WP/04/227
COMESA and SADC: Prospects and
Challenges for Regional Trade Integration
Padamja Khandelwal
© 2004 International Monetary Fund WP/04/227
IMF Working Paper
Policy Development and Review Department
COMESA and SADC: Prospects and Challenges for Regional Trade Integration
Prepared by Padamja Khandelwal
1
Authorized for distribution by Hans Peter Lankes
December 2004
Abstract
This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent
those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are
published to elicit comments and to further debate.
Regional integration has been seen in Africa as a means of encouraging trade and securing
economies of scale. This paper examines in detail the prospects and challenges for trade
expansion in the two most prominent arrangements in eastern and southern Africa: the
Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA) and the Southern African
Development Community (SADC). It finds that possibilities of growth in intraregional trade
may be limited, but that the two arrangements offer opportunities for member countries to
gain policy credibility for trade reforms and tariff liberalization and to address structural
weaknesses. In this regard, the negotiation of the Economic Partnership Agreements with the
European Union can also have a significant impact.
JEL Classification Numbers: F15, R58
Keywords: COMESA, SADC, Regional Integration, Economic Partnership Agreements
Author(s) E-Mail Address: [email protected]
1
This paper is associated with the work program of the Trade Policy Division of the IMF’s Policy Development
and Review Department. I am grateful to Dustin Smith for excellent research assistance and to Nur Calika,
Jean-Jacques Hallaert, Michael Hadjimichael, Lawrence Hinkle, Prakash Hurry, El-Tigani Ibrahim,
Hans Peter Lankes, Jon Shields, and Yongzheng Yang for helpful input and comments, without implication for
any remaining errors.
- 2 -
Contents Page
Executive Summary...................................................................................................................4
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................6
II. Features of COMESA and SADC.........................................................................................8
A. COMESA..................................................................................................................8
B. SADC ......................................................................................................................12
III. Prospects of COMESA and SADC....................................................................................14
A. Overlapping Memberships in Regional Arrangements...........................................14
B. Product Complementarities.....................................................................................15
C. Trade Diversion Versus Trade Expansion ..............................................................17
D. Potential for Trade Expansion in COMESA and SADC ........................................19
IV. Challenges in Tariff Liberalization and Harmonization....................................................20
A. Dependence on Trade Taxes...................................................................................20
B. Disparities in Restrictiveness of Trade Regime ......................................................22
C. Impact of Common External Tariff on Tariff Structures ........................................23
V. European Union—Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA) Negotiations .......................28
A. Features of EPA ......................................................................................................29
B. Overlapping Membership Issues.............................................................................30
C. Revenue Losses Owing to EPA ..............................................................................32
D. Other Challenges and Opportunities in EPA Implementation................................33
VI. Conclusion .........................................................................................................................34
Annex
I. Features of SADC and COMESA .....................................................................................36
References................................................................................................................................40
Tables
1. Bilateral Complementarity Indices in COMESA ..............................................................16
2. Bilateral Complementarity Indices in SADC ....................................................................16
3. Intraregional Trade ............................................................................................................18
4. Total Trade.........................................................................................................................18
5. Trade Tariffs and Revenues in Eastern and Southern Africa ............................................21
6. Restrictiveness Ratings in Eastern and Southern Africa, 2003.........................................23
7. Average Tariffs Under Three- and Four-Band Common External Tariff..........................24
8. Impact of Common External Tariff on Selected Countries ...............................................26
9. Number of Tariff Bindings to Be Renegotiated at World Trade Organization (WTO).....27
10. European Union (EU)—Share in Trade.............................................................................28
11. Trade Revenue Loss Owing to EPA ..................................................................................32
- 3 -
Figure
1. Share of Africa in World Trade, 1980–2003 ........................................................................6
Boxes
1. Open Regionalism and Deep Integration..............................................................................7
2. Rules of Origin in COMESA and SADC .............................................................................9
- 4 -
E
XECUTIVE SUMMARY
If well designed, regional trade arrangements (RTAs) can contribute to Africa’s
integration into the global economy. Past RTAs have done little to halt Africa’s
marginalization in world trade. As is well-established regional liberalization behind high
external barriers can be welfare subtracting and does little to foster competitiveness and the
incentives to integrate globally. Trade in the region is beset by a host of obstacles ranging
from distortions in the trade regimes to inadequacies in the customs, transport and
communications infrastructure. And many of Africa’s economies do not have complementary
production profiles—artificially stimulating trade through tariff preferences would seem
pointless and, if effective, can be costly. The renewed momentum for regional integration
should be viewed as an opportunity to improve the design of Africa’s RTAs, by setting them
firmly within a framework of multilateral liberalization (“open regionalism”) and leveraging
cooperation at the regional level to tackle regulatory and other obstacles to trade (“deep
integration”).
A close examination of the two most prominent RTAs in eastern and southern Africa
reveals risks and weaknesses in their design. Both the Common Market for Eastern and
Southern Africa (COMESA) and the Southern African Development Community (SADC)
are implementing a free trade area and have plans to form customs unions. Progress in
COMESA has been limited by country-level implementation problems while SADC has been
hampered by complicated and restrictive rules of origin. Overlapping memberships have led
to conflicting goals and limited progress in both organizations, and reveal a lack of political
commitment. Our estimates of product complementarities in the region suggest limited scope
for intra-regional trade. A commitment to open regionalism and deep integration would help
address some of these problems and create a healthy basis for regional and global trade
integration.
COMESA and SADC face several challenges in pursuing open regionalism (in the form
of a commitment to nondiscriminatory tariff liberalization). We investigate the trade
regimes of member countries and highlight possible difficulties and obstacles to agreeing on
a low and uniform common external tariff. These include:
Dependence on trade taxes. For almost all member countries in COMESA and
SADC, revenue from trade taxes is at least 10 percent of total government revenue. In
addition, past experience suggests that African countries have had very limited
success in replacing lost trade taxes with revenue from other sources.
Disparities in the restrictiveness of trade regimes. Several countries in the region
rank among the most open in the world while others are among the most restrictive.
In these circumstances, harmonizing a common external tariff will involve significant
adjustments and carries the risk that some countries will end up closing rather than
opening their economies.
- 5 -
Protectionism. The proposed three or four band common external tariff structures are
based on the classification of products into four categories—raw materials, capital
goods, intermediates, and finished products. The proposed tariff structure would
lower the average degree of protection for some countries but increase it for others.
Moreover, past experience suggests that the classification of the commodities into
bands leaves ample opportunity for special interests to assert themselves.
Negotiations over Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) with the European Union
(EU) are ongoing and it remains to be seen if the agreements prove to be welfare-
enhancing. The EPAs are an opportunity to rationalize the overlapping memberships in
various RTAs and can act as a mechanism to lock-in trade and other structural and
institutional reforms, including in the services sectors. Liberalization of trade with the EU is
likely to cause steep declines in revenue from trade taxes in COMESA and SADC countries,
which could however be addressed by appropriate reform of tax systems. But more
importantly, it is not clear whether the EPAs will play a positive role in fostering an open
regionalism or whether they might, by ensuring the more systematic implementation of
regional integration provisions, end up strengthening inward-looking forces. There is also a
concern over the impact that an FTA between the EU and half of the WTO’s membership
might have on incentives for multilateral liberalization within the WTO, since MFN
liberalization would erode the preference margin that the FTA conveys.
The main recommendations that emerge from our analysis are for COMESA and
SADC (as well as EPAs) to pursue nondiscriminatory liberalization concomitantly with
preferential liberalization, in both goods and services. The agreements should aim for
comprehensive coverage of trade flows and selected regulatory policies, and for appropriate
sequencing, including of trade and tax reforms. Agreement should be reached on a low and
uniform common external tariff, with a continuing commitment to further tariff reductions.
- 6 -
I. I
NTRODUCTION
Regional integration has long been seen in Africa as a means of achieving
industrialization and modernization through encouraging trade and securing economies of
scale and market access. Consequently, regional arrangements have sprung up all over Africa
(Aryeetey, 1997). These have, however, done little to halt the marginalization of Africa in
world trade—Africa’s share of world trade in goods and services dropped from more than 5
percent in 1980 to around 2 percent in 2003 (Figure 1). The decline in Africa’s share in world
trade has happened simultaneously with an increase in the overall share of developing
countries indicating that the growth of African countries’ trade has lagged behind that of
developing countries in Asia and Latin America. The weak performance of African trade is a
particular concern.
Several studies (see Iqbal and Khan, eds.,1997) have pointed out that African trade
has been hindered by distorted trade regimes and high transaction costs owing to inadequate
transport, information, and communications infrastructure.
African countries have the most
restrictive trade regimes among all groups of countries, with high tariffs, a large number of
often specific and seemingly arbitrary exemptions, and significant degrees of tariff escalation
(Subramanian and others, 2000). Even though formal nontariff barriers (NTBs) are not very
common any more, there continue to be informal barriers such as nonacceptance of rules-of-
origin certificates, and cumbersome and inconsistent customs procedures.
Regional integration efforts have also been marked by a lack of political commitment
and policy reversals in implementing harmonization provisions, multiple and conflicting
Figure 1. Share of Africa in World Trade, 1980–2003 (in percent)
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001
Merchandise
exports
Merchandise
imports
Services
exports
Services
imports
Source: IMF staff calculation based on World Trade Organization (WTO) data.
- 7 -
objectives of overlapping regional arrangements, and limited administrative resources (Iqbal
and Khan, eds., 1997). As a result, even though regional trade arrangements (RTAs) have
been in place over the last several years (SADC-1992, COMESA-1982, ECOWAS-1975),
they do not appear to have been successful in generating a trade expansion in Africa.
