
Farber, D. 2005. Restoring trust after fraud: does corporate governance matter?
The
Accounting Review, v. 80 (2): 539-561.
Francis, J., J. Hanna and L. Vincent. 1996. Causes and effects of discretionary asset
write-offs.
Journal of Accounting Research, v. 34: 117-134.
Francis, J. and J. Krishnan. 1999. Accounting accruals and auditor reporting
conservatism.
Contemporary Accounting Research, v. 16(1): 135-165.
General Accounting Office. 2002. Financial Statement Restatements: Trends, Market
Impacts, Regulatory Responses, and Remaining Challenges. GAO-03-138.
Givoly, D. and C. Hayn. 2000. The changing time-series properties of earnings, cash
flows and accruals: Has financial reporting become more conservative?
Journal of
Accounting and Economics, v. 29(3): 287-320.
Givoly, D., C. Hayn and A. Natarajan. 2007. Measuring Reporting Conservatism.
The
Accounting Review, v. 82 (1): 65-106.
Holthausen, R. and R. Watts. 2001. The relevance of the value-relevance literature for
financial accounting standard setting.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 31: 3-75.
99
Hribar, P. and N. Jenkins. 2004. The effect of accounting restatements on earnings
revisions and the estimated cost of capital.
Review of Accounting Studies, v. 9: 337-356.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency
costs and ownership structure.
Journal of Financial Economics, v. 3: 305-360.
Kinney, W. and L. McDaniel. 1989. Characteristics of firms correcting previously
reported quarterly earnings.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 11(1): 71-93.
Klein, A. 2002. Audit committee, board of director characteristics, and earnings
management.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 33(3): 375-400.
Krishnan, G. 2005. Did earnings conservatism increase for former Andersen clients?
Working Paper, George Mason University.
Lee, T., R. Ingram, and T. Howard. 1999. The difference between earnings and
operating cash flow as an indicator of financial reporting fraud.
Contemporary
Accounting Research, v. 16 (4): 749-786.
Moore, E. and R. Pfeiffer Jr. 2004. The effect of financial statement restatements on
firms’ financial reporting strategies. Working Paper, Lehigh University.
Palmrose, Z., V. Richardson, and S. Scholz. 2004. Determinants of market reactions to
restatement announcements.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 37(1): 59-89.
Palmrose, Z. and S. Scholz. 2004. The circumstances and legal consequences of non-
GAAP reporting: Evidence from restatements.
Contemporary Accounting Research, v.
21(1): 139-180.
Penman, S. and X. Zhang. 2002. Accounting conservatism, the quality of earnings, and
stock returns.
The Accounting Review, v. 77(2): 237-264.
Penman, S. 2003. The quality of financial statements: Perspectives from the recent stock
market bubble.
Accounting Horizons, v. 17: 77-96.
Pourciau, S. 1993. Earnings management and nonroutine executive changes.
Journal of
Accounting and Economics, v. 16: 317-336.
Riedl, E. 2004. An examination of long-lived asset impairments.
The Accounting
Review, v. 79(3): 823-852.
Sarbanes-Oxley Act. 2002. Public Law 107-204, 107
th
Congress.
http://www.sec.gov/about/laws/soa2002.pdf
100
Sengupta, P. 1998. Corporate disclosure quality and the cost of debt.
The Accounting
Review, v. 73(4): 459-474.
Srinivasan, S. 2005. Consequences of financial reporting failure for outside directors:
Evidence from accounting restatements and audit committee members.
Journal of
Accounting Research, v. 43(2): 291-334.
Watts, R. and J. Zimmerman. 1986. Positive Accounting Theory. Prentice Hall.
Watts, R. 2003a. Conservatism in accounting Part I: Explanations and implications.
Accounting Horizons, v. 17 (3): 207-221.
Watts, R. 2003b. Conservatism in accounting Part II: Evidence and research
opportunities.
Accounting Horizons, v. 17 (4): 287-301.
Zhang, J. 2004. Efficiency gains from accounting conservatism: benefits to lenders and
borrowers. Working Paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
101
102
BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH
William D. LaGore is an Assistant Professor of Accounting at Eastern Michigan
University. He is currently teaching the introductory financial accounting course at the
undergraduate level and the graduate-level advanced financial accounting course. In
addition, he has taught courses in intermediate accounting, managerial accounting,
governmental and nonprofit accounting, and financial statement analysis. His research
interests are in the area of financial accounting and reporting, including accounting
conservatism and the value-relevance of accounting information. He also has several
years experience in public accounting, including audits of governmental and nonprofit
entities.
William D. LaGore is a Registered CPA in the State of Michigan. He has a Master’s
Degree in Business Administration from the University of Wyoming and a Bachelor’s
Degree in Business Administration from Adrian College in Adrian, Michigan.