Jebuni (1997) has argued that protectionist trade regimes in Africa have created a
strong anti-export bias and have rendered preferential liberalization meaningless. More
generally, there is a preponderance of evidence (Baldwin, 2003; Wacziarg and Welch, 2003;
and Warner, 2003) linking poor growth performance to trade restrictions, on the one hand,
and, on the other hand, linking trade liberalization to improved growth and investment. It is
also not clear whether greater integration of regional trade has preceded or followed a formal
regional arrangement. For instance, in East Asia (World Bank, 2004), integration with the
global economy provided a strong impetus to expansion of intraregional trade and formal
regional preferential arrangements were established after this regional integration.
The momentum for RTAs in Africa has picked up in recent times, driven in part by
global trends in the same direction and in part by the negotiation of EPAs with the EU. Based
on existing knowledge about the links between trade and growth, one clear inference that can
be drawn is that African countries should simultaneously pursue nondiscriminatory
liberalization and regional integration. As important, RTAs should be used as a mechanism
to enhance policy credibility in the region and lock in trade reforms. Regional cooperation
can also play an important role in addressing the various infrastructure constraints and
limitations on resources in Africa. In this regard, RTAs should be designed to maximize their
benefits (Schiff and Winters, 2003; World Bank, 2004; and Lawrence, 1997). These desirable
attributes of RTAs may broadly be described as open regionalism and deep integration (see
Box 1).
Box 1. Open Regionalism and Deep Integration
Open regionalism is broadly characterized by a commitment to most-favored-nation (MFN)
liberalization; comprehensive product coverage in goods and services with few exclusions; a strong
focus on reducing transaction costs at borders; and liberal, clear, and consistent rules of origin (World
Bank, 2004).
Open regionalism forms a key ingredient in the success of an RTA and plays an important role in
expanding the scope for competition and trade creation and minimizing trade diversion.
Deep integration is the inclusion in regional arrangements of liberalization commitments that go far
beyond the multilateral agreements. Commitments in areas such as investments, intellectual property
rights, competition policy, standards, and trade facilitation at a regional level help reconcile divergent
national practices and can create supranational implementation mechanisms.
When deep integration is tailored to the level of development of a country, it has the potential to
improve institutions and impart credibility to trade reforms beyond what would be possible in the
multilateral context (World Bank, 2004; and Lawrence, 1997). In addition, regional cooperation has
the potential to alleviate trade development and supply constraints.
- 8 -
The purpose of this paper is to examine and discuss prospects and challenges for trade
expansion in the two largest RTAs in eastern and southern Africa
2
—COMESA and SADC.
3
The paper is structured as follows. Section II describes the features of the two agreements
and the extent to which they possess the desirable attributes outlined here. Prospects for trade
diversion and trade expansion in the two RTAs are discussed in Section III. Section IV is
based on the current plans of COMESA and SADC to implement customs unions in the near
future. There are several challenges in simultaneously pursuing the desirable goal of MFN
liberalization and agreeing on a common external tariff. These issues are discussed in Section
IV. In Section V, we describe and outline some of the issues, challenges, and opportunities in
the ongoing EPA negotiations. Section VI concludes.
II. F
EATURES OF COMESA AND SADC
This section describes the features of COMESA and SADC, the two most prominent
RTAs in eastern and southern Africa, in terms of membership, and evaluate the extent to
which they possess the desirable attributes of open regionalism and deep integration (see
Annex I for details).
A. COMESA
Features of the Agreement
COMESA originated as a preferential trade area (PTA) in 1982 and has 19 members
at present. Eleven of the nineteen member states participate in a free trade area (FTA); others
trade on preferential terms.
4
The FTA was formed in October 2000 as the result of a long
period of tariff reductions and has followed some of the principles of open regionalism.
5
This
2
Other prominent RTAs in the region are the East African Community (EAC), the Indian Ocean Commission
(IOC), and the Southern African Customs Union (SACU).
3
COMESA has 19 members including Angola, Burundi, Comoros, the Democratic Republic of the Congo,
Djibouti, Egypt, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Seychelles, Sudan, Rwanda,
Swaziland, Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. Eleven of the 19 COMESA members participate in a free trade
area. SADC has 13 members including Angola, Botswana, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Lesotho,
Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, South Africa, Swaziland, Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. Eleven
of its members have elected to participate in its free trade area.
4
Members of the FTA include Burundi, Djibouti, Egypt, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Rwanda,
Sudan, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.
5
An important component that has been missing is a commitment to MFN liberalization at the COMESA level,
even though some individual member countries have liberalized unilaterally.
- 9 -
is reflected in a comprehensive product coverage with no exclusions, and a set of liberal and
clear rules of origin (see Box 2 for details on rules of origin). These two features of the
COMESA FTA agreement, by themselves, have done a great deal in liberalizing
intraregional trade.
Box 2. Rules of Origin in COMESA and SADC
As has been noted in World Bank 2004, administrative costs to importers due to rules of origin can be
fairly high. Therefore, adopting simple and clear rules of origin is an important aspect of regional
arrangements.
COMESA
Goods qualify for preferential treatment if they undergo substantial transformation such that they
contain a minimum of 35 percent regional value-added, or include non-COMESA imported materials
worth no more than 60 percent of the value of total inputs used, or undergo a single change of tariff
heading. There is a list of “goods of economic importance” to member states, according to which the
domestic value added requirement is relaxed to 25 percent.
SADC
In 1996, SADC trade negotiators initially chose the same simple and transparent rules of origin as
COMESA. Goods would qualify for preferential treatment if they underwent a single change of tariff
heading, contained a minimum of 35 percent regional value-added, or included non-SADC imported
materials worth no more than 60 percent of the value of total inputs used.
By the time of the implementation of the SADC Trade Protocol in 2000, protectionist interests in
member states pressed for exceptions to these rules on a sector-and product-specific basis (Flatters,
2002; and Nhara, 2003). The rules were modified to include detailed technical process requirements,
lower permitted import content and higher domestic value added requirements.
Wheat flour and related products, coffee, tea and spices, machinery and electrical products, mineral
fuels, motor vehicles, and textiles and garments are particular sectors where rules of origin are either
not yet agreed or have been made restrictive in order to protect local industry. For instance, in textiles
and garments, the rules of origin require double transformation to qualify for preferences—for
example, garments must be made from regionally produced fabric and fabric must be made from
regionally produced yarn.
1
In some sectors such as wheat flour and its products, mineral fuels, motor
vehicles, and machinery and electrical products, negotiations to finalize rules of origin are still
continuing. With respect to the sugar industry, SADC has agreed on a system of quotas to provide
nonreciprocal duty-free market access into the Southern African Currency Union (SACU).
1
This is a fairly restrictive provision as pointed out in Flatters (2002), since regional capacity for producing
quality fabric and yarn is severely constrained. The double transformation rule has been relaxed to the single
transformation rule by SACU for the LDC members of SADC till 2005.
- 10 -
The agreement reaches beyond border measures and provides for the monitoring of
NTBs. There is an extensive program of cooperation and technical assistance in trade
facilitation and harmonization of standards. A formal dispute settlement mechanism in the
form of a COMESA Court of Justice is provided, but disputes in general have been
successfully handled through an informal process of diplomatic consultation and the court is
not yet operational. The COMESA agreement has also incorporated temporary balance of
payments related safeguards. Progress is being made towards a regional framework
agreement for investment and a competition policy.
Perhaps due to a lack of political commitment in member countries, the COMESA
FTA has been hampered by country level institutional changes and prevailing structural
constraints. Eight of the nineteen members have not yet joined the FTA. Among those that
have joined, informal NTBs such as nonacceptance of rules of origin certificates,
cumbersome bureaucratic procedures, and restrictive standards are some common problems.
Some countries have replaced tariffs with discriminatory excises. On the issue of services
liberalization, little progress has been made.
Plans for Further Integration
For several years, COMESA has been studying a common external tariff (CET)
structure of 0, 5, 15, and 30 percent with plans to implement it by December 2004
(COMESA Secretariat, 2003b). Work ongoing in the areas of customs management and trade
facilitation, development of a regional competition policy, etc., has been geared to support
the customs union (see Annex I). However, with the setting up of a customs union by the
EAC in 2003, two COMESA members, Kenya and Uganda, have agreed on a CET structure
of 0, 10, and 25 percent.
6
As a result, confusion has ensued, discussions on the CET have
been postponed until May 2005, and further delays are likely.
7
In addition, a number of
alternative CETs are presently under consideration and member states have not yet agreed on
the maximum tariff rate or the number of bands. There is stiff resistance to reducing the
number of tariff bands and the proposed maximum CET. Going forward, COMESA’s goal to
establish a customs union has the potential to unravel the goals of liberalization. Failure to
agree on a low and uniform CET will have important repercussions for the region in that
several countries could be locked in to fairly restrictive trade regimes.
There are important impediments to the goal of establishing a low and uniform CET.
Protectionism has not only manifested itself in resistance to lowering the number of tariff
6
A third member of the EAC is Tanzania. The CET structure in the EAC provides for exceptional treatment of
sensitive products.
7
At the most recent COMESA summit, it was decided that all 19 member countries should join the FTA before
the customs union goes forward. This is also likely to delay the customs union.
- 11 -
bands and the maximum tariff rate but also in discord over the classification of goods into the
four categories of raw materials, capital goods, intermediates, and finished goods.
8
One
suggestion has been to make an exception from the CET for a limited number of goods for a
specified period of time. With 19 members in COMESA, there will be a need for political
commitment to ensure that the list of exceptions to the CET does not get extensive. Another
significant impediment to agreeing on a low and uniform CET is the dependence on trade
taxes as a source of revenue for many countries (Table 5). While a few countries have
already aligned their tariff structures with the proposed CET, a number of them have
significant adjustment ahead.
Several of the proposed features of the COMESA customs union will make it
essential to maintain border controls for intraregional trade. As a result, member countries
will be unable to realize efficiency gains from the customs union, making it an exercise in
futility. To make things worse, individual countries will have given up a great deal of
discretion over their trade policy and future liberalization in the process.
The proposed features of the COMESA customs union that would necessitate border
controls in the region are discussed below. First, the proposed exceptions to the CET for a
limited number of goods will require member countries to maintain border controls within
the customs union. Second, the dependence on trade taxes by member countries has led to an
agreement that revenue would be kept by the country of final consumption. This allows
countries to keep their import revenues—but will require enormous effort and cooperation on
the part of customs administrations to track the country of final consumption. The motivation
for countries to avoid a genuine revenue-sharing arrangement comes from the need to
maintain fiscal sustainability in the face of difficulties in raising revenue from domestic
sources. However, this has the potential to completely overwhelm the regional customs
administrations and erode efficiency gains from the customs union. It is worth pointing out
that customs administration capacity will be similarly burdened due to overlapping
membership between COMESA, SADC, and the EAC and the associated need to track
qualifying domestic/regional content for each of the arrangements. These problems will be
further accentuated due to the implementation of preferences in African Growth and
Opportunity Act (AGOA) or the EU EPAs.
COMESA has plans for eventual formation of a common market and a monetary area,
but those plans are in the distant future.
8
This has also been a bone of contention in another customs union in the region, viz., the EAC.
- 12 -
B. SADC
Features of the Agreement
SADC originated as an organization of Frontline states (Angola, Botswana, Lesotho,
Malawi, Mozambique, Swaziland, Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe) to resist the influence
of South Africa in the region and was transformed into a development community only in
August 1992 with the signing of the Treaty of Windhoek.
9
The organization has had a very
different approach to regional integration than COMESA—it has concentrated on relaxing
the supply side constraints to trade through regional cooperation in various sectors as diverse
as infrastructure, agriculture, transportation and human resources (see SADC’s Regional
Indicative Strategic Development Plan (RISDP)). Its trade protocol, which was signed in
1996 and led to the launch of an FTA in 2000, is only one of several protocols of cooperation
in the organization. Eleven of the 13 SADC member states have joined the FTA.
10
The SADC Trade protocol, which is based on negotiations and offers by contracting
parties, aims for liberalization of all trade by 2012. Member countries have agreed to
liberalize 85 percent of intra-SADC trade by 2008 and liberalize sensitive products by 2012.
A small number of sectors are excluded from the liberalization—narcotics, precious and
strategic metals such as gold, silver, platinum, etc., second hand goods, and some others for
environmental reasons and the like are in this category.
There is a concern that tariff reductions under SADC have been backloaded and the
pace of liberalization has been slow (Kritzinger-van Niekerk and Moreira, 2002). Another
important issue is that over time, the rules of origin in SADC have become restrictive and
product-specific under pressure from member states (see Box 2). The fact that in some
sectors negotiations on the rules of origin are still ongoing is probably indicative of a lack of
political commitment to liberalization. The complicated and restrictive rules of origin are
likely to increase administrative costs and will make it difficult for exporters to take
advantage of SADC preferences. As such, they constitute a serious obstacle to the
liberalization of intraregional trade. There is an attempt to ameliorate possible polarization
effects on least developed country (LDC) member states through nonreciprocal market
access in sugar and more relaxed rules of origin in textiles.
11
The agreement also includes
provisions for protection of infant industries and antidumping and safeguard measures.
9
Following the collapse of apartheid, South Africa became a member in 1994 while Mauritius, Namibia, and
the Democratic Republic of Congo joined the organization later.
10
Angola and the Democratic Republic of Congo have not elected to join the FTA.
11
As noted in Box 2, the rules of origin in textiles and garments effectively provide market access into the
SACU market only to the LDCs, leaving out Mauritius and Zimbabwe. These two countries have argued for
market access on par with the other countries. With respect to sugar, market access of about 138,000 tons has
(continued…)
- 13 -
While the agreement calls for elimination of NTBs and the liberalization of services
trade, not much progress has been made in either of these areas. There is no institutional
mechanism for reporting of NTBs or resolution of disputes, while the liberalization of
services is a futuristic provision. Some work has been completed on harmonization of
customs procedures. Implementation of the protocol in terms of meeting liberalization
commitments on merchandise trade has been uneven with Tanzania, Zambia, and Zimbabwe
lagging behind.
While the trade liberalization aspect of SADC appears to be lacking, its approach of
addressing structural impediments and supply constraints through sectoral cooperation
initiatives is an important one. Active areas of cooperation where there has been progress
include the monetary and financial areas—training and capacity building in central banks,
development and harmonization of payments, clearing and settlement systems, and some
others. Despite the ambitious goals of the SADC sectoral initiatives, progress made thus far
has been somewhat limited and it has been widely acknowledged that there is a lack of
mechanisms for evaluating and monitoring projects or assessing their effectiveness.
Moreover, there is a concern that the organization is still more of a political block than a true
instrument for regional economic integration.
Plans for Further Integration
More recently, SADC has focused on macroeconomic stability and convergence in
member countries in order to achieve the formation of a common market over the medium
term. In this regard, SADC has announced a plan in March 2004 the goals of which include
establishment of a SADC customs union and implementation of a common external tariff by
2010, a common market pact by 2012, and establishment of a SADC central bank and
preparation for a single SADC currency by 2016.
While the goal of deeper regional integration is desirable, there is a concern that the
structure of the proposed SADC customs union will mirror that of SACU.
12
Even though the
tariff structure of the latter has been simplified somewhat in recent years, it remains complex,
consisting of ad valorem, specific, mixed, compound, formula duties based on reference
prices, and other duties and charges. The ad valorem duties cover around three-fourths of
tariff lines and comprise 39 bands, ranging between 0 percent and 55 percent. The specific,
mixed, compound, formula duties, and other duties and charges, cover an important set of
been provided into the SACU market on the basis of quotas. There are few other commitments at present on
liberalization in the sugar market.
12
SACU is a customs union between Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, South Africa, and Swaziland that was
originally formed in 1910. Under the agreement, a common external tariff is applied. An important feature is the
revenue sharing arrangement which diverts most of the customs revenue to Botswana, Lesotho, Namibia, and
Swaziland to compensate them for possible polarization effects from the customs union.
- 14 -
agricultural and agro-industrial products and apparel. While the SACU has harmonized
applied customs tariffs, excise duties, customs valuation, rules of origin, and contingency
trade remedies, not much else has been harmonized (for instance, customs procedures,
technical standards, etc.).
13
In addition, at a trade restrictiveness rating of 5, the current trade
regime in SACU cannot be characterized as open.
14
III. P
ROSPECTS OF COMESA AND SADC
In this section, we evaluate the prospects for expansion of intraregional trade in
COMESA and SADC. We discuss concerns with regard to overlapping memberships and
product complementarities, as well as trends in intraregional trade. These are useful to shed
light on the potential benefits from COMESA and SADC. We find that product
complementarities and levels of intraregional trade are low, although intraregional trade has
been expanding at a healthy pace in the last few years. Therefore, as we discuss later, the
main benefits from COMESA/SADC are likely to come from their ability to impart
credibility to trade policies in the region and their success in addressing structural
impediments to trade and behind the border measures. There is also an urgent need to
rationalize membership in these organizations.
A. Overlapping Memberships in Regional Arrangements
A number of regional arrangements are already in place in the eastern and southern
Africa region (COMESA, EAC, IOC, SADC, SACU, among others) and most countries are
members of more than one such organization (Kritzinger-van Niekerk and Moreira, 2002).
For instance, seven countries are members of both COMESA and SADC. One member of the
EAC is a member of SADC while two members belong to COMESA.
Overlapping memberships between the various regional arrangements have costs.
Negotiating resources and capacity have been stretched thin across the region. There are
administrative costs related to often complex rules of origin. Multiple membership fees are
expensive to pay and maintain. Conflicting objectives among rival arrangements have
contributed to a lack of progress in many areas (Iqbal and Khan, eds., 1997). As several of
these arrangements are in various stages of forming customs unions (COMESA, SADC, and
the EAC), it has become clear that conflicts of membership need to be resolved, but this may
prove politically difficult.
13
WTO (2003).
14
The IMF’s Trade Restrictiveness Index (TRI) is a combined rating of the tariff and NTBs in a country’s trade
regime. The tariff rating is based on simple average nominal tariffs while the NTB rating is based on product
coverage of NTBs. The TRI rates all countries, with the most open tariff regimes rated a “1,” and the most
restrictive regimes rated 10.
- 15 -
B. Product Complementarities
Product complementarities between countries are an important indicator of the
potential for expansion of intraregional trade. The bilateral product complementarity index
between two countries j and k (C
jk
) is defined as:
C
jk
= 100 – Σ
i
(M
ik
-X
ij
÷ 2) ( 1 )
where X
ij
represents the share of good i in the total exports of country j and M
ik
represents
the share of good i in the total imports of country k (Tsikata, 1999). The index is a measure
of similarities between the export basket of one country and the import basket of another
country. The value of the complementarity index can range from zero, which represents no
complementarity between exports and imports of two countries, to one hundred, which
implies a perfect match. The higher the index between two countries, the greater the product
complementarity.
We calculate bilateral product complementarity indices for COMESA and SADC
member countries using UN-COMTRADE data at the two-digit classification level. These
calculations are reported in Tables 1 and 2 below for COMESA and SADC respectively. For
example, in Table 1, the complementarity index between Egypt’s exports and Burundi’s
imports is 42.1, which is higher than, for instance, that between Malawi’s exports and
Burundi’s imports (7.1). Our results indicate that within COMESA, product
complementarities between exports of Egypt and imports of the other member countries
average to 43.0 while those for Kenya’s exports to the region average to 38.6. For all other
countries, the average product complementarity for exports is far lower.
15
What these numbers imply is that while there is scope for Egypt and Kenya to export
to the region, there is not much scope for other countries to do the same since there are few
complementarities for their exports. It is significant that Kenya and Egypt, which can be
viewed as the relatively more developed member countries, do not import many of the
products exported by other countries in the region. Similarly in SADC, there is
complementarity between South Africa’s exports and the imports of the rest of the region,
15
Evidence is presented in Tsikata (1999) regarding product complementarity indices for a number of regional
arrangements. In her analysis, all arrangements with a value of less than 25 have failed. In Table 1, we have
highlighted the product complementarity indices above 25.
- 16 -
Table 1. Bilateral Complementarity Indices in COMESA
Importing Country 1/
Burundi Comoros Egypt Ethiopia Kenya Malawi Mauritius Madagascar Rwanda Seychelles
Sudan Uganda Zambia Zimbabwe Average
Exporting Country 1/
Burundi ... 5.2 9.6 1.7 3.6 3.7 5.6 3.0 4.9 9.8
5.3 3.8 2.0 2.4 4.7
Comoros 4.4 ... 8.8 4.6 5.5 5.2 5.0 5.2 4.8 12.3
7.2 5.4 4.8 5.9 6.1
Egypt
42.1
24.0 ...
46.4 44.5 44.4 45.8 52.1 46.3 29.4
35.0 46.6 38.7 63.9 43.0
Ethiopia 5.2 7.7 15.4 ... 5.8 5.3 9.5 8.0 8.8 12.5
9.9 6.2 5.1 3.6 7.9
Kenya
37.8
23.6
33.8 40.2
...
44.0 38.5 47.1 44.1 31.6
32.1 41.9 35.3 51.3 38.6
Malawi 7.1 7.7 13.8 7.6 7.8 ... 9.3 7.9 10.3 14.0
12.1 9.1 8.1 6.6 9.3
Mauritius 10.3 9.1 13.6 10.3 9.9 11.3 ... 11.6 11.6 15.6
11.1 12.0 10.3 8.9 11.2
Madagascar 17.4 13.4 22.2 14.0 15.5 18.9
38.8
... 19.6 24.6
18.6 18.4 17.2 13.9 19.4
Rwanda 1.9 1.5 6.8 1.6 2.5 2.2 2.5 1.8 ... 9.1
4.9 2.0 1.9 2.6 3.2
Seychelles 4.4 2.4 11.4 3.1 3.3 2.7 6.7 3.4 3.2 ...
3.4 2.8 3.4 3.5 4.1
Sudan 16.1 8.2 14.0 20.4 20.6 21.2 20.6
28.5
17.2 13.6
... 19.3 12.4
45.8
19.8
Uganda 17.7 17.3 24.8 17.8 17.9 21.1
25.8
19.1 19.3
25.1
21.1 ... 17.7 14.8 20.0
Zambia 11.4 12.1 17.8 11.3 12.0 12.9 19.3 12.2 15.0 18.6
12.8 12.3 ... 11.9 13.8
Zimbabwe 13.9 12.5 16.8 10.5 10.8 14.0 18.4 10.5 14.3 14.1
11.0 14.2 9.1 ... 13.1
Source: IMF staff calculations using UN COMTRADE data.
1/ Indices for Angola, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, Djibouti, and Eritrea were not computed because of lack of data.
Table 2. Bilateral Complementarity Indices in SADC
Importing Country 1/
Botswana Malawi Mauritius Mozambique Namibia South Africa Swaziland Tanzania Zambia Zimbabwe Average
Exporting Country 1/
Botswana ... 7.5 11.3 17.8 9.6 13.0 9.7 7.4 7.8 8.9 10.3
Malawi 13.7 ... 9.3 18.4 11.6 11.6 13.0 9.3 8.1 6.6 11.3
Mauritius 16.8 11.3 ... 21.3 14.6 15.3 15.8 12.0 10.3 8.9 14.0
Mozambique 23.2 21.8
26.7
... 23.9 24.6
26.2
20.8 19.5 19.1 22.9
Namibia 22.8 14.0 20.5 24.8 ... 17.1 18.8 11.5 21.0 11.3 18.0
South Africa
53.9 48.5 54.1 59.4 54.1
...
55.1 51.3 51.0 49.9 53.0
Swaziland
27.9
20.4 23.5
30.0 29.9
22.0 ... 20.6 19.0 17.6 23.4
Tanzania 16.4 13.1 20.2 20.2 13.4 13.2 13.3 ... 8.9 7.1 14.0
Zambia 19.0 12.9 19.3 23.2 14.9 16.6 14.2 12.8 ... 11.9 16.1
Zimbabwe 13.7 14.0 18.4 20.4 10.6 11.5 11.5 10.6 9.1 ... 13.3
Source: IMF staff calculations using UN COMTRADE data.
1/ Indices for Angola, the Democratic Republic of the Congo, and Lesotho were not computed because of lack of data.
- 17 -
but not vice versa. The asymmetric complementarity essentially implies that the more
developed economies of Egypt, Kenya and South Africa are in a much better position to
market their exports in COMESA/SADC but the less developed countries are unable to find
significant markets in COMESA/SADC. The asymmetric product complementarity in favor
of the more developed members raises a concern over possible polarization as investment
may be attracted towards the larger and more industrially diversified economies in the region.
Our results are in line with Yeats (1998) which finds that African countries tend to
have exports concentrated in a few commodities, reducing their possibilities of intraregional
trade. A similar result is obtained in Chauvin and Gaulier (2002) for SADC—they point out
that it will be hard for South Africa to function as a “growth pole” or an important outlet for
the exports of the rest of the SADC region.
16
The authors find that SADC countries have
similar disadvantages in manufactured goods (except South Africa) while having similar
advantages in primary goods. South Africa appears to be the only source of manufactured
goods, and even here, the range of products is limited. The major finding of that study is that
potential to expand trade within SADC is small and existing opportunities may already have
been exploited.
C. Trade Diversion Versus Trade Expansion
Tables 3 and 4 report growth rates in intraregional and total trade for the entire
COMESA and SADC regions—Zimbabwe is excluded because of concerns over data
quality. Intraregional trade is computed taking into consideration all present members of
COMESA and SADC, even though the membership may have been different over time.
17
This is to ensure that growth estimates do not reflect merely additions in membership but
genuine trends in trade.
Within COMESA, it can be seen from Table 3 that intraregional trade has expanded
at an average annual rate of 18.8 percent since the creation of the FTA in 2000. Moreover, it
appears that growth in intraregional trade slowed in the mid- and late-1990s but recovered
after the creation of the FTA. While the time period under consideration is relatively short to
arrive at any definitive conclusion about the role of the FTA, the rapid response of
intraregional trade raises the question of trade diversion versus expansion. At this time, the
literature has not empirically examined the question of trade diversion but the possibilities
are widely acknowledged since 7 of the 19 member countries have trade regimes that can be
described as at least moderately restrictive (Table 6).
18
16
Lewis and others (2003) also conclude that the South African economy is not large enough to serve as a
growth pole for the region.
17
It is not important to distinguish between intraregional exports and imports since they are essentially the
same.
18
These are countries that are rated a 6 or above on the 10-point IMF’s trade restrictiveness index.
- 18 -
To shed light on the question, it does not appear that an increase in imports from the
region has been accompanied by a decline in imports from the rest of the world in recent
years. In fact, since total imports have grown at around 8 percent since the mid-1990s
(Table 4) and from the very small share of intraregional trade in total imports, it is obvious
that imports from the rest of the world must also be growing at close to 8 percent. Moreover,
while the proportion of intraregional imports in total imports has gone up, it does not appear
to have shifted dramatically. In other words, by this admittedly rather coarse test, we find
very limited evidence of trade diversion. Total exports from the COMESA region also have
been growing at a healthy pace of almost 10 percent in recent years.
Examining the growth rates of intraregional and total trade for the SADC region in
Tables 3 and 4, the period between 1991–95 stands out as the period with significant average
Table 3. Intraregional Trade
1991–1995 1996–2000 2001–2003
(as a percent of total imports)
COMESA 1/ 3.6 3.6 4.1
SADC 7.6 9.7 10.4
(average annual change in percent)
COMESA 1/ 19.8 5.9 18.8
SADC 34.6 1.7 8.0
Source: IMF staff calculations based on IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics.
Zimbabwe is excluded from all computations.
1/ Data are unavailable for Eritrea and Swaziland.
Table 4. Total Trade
1992–1995 1996–2000 2001–2003
(average annual change in percent)
Exports
COMESA 1/ 3.6 9.9 9.4
SADC 0.8 -0.6 14.4
Imports
COMESA 1/ 8.5 8.0 7.6
SADC 9.7 0.1 11.2
Source: IMF staff calculations based on IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics.
Zimbabwe is excluded from all computations.
1/ Data are unavailable for Eritrea and Swaziland.
- 19 -
annual growth in intraregional trade, around 35 percent. This is far higher than the growth in
total imports of the region, which grew at a rate of around 10 percent. This expansion in
intraregional exports is mainly due to the trade integration of South Africa and the lifting of
sanctions after the abolition of apartheid. During the mid- and late-1990s, total imports into
the region stayed flat while intraregional trade grew at a marginal rate of under 2 percent.
In recent years (2000–03), intraregional and total trade in the SADC region appear to
have broken out of the stagnation of the mid-1990s. Intraregional imports appear to have
grown at a slower annual pace than total imports—clearly, these trends do not support the
hypothesis of trade diversion. In addition, growth in total exports from the region looks as
though it has picked up as well after being practically flat over the 1990s.
While the time period since 2000 is too short a time frame to draw firm conclusions,
the preceding provides some evidence to refute concerns over trade diversion from
COMESA and SADC. On the subject of trade expansion, the growth in total exports over the
last few years is encouraging and one might cite anecdotal evidence of recent diversification
into nontraditional exports in the region. However, it is not clear what impact COMESA and
SADC might have had—one cannot say whether growth in exports in the region is due to
economies of scale, the competitive effect, or other benefits of COMESA/SADC or due to
unilateral liberalization undertaken by several member states in recent years (Subramanian
and others, 2000), or other factors such as AGOA.
D. Potential for Trade Expansion in COMESA and SADC
Although intraregional and total trade have been growing at a healthy pace in recent
years, opportunities for expansion of trade from greater integration in the COMESA and
SADC regions might be somewhat limited since product complementarities and levels of
intraregional trade are low and there is a risk of polarization.
As has been noted in the literature (see Iqbal and Khan, eds., 1997; and Oyejide,
Elbadawi, and Yeo, 1997), African trade has been hindered by a number of factors including
distorted trade regimes, high transaction costs due to inadequate transport, information and
communications infrastructure, lack of political commitment and frequent policy reversals,
difficulties in implementing harmonization provisions, multiple and conflicting objectives of
overlapping regional arrangements, and limited administrative resources.
It has been pointed out that RTAs can play an important role in addressing these
hindrances to trade (Oyejide, 1997).
They can help address concerns over policy credibility
by locking in domestically implemented trade liberalization and functioning as an agency of
restraint. Regional cooperation can be effective in addressing weaknesses in infrastructure,
and harmonization of standards and customs procedures. A strong RTA can also strengthen
Africa’s bargaining power in the multilateral negotiations. In the same vein, Lawrence (1997)
argues that regional integration can be a means to achieve deep integration—where deep
integration includes integration of national regulatory systems and policies, competition
policies and investment rules. Deep integration is viewed as having the potential to create an
- 20 -
open and credible policy environment to encourage foreign direct investment and export-
oriented growth. According to Chauvin and Gaulier (2002) also, important structural changes
may be necessary in order to expand trade potential in the region.
In some ways, the agenda for integration in SADC and COMESA reflects attempts to
address these challenges in development of African trade. SADC has taken an approach to
regional integration that attempts to address infrastructure constraints, while COMESA has
placed more emphasis on harmonization of standards and customs procedures and trade
facilitation. However, the lack of political commitment has afflicted both organizations,
impeding progress in implementing their vision. The lack of political commitment is also
reflected in the fact that the larger economies of the region (South Africa in SADC, Kenya,
and Egypt in COMESA) have not taken on active roles as champions of regional integration
and liberalization.
As a result, both organizations have a great deal to do in order for countries to take
advantage of possible benefits from regional integration. Going forward, it is important that
COMESA and SADC become effective vehicles for nondiscriminatory tariff liberalization as
well as addressing weaknesses in infrastructure, harmonization of standards and customs
procedures. COMESA and SADC should function as agencies of restraint and provide policy
credibility through locking in trade openness.
IV. C
HALLENGES IN TARIFF LIBERALIZATION AND HARMONIZATION
As discussed in the previous section, regional integration in COMESA and SADC
can deliver important benefits to the region. An important component of maximizing
potential benefits from COMESA and SADC will be committing to a low and uniform
common external tariff in a customs union to provide policy credibility and locking in tariff
liberalization and harmonization on a multilateral basis. Below, we discuss some
impediments to accomplishing this goal.
A. Dependence on Trade Taxes
The dependence on trade taxes constitutes a major hurdle for tariff liberalization in
the region. Some details on the proportion of trade taxes in total revenue and GDP are
presented in Table 5. In all of the countries in the region, except South Africa, trade taxes
account for over 10 percent of total fiscal revenue. In 8 out of 24 countries, trade taxes are
over 20 percent of revenue. In only 4 of the 24 countries, namely Rwanda, South Africa,
Tanzania, and Uganda, are trade taxes less than 2 percent of GDP. Lesotho, Namibia, and
Swaziland are the most dependent on trade taxes. As shown for SADC in Tsikata (1999),
trade liberalization is likely to create a significant fiscal gap through the lowering of import
duties in some countries. Moreover, as noted in Chauvin and Gaulier (2002), regional
integration may lead to changes in the structure of individual economies that could lead to a
contraction of previously import-substituting industries that were important sources of
- 21 -
revenue. In the same study, the authors estimate that a SADC FTA may lead to as much as a
6 percent decline in total revenue.
The challenge in maintaining fiscal sustainability in the face of trade liberalization
should not be minimized. In particular, as a recent study by Baunsgard and Keen (2004)
demonstrates, most low-income countries have not been able to replace lost trade tax revenue
from other revenue sources. While the authors do not rule out indirect effects of improved
economic efficiency on tax revenue, their results do suggest that concerns over tax revenue
are serious. On the other hand, as noted by Mussa (1997), the fiscal situation should not be
used as an excuse to inordinately delay trade reform. Distorted trade regimes operate as
impediments to improving efficiencies of resource allocation. As reforms are implemented,
care should be taken to broaden the effective tax base and seek alternate sources of revenue
Table 5. Trade Tariffs and Revenues in Eastern and Southern Africa
Maximum
Tariff
Simple
Average
Tariff
Trade Tax
Revenue/GDP
Trade Tax
Revenue/
Total Revenue
Effective
Collected
Tariff Rate
(in percent)
Angola 35 19.0 ... ... ...
Burundi 40 23.5 3.4 18.6 22.6
Comoros 200 37.9 2.8 31.0 15.1
Congo, Dem. Rep. of 20 13.0 ... ... ...
Djibouti 0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Eritrea 25 9.0 ... ... ...
Ethiopia 35 17.5 2.6 18.4 13.7
Kenya 35 17.2 3.6 17.6 12.4
Malawi 25 13.6 2.5 12.4 7.2
Mauritius 80 19.9 5.4 31.5 13.5
Madagascar 25 16.2 2.8 25.6 11.3
Mozambique 25 11.1 2.2 18.9 8.1
Rwanda 30 9.3 1.4 14.2 10.6
SACU 60 11.4 ... ... ...
Botswana ... ... 7.7 18.1 24.2
Lesotho ... ... 18.0 58.0 22.4
Namibia ... ... 12.1 38.0 26.7
South Africa ... ... 0.8 3.0 ...
Swaziland ... ... 15.3 55.2 19.6
Seychelles 200 25.0 ... 26.9 18.2
Sudan 45 22.6 ... ... ...
Tanzania 25 12.5 1.3 11.6 8.9
Uganda 15 9.0 1.7 11.3 8.5
Zambia 20 11.5 5.9 30.9 19.9
Zimbabwe 100 19.7 2.6 10.4 13.0
Source: Tariffs data are from Trade Policy Information Database. Tax data for the tax year 2000 are courtesy of
Thomas Baunsgaard.
- 22 -
and if these are limited, better expenditure control should be emphasized. Similar
recommendations are made by Ebrill, Stotsky, and Gropp (1999).
According to Tsikata (1999), revisiting the eligibility criteria for tax exemptions in
SADC would be an important step in strengthening the revenue effort, particularly since
exemptions can account for a large portion of lost revenue in African countries. For instance,
exemptions covered over 42 percent of imports in Tanzania in 1999 (WTO, 2000). To the
extent that exemptions are for the purpose of offsetting the high tariffs, it should be possible
to reduce the tariff rates along with a streamlining of exemptions. These efforts could be
taken in conjunction with measures to improve tax administration or broaden the tax base,
with the goal of increasing reliance on domestic sources of taxation.
B. Disparities in Restrictiveness of Trade Regime
There are great disparities in the restrictiveness of trade regimes across the region, as
can be seen below (Table 6). Several countries such as Djibouti, Malawi, Rwanda, Uganda,
and Zambia rank among the most open in the world, while others such as Burundi, Comoros,
and Seychelles rank among the most restrictive trade regimes in the world. Only about 9 of
the countries have open trade regimes (rated below a 3) and these do not include the
relatively developed countries in the region (Egypt, Kenya, and South Africa). Clearly, the
more developed countries have not played a leadership role in trade liberalization in the
region. In these circumstances, harmonization in the sense of a low and uniform common
external tariff will involve significant adjustment from a majority of the countries, including
the more developed ones, and agreement will be complicated by the very different starting
positions.
At this time, it is worthwhile to re-emphasize the desirability of a low, common
external tariff by looking at the potential for trade diversion in the context of a SADC or
COMESA free trade area. The more restrictive the trade regime in a country (as in Burundi,
Comoros, or Seychelles), the greater the preferential margin granted to partner countries in
the FTA. Therefore, the potential for welfare losses due to trade diversion is the greatest for
these countries. MFN liberalization can help in reducing these losses. In addition, the
preponderance of evidence supports the hypothesis that trade openness contributes greatly to
growth (Berg and Krueger, 2003).
In this regard, the RTA should be viewed as an opportunity to lower tariffs on an
MFN basis to gain from the policy credibility of the regional commitment. Careful
sequencing and appropriate monetary and exchange rate policies can help in addressing any
sharp balance of payments swings.
- 23 -
Table 6. Restrictiveness Ratings in Eastern and Southern Africa, 2003
Tariff Rating
(1-5)
NTB rating
(1-3)
Overall TRI
rating
(1-10)
COMESA
Angola 3 1 3
Burundi 5 2 8
Comoros 5 2 8
Congo, Dem. Rep. of 2 1 2
Djibouti 1 1 1
Egypt 4 2 7
Eritrea 1 2 4
Ethiopia 3 2 6
Kenya 3 2 6
Malawi 2 1 2
Mauritius 3 2 6
Madagascar 3 1 3
Rwanda 2 1 2
Seychelles 5 3 10
Sudan 4 1 4
Swaziland 2 2 5
Uganda 2 1 2
Zambia 2 1 2
Zimbabwe 3 2 6
SADC
Angola 3 1 3
Congo, Dem. Rep. of 2 1 2
Malawi 2 1 2
Mauritius 3 2 6
Mozambique 2 1 2
SACU 2 2 5
Tanzania 2 2 5
Zambia 2 1 2
Zimbabwe 3 2 6
Source: Trade Policy Information Database. See footnote 14.
C. Impact of Common External Tariff on Tariff Structures
In this section, we examine additional difficulties in agreeing on a low and uniform
common external tariff. We analyze three- and four-band tariff structures, similar to proposed
CETs in the EAC and COMESA. Since SADC does not yet have a proposed CET, we
assume that they will eventually move to a similar simplified structure. In accordance with
the proposals put forward by the two arrangements, tariff lines are separated into raw
- 24 -
materials, capital goods, intermediates, and finished goods. An escalating tariff structure is
used, with the highest rates reserved for finished goods, and the lowest for capital goods and
raw materials. It should be noted that this tariff structure can be a means of providing
protection to manufacturing and builds in an anti-export bias. Not only are higher tariffs
reserved for finished goods but low tariffs on inputs provide an additional layer of escalation.
In thiscontext, agreeing on a low and uniform common external tariff can minimize the
degree of protection and help in countering the anti-export bias.
We first examine the impact of the different CETs on the average degree of
protection. We have classified all tariff lines into the four categories of goods based on the
six-digit level classification. While our classification is not likely to be exactly the same as
that which will be finally agreed by the RTAs, it should be indicative. Table 7 displays the
impact of 16 possible CET combinations on the simple average tariff—using our own
classification of goods into the three or four tariff bands. The maximum tariff is allowed to
vary from 20 to 40 percent, the tariff on intermediate goods is allowed to vary between
10 and 15 percent, and the tariff on capital goods is allowed to vary between 0 and 5 percent.
The tariff on raw materials is always maintained at 0 percent. Scenarios 1–8 model a three-
band CET, and scenarios 9-16 model a four-band CET.
From Table 7, it is clear that raising the maximum tariff, or going from a three- to
four-band CET has a tremendous impact on the average degree of protection. Increasing the
tariff on capital goods from 0 to 5 percent increases the simple average tariff by 1 percent.
Increasing the tariff on intermediate goods by 5 percent increases the simple average tariff by
Scenario 1
Scenario 2
Scenario 3
Scenario 4
Scenario 5
Scenario 6
Scenario 7
Scenario 8
Raw materials
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Capital goods
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Intermediate goods
10 10 10 10 15 15 15 15
Finished goods
20 25 30 40 20 25 30 40
Simple average
10.2 12.0 13.7 17.2 11.9 13.6 15.4 18.8
Agricultural
9.5 11.7 13.8 18.1 10.0 12.1 14.3 18.6
Non-agricultural
10.4 12.0 13.7 17.0 12.2 13.9 15.5 18.9
Standard Deviation
8.2 10.3 12.6 17.1 8.5 10.3 12.3 16.6
Scenario 9
Scenario 10
Scenario 11
Scenario 12
Scenario 13
Scenario 14
Scenario 15
Scenario 16
Raw materials
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Capital goods
5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5
Intermediate goods
10 10 10 10 15 15 15 15
Finished goods
20 25 30 40 20 25 30 40
Simple average
11.2 13.0 14.7 18.2 12.9 14.6 16.4 19.8
Agricultural
9.5 11.7 13.8 18.1 10.0 12.1 14.3 18.6
Non-agricultural
11.5 13.2 14.9 18.2 13.4 15.0 16.7 20.0
Standard deviation
7.1 9.3 11.6 16.2 7.2 9.1 11.1 15.5
1/ Source:
IMF staff calculations.
Table 7. Average Tariffs Under Three- and Four-Band Common External Tariff
- 25 -
approximately 1.7 percent. Increasing the tariff on finished goods by 5 percent increases the
simple average tariff by approximately 1.8 percent.
Comparing the results in Table 7 to the existing levels of the simple average tariff in
Table 5, it is apparent that a maximum tariff of 25 percent and a three-band CET will yield,
at the minimum, a simple average tariff of 12 percent (Scenario 2). This results in little
liberalization or a reversal for several countries in the region (including Djibouti, Eritrea,
Mozambique, Rwanda, Uganda, and Zambia, and members of SACU) and could potentially
imply welfare losses to these countries from the arrangement. On the other hand, the
maximum tariff of 25 percent reduces significantly the degree of protection available to
industries in several other countries. Countries like Angola, Burundi, Comoros, Ethiopia,
Kenya, Mauritius, Madagascar, Seychelles, Sudan, and Zimbabwe have significantly higher
protection at present and may face temporary adjustment costs from liberalization. As
emphasized earlier, implementing a CET in this situation will require careful sequencing of
reforms and complementary policies. In addition, for all member countries to benefit from
liberalization under the RTA, it is important that no country suffer a reversal in liberalization.
A three-band tariff structure with a maximum tariff of 20 percent would be the preferred
option in this regard.
19
In Table 8, we analyze the impact of the five most liberal CETs studied above on the
tariff structures in the region. Information is provided on the number of tariff lines that would
remain unchanged, or experience an increase or decrease in tariffs. Acronyms describing the
countries are BDI (Burundi); COM (Comoros); MOZ (Mozambique); RWA (Rwanda); TZA
(Tanzania); UGA (Uganda); ZMB (Zambia); ZWE (Zimbabwe); MUS (Mauritius); MWI
(Malawi); MDG (Madagascar); and KEN (Kenya).
20
As can be seen, the implementation of
the CET based on the classification of raw materials, intermediates, capital and finished
goods will imply substantial changes in the tariff structure in all countries. Tariffs on a
number of lines will go down, and on a number of lines will go up.
Clearly, this has the potential to hurt some sectors and benefit others in each country.
In fact, both COMESA and EAC are facing tremendous difficulty in agreeing on the
classification of goods since an input for one country may be a finished good for another.
19
It should be emphasized that a common external tariff, once set, is not changed very easily. A high maximum
tariff can lock in all countries in the region, making further liberalization difficult. A maximum tariff of
20 percent is also recommended by Hinkle and Schiff (2004).
20
The latest available information on the tariff schedule was used for these countries, ranging from the years
2000-04. The analysis for other countries was not possible due to data unavailability.
- 26 -
BDI COM MOZ RWA SACU TZA UGA ZMB ZWE MUS MWI MDG KEN
1. CET 1
Capital goods 0
Raw materials 5
Intermediate goods 10
Finished goods 20
Number of tariff lines that will
Decrease 3,209 4,767 2,681 3,908 727 2,335 1,348 3,090 2,666 1,782 2,991 1,479 3,699
No change 1,093 103 136 457 1,103 1,087 685 330 629 739 411 440 181
Increase 811 243 2,296 748 3,283 1,691 3,080 1,693 1,818 2,592 1,711 3,194 1,233
2. CET 2
Capital goods 0
Raw materials 5
Intermediate goods 15
Finished goods 20
Number of tariff lines that will
Decrease 3,155 4,767 2,679 2,543 649 2,332 954 2,544 2,457 1,739 2,975 1,402 3,043
No change 125 103 136 1,822 1,080 642 1,079 873 576 733 53 428 826
Increase 1,833 243 2,298 748 3,384 2,139 3,080 1,696 2,080 2,641 2,085 3,283 1,244
3. CET 3
Capital goods 0
Raw materials 0
Intermediate goods 15
Finished goods 20
Number of tariff lines that will
Decrease 3,155 4,767 2,682 2,803 683 2,334 954 2,662 2,583 1,743 3,004 1,603 3,144
No change 153 177 321 1,563 1,453 817 1,093 794 535 1,057 87 496 763
Increase 1,805 169 2,110 747 2,977 1,962 3,066 1,657 1,995 2,313 2,022 3,014 1,206
4. CET 4
Capital goods 0
Raw materials 0
Intermediate goods 10
Finished goods 25
Number of tariff lines that will
Decrease 3,182 4,767 1,697 4,162 709 1,231 1,348 2,179 2,523 1,778 1,951 1,568 3,186
No change 1,145 77 1,308 199 1,317 2,368 699 1,270 733 1,030 1,509 493 679
Increase 786 269 2,108 752 3,087 1,514 3,066 1,664 1,857 2,305 1,653 3,052 1,248
5. CET 5
Capital goods 0
Raw materials 0
Intermediate goods 10
Finished goods 20
Number of tariff lines that will
Decrease 3,209 4,767 2,684 4,168 761 2,337 1,348 3,208 2,792 1,786 3,020 1,680 3,800
No change 1,121 177 321 198 1,476 1,262 699 251 588 1,063 445 508 118
Increase 783 169 2,108 747 2,876 1,514 3,066 1,654 1,733 2,264 1,648 2,925 1,195
Source: IMF staff calculations.
1/ Country acronyms are as follows: BDI (Burundi); COM (Comoros); MOZ (Mozambique); RWA (Rwanda); TZA (Tanzania); UGA (Uganda); ZMB (Zambia); ZWE (Zimbabwe);
MUS (Mauritius); MWI (Malawi); MDG (Madagascar); and KEN (Kenya).
Table 8. Impact of Common External Tariff on Selected Countries 1/
- 27 -
While there may be a great deal of temptation to protect domestic industries by
negotiating for a suitable classification of goods, countries in the region should bear in mind
that this will only serve to highlight their lack of commitment to true liberalization and will
cause delays in agreement and implementation problems down the road. To the extent that
their goal is to liberalize and gain policy credibility, protracted negotiations in this area are
likely to be counterproductive.
Another issue with agreeing on a CET is that there may be a conflict with tariff
bindings at the WTO. When countries bind their tariffs at the WTO, they put a ceiling on
their applied tariff rates. Therefore, tariff bindings may get violated if the bound rates are
lower than the corresponding rates under the CET. In Table 9, we present some estimates on
the number of bound tariff lines that may be in conflict with the CET for COMESA and
SADC member countries, depending on the agreed CET.
Table 9. Number of Tariff Bindings to Be Renegotiated at
World Trade Organization (WTO)
Common External Tariff
0, 5, 15, 30 0, 10, 25 0, 10, 20
Burundi 197 189 110
Mozambique 0 0 0
Rwanda 160 125 72
SACU 1,897 1,314 1,070
Tanzania 0 0 0
Uganda 0 0 0
Zambia 0 0 0
Zimbabwe 221 141 121
Mauritius 27 27 27
Malawi 1 0 0
Madagascar 28 28 27
Kenya 6 6 6
Source: IMF staff calculations.
From Table 9, it appears that over half of the countries except Mozambique,
Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia will exceed their tariff bindings in order to implement the
suggested CET. The SACU countries will have the largest number of tariff lines in excess of
bindings, reflecting the fact that they have bound a greater number of lines in the WTO. For
other countries—Burundi, Rwanda, Zimbabwe, Mauritius, Malawi, Madagascar, and
Kenya—the number of lines is not very large. It should be pointed out that the enforcement
of tariff bindings in the WTO depends on whether a country’s trading partners raise a
complaint at the WTO.
- 28 -
V. E
UROPEAN UNION—ECONOMIC PARTNERSHIP AGREEMENT (EPA) NEGOTIATIONS
In this section, we examine and discuss developments and issues relating to the
ongoing negotiations with the EU on EPAs. The EU is an important trade partner in respect
of both imports and exports for countries in the region (Table 10), and the outcome of these
negotiations will have a significant impact. At this point in time, not much progress has been
made in the negotiations as individual countries are in the process of formulating their trade
negotiating positions.
Historically, a group of 77 African-
Caribbean-Pacific (ACP) countries, which
includes all member countries of COMESA
and SADC except Egypt and South Africa,
have been recipients of unilateral
preferences into the EU market under the
Lomé conventions. These preferences have
provided them with important market access
for agricultural and other exports. However,
these unilateral preferences are
incompatible with WTO rules—since the
“Enabling Clause” in the GATT does not
allow unilateral preferences that
discriminate between groups of developing
countries, except in favor of LDCs. Since
preferences granted to the ACP countries
are neither available to all developing
countries, nor restricted to just LDCs, the
Cotonou agreement, concluded in 2000,
requires all ACP countries to negotiate
WTO-compatible EPAs with the EU to
replace unilateral preferential arrangements
by end-2007. The EPAs will involve
reciprocal market access into the ACP
countries for the EU with a possible
transition period of 10–12 years for the
phasing out of trade barriers between the
parties (in accordance with GATT Article
XXIV).
The EPAs have a development focus—they are to assist ACP countries in enlarging
their markets by improving the predictability and transparency of the regulatory framework
for trade and creating conditions for increased investment. In this context, the EU has placed
strong emphasis on South-South integration through reinforcing existing regional integration
initiatives, harmonization of rules and creation of customs unions. Negotiations are being
conducted with regional economic groupings instead of individual countries.
Table 10. European Union (EU)—Share in Trade
Exports
to EU
Imports from
EU
(as a percent of total)
Angola 13.7 52.2
Burundi 50.0 30.6
Comoros 69.4 42.2
Congo, Dem. Rep. of 66.8 41.6
Djibouti 3.5 21.8
Eritrea ... ...
Ethiopia 31.0 19.8
Kenya 30.1 23.6
Malawi 31.3 9.8
Mauritius 71.3 41.5
Madagascar 51.5 52.3
Mozambique 63.7 14.6
Rwanda 10.5 26.4
SACU ... ...
Botswana 59.6 45.2
Lesotho ... ...
Namibia ... ...
South Africa 38.9 44.9
Swaziland ... ...
Seychelles 68.4 45.5
Sudan 15.0 29.1
Tanzania 32.0 23.6
Uganda 60.7 20.6
Zambia 16.6 10.0
Zimbabwe 18.0 10.1
Source: IMF staff calculations.
- 29 -
In eastern and southern Africa, the two regional economic groupings that are
negotiating with the EU are de facto COMESA and SADC. At present, the so-called ESA
(Eastern and Southern Africa) negotiating group comprises 16 of COMESA’s 19 member
countries.
21
The SADC negotiating group, on the other hand, includes 7 of the 13 member
countries (Angola, Mozambique, Tanzania, and the SACU countries) of SADC with South
Africa participating as an observer.
A. Features of EPA
The EPA is expected to take the form of an FTA.
22
It is expected that the EU will
provide market access similar to that under the “Everything But Arms” (EBA) initiative.
23
The provision of such market access under EPAs, it should be noted, will not be an
improvement for LDC members of the negotiating group and by itself, will provide them
with few incentives to participate. The rules of origin under EBA are more restrictive than
those under the Cotonou Agreement. Therefore, LDCs are likely to seek an improvement
through simpler and less restrictive rules of origin and full cumulation across all ACP
countries, the EU, and other EBA countries. Non-LDC members of ESA and the SADC
negotiating groups, on the other hand, have greater incentive to participate in order to
preserve market access to the EU.
An important issue to be negotiated is the level of market access offered to the EU in
reciprocity. Since the EU has committed to an asymmetric approach in terms of product
coverage and transition periods, it is likely that African countries will not be required to
liberalize all sectors and will be allowed a reasonable transition time. In order to be
compatible with WTO rules (GATT, Article XXIV), the agreement will require the
reciprocal liberalization of substantially all trade by African countries—the EU has expressed
its ambition that over 90 percent of trade will be covered over the long term. However, the
interpretation of this provision leaves considerable room for uncertainty and countries in the
region are likely to push for exclusion of a greater number of products from the agreement. It
has been pointed out that even if the agreement were to liberalize 90 percent of trade, African
countries could potentially end up without liberalizing most of their important domestic
sectors because with current high tariffs, imports in the important sectors might be small
21
The countries excluded are Angola, Egypt, and Swaziland.
22
The discussion in this section is based upon Hinkle and Schiff (2004) and the European Union, 2003. It
applies to all ACP countries, including African ACP countries, unless specifically noted.
23
The EBA, which took effect in March 2001, grants 48 LDCs duty free access to EU markets for all goods
except weapons and armaments, for an unlimited time period, and without any quantitative restrictions. Some
trade restrictions remain on a group of “sensitive products”—rice, sugar, and bananas. Liberalization for rice
and sugar is postponed until 2009 and until 2006 for bananas. Restrictions on these items take the form of duty-
free tariff quotas on these products which will be increased annually.
- 30 -
(Hinkle and Schiff, 2004). This would be disappointing and another missed opportunity to
reap efficiency gains from trade. A suggestion that has been made is that the agreement
should aim for liberalization of 90 percent of tariff lines and that there should be limits on the
number of tariff lines within a chapter or heading that can be excluded from liberalization.
This will ensure that entire sectors do not escape liberalization. Moreover, the agreements
should phase in additional tariff reductions over a period of time to cover over 95 percent of
tariff lines.
Nontariff barriers such as sanitary and phytosanitary standards are also to be
addressed in the agreement. Here, the development aspect of the EPA is expected to come
into play through technical assistance and capacity building measures. For instance, the EU is
expected to support regional and national capacity building to develop regional testing and
certification institutions in Africa (COMESA Secretariat, 2003a). With regard to other
features of the agreement: safeguard measures for both industrial and agricultural products
are expected to be included. The ACP countries are to provide the EU with a list of products
for the priority removal of export subsidies.
24
A significant part of the EPA is that ACP countries and the EU have agreed to
liberalize trade in services on the basis of a positive list approach. To address concerns over
weak regulatory and supervisory systems in African countries, the EU is to provide support
in the development of the services sector and in appropriate sequencing of liberalization
commitments. There is also provision for a special safeguard in the area of services. The
coverage of services in the agreement along with appropriate sequencing and regulation
could be very beneficial for African countries provided they take advantage of the
opportunity to liberalize and make substantial commitments. Services provision in areas such
as accounting, telecommunications, transport, finance, etc., is fairly inefficient in the region
and drives up the transaction costs of doing business.
The negotiations will also cover the issue of improved market access for mode 4
supply of services (movement of natural persons). This is important since worker remittances
from temporary movement of workers can be a significant source of income for developing
countries and can stimulate growth through dissemination of technological and business
skills. It is unclear how generous the improvement in market access for movement of natural
person will be because of Europe’s concerns over absorbing labor flows from the accession
countries.
B. Overlapping Membership Issues
As discussed above in Section II, overlapping memberships between RTAs in Africa
are a significant obstacle to achieving the goals of regional integration. In this regard, the
EU’s plan to push the formation of customs unions is a particularly beneficial aspect of the
24
The EU has committed to remove export subsidies in the current WTO round of negotiations.
- 31 -
EPAs in that they will require a long-overdue rationalization in the membership of COMESA
and SADC, since it is technically impossible for a country to be a member of more than one
customs union. The problems of overlapping membership are:
1. Seven countries (Angola, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Malawi, Mauritius,
Swaziland, Zambia, and Zimbabwe) are members of both COMESA and SADC.
2. Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda are members of the EAC customs union. While Kenya
and Uganda are members of COMESA, Tanzania is a member of SADC. Even if
COMESA and the EAC harmonize (there is some potential here), there is still the
issue that Tanzania is a member of SADC and not COMESA.
3. Egypt is not an ACP country but is a member of COMESA.
4. SACU is already a customs union and includes South Africa, which is not an ACP
country.
One option, albeit unlikely, may be that COMESA and SADC decide to harmonize
their tariff structures and form one large customs union, which would also be in line with the
goals of the African Union. Alternatively, countries in the region would have to choose the
RTA they wish to be a member of. Based on the membership in EPA negotiating groups, it is
possible that Angola, and Swaziland will drop out of COMESA while the Democratic
Republic of Congo, Malawi, Mauritius, Zambia, and Zimbabwe will drop out of SADC over
the medium term. Given that the EAC customs union protocol has already been adopted, the
member states—Kenya, Uganda and Tanzania—can decide to harmonize with either
COMESA or SADC. Tanzania might elect to leave SADC or Kenya and Uganda might leave
COMESA. This might be ultimately determined by which group is viewed as having
negotiated the more favorable EPA or regional agreement.
It remains to be seen how the issues of Egypt and South Africa will be addressed.
Given that Egypt’s exports to the rest of COMESA are approximately 1 percent of its total
exports, and that it does not provide great scope for exports from other countries in the
region, its membership of COMESA is likely to come under greater scrutiny.
25
With regard
to South Africa, it will be extremely difficult administratively to separate goods originating
in South Africa versus the rest of SACU. Given that South Africa has an FTA with the EU, it
may be much simpler and possible for them to participate in the agreement.
25
Egypt currently benefits from preferences into the EU market under the Euromed Agreement. Egypt may also
not be interested in implementing the COMESA CET.
- 32 -
C. Revenue Losses Owing to EPA
One of the major concerns is over possible losses in fiscal revenue given that the EU
is the biggest trade partner for the region. In Table 11, we present estimates of the revenue
loss from the removal of all tariffs on all EU imports. These estimates have been computed
using the UN COMTRADE data on imports classified at the six-digit tariff line level. The
revenue loss, as a percent of GDP, is computed by assuming that the statutory rates are
actually applied to each of the tariff lines so that this is an upper bound on the possible
revenue loss. These estimates do not take into account the impact of exemptions, which are
reported to be widespread in sub-Saharan Africa. In order to estimate the possible impact of
exemptions, we assume that they are applied equally to imports from the EU and the rest of
world. We accordingly present an adjusted estimate of loss in trade revenue as a percentage
of total revenue.
Table 11. Trade Revenue Loss Owing to EPA
In percent
of GDP
In percent of
Total Revenue
1/
Burundi 1.6 6.9
Comoros 1.6 6.3
Kenya 0.6 7.7
Madagascar 0.2 1.9
Malawi 0.6 3.3
Mauritius 1.8 11.8
Rwanda 0.8 10.2
SACU 0.5 ...
Tanzania 0.3 1.1
Uganda 0.2 0.7
Zambia 0.5 4.0
Source: IMF staff calculations.
1/Adjusted for tariff exemptions.
As can be seen from Table 11, Burundi, Comoros, Kenya, Mauritius, and Rwanda are
likely to face the most significant losses in fiscal revenue (over 6 percent of total revenue)
from the EPA. While these results are not unexpected for the other countries, it is surprising
that Rwanda is likely to face a significant loss in revenue from the EPA. Rwanda does not
appear very vulnerable if one examines the proportion of its imports from the EU and tfrom
its dependence on trade taxes (Tables 5 and 10). However, our analysis indicates that
Rwanda’s imports from the EU are concentrated in the tariff lines with the highest tariffs so
that removal of tariff barriers vis-à-vis the EU can lead to substantial revenue losses. One
shortcoming of our analysis is that since we lack information on exemptions, we assume that
they apply equally across all tariff lines.
- 33 -
Within SACU, we have been unable to separate the customs revenue because of lack
of data, but the loss of revenue will be an important concern for Lesotho, Namibia, and
Swaziland. In other countries also that we have been unable to examine because of lack of
data, there may be some revenue loss and alternative revenue sources will need to be
identified.
D. Other Challenges and Opportunities in EPA Implementation
Here we discuss additional opportunities, challenges, and concerns that are associated
with implementation of the EPAs. In terms of opportunities presented by EPAs—these
agreements can act as a mechanism to lock in trade reforms and gain credibility for
liberalization policies, and trade-related governance and institutions (Lawrence, 1997; and
Lewis and others, 2003). The negotiations envisage technical assistance in the area of
standards and liberalization of services, both of which are critical areas in Africa.
A major concern on the other hand, in EPAs is that they might impede or slow down
the process of liberalization in many African countries and create incentives against
multilateral reform. There are several reasons to view EPAs with suspicion in this regard.
First, given the high tariff barriers and dependence on trade taxes in a number of ESA and
SADC countries, and the EU’s stated desire to push for the formation of customs unions,
there is a distinct possibility that the agreed common external tariff will be high and increase
the average degree of protection in the more liberal countries in the region. Thus, not only
would past liberalization efforts be reversed but once the common external tariff is set, it
would not be possible for individual countries to pursue unilateral tariff reductions. Future
liberalization could thus be difficult and slow—not the least because of difficulties in
coordinating across many countries but also because of resistance from domestic entrenched
interests. Second, as with any other preferential arrangement, there is the concern that ACP
countries and/or the EU will have secured market access and will have incentives to oppose
and undermine future multilateral liberalization. The concern is magnified in this instance by
the size of the preferential arrangements being envisaged—with 77 ACP countries and the
EU participating, these account for around half of the total WTO membership. Interests in the
ACP countries that would have preferential market access to the EU might oppose future
multilateral liberalization, including in agricultural trade. Moreover, with the EU obtaining
preferential market access in a large number of developing countries, they might have little
incentive to push for further MFN liberalization in these countries.
On balance, it is not clear if EPAs will be welfare-enhancing or not. In large part, this
will be determined by the actual scope of the liberalization commitments undertaken and
their implementation. Therefore, in order to maximize benefits and minimize concerns, it is
critical that the EPAs result in the adoption of a low and uniform common external tariff. The
agreements should also aim for comprehensive product coverage in both goods and services
and appropriate sequencing, including in trade and tax policies. In both goods and services,
multilateral liberalization should be pursued concomitantly with preferential liberalization.
There is also a need to ensure that rationalization of membership does indeed take place and
these agreements are not a force for further fragmentation in the RTAs.
- 34 -
VI. C
ONCLUSION
Regional integration has gained momentum in recent years in eastern and southern
Africa, driven in part by global trends and in part by the negotiation of the Economic
Partnership Agreements with the EU. This paper examines prospects and challenges facing
two prominent regional arrangements in eastern and southern Africa, COMESA and SADC,
with regard to their role in promoting trade.
Analyzing the features of the agreements in detail, this paper finds that the COMESA
FTA has taken a market-liberalization approach to regional integration but has been
hampered by country-level implementation issues. On the other hand, SADC has taken the
approach of addressing infrastructure and supply constraints but has also had implementation
problems. Restrictive rules of origin are also a concern in SADC. The problems faced in
either arrangement point to a lack of political will and commitment. Going forward, both
COMESA and SADC have plans to form customs unions, although the plans of COMESA
are more advanced. It will be important to ensure that the customs unions are implemented in
a way that furthers the goals of liberalization.
This paper’s empirical analysis confirms the results of other studies that suggest
prospects for expansion of intraregional trade might be limited—it bases its inference on low
levels of intraregional trade and product complementarities. It has been previously
documented that exports of eastern and southern African countries are concentrated in a few
primary commodities. In this regard, our estimates confirm existing results indicating that the
relatively developed economies of South Africa, Egypt, and Kenya might not be able to
function effectively as markets for the products of other economies in SADC and COMESA.
Furthermore, there is a risk that investment might be attracted to the relatively more
developed economies resulting in polarization.
In this environment, benefits of COMESA/SADC are likely to flow from other
sources. They can be a useful avenue for harmonization and capacity building in various
trade-related areas (standards, customs procedures, other NTBs, etc.) and help to alleviate
infrastructure constraints through regional cooperation. In addition, they can provide policy
credibility to trade reforms through commitment to MFN liberalization, potentially
demonstrated by a low and uniform common external tariff.
There are several challenges in implementing a low and uniform common external
tariff. The most prominent of these relates to the dependence of a large number of countries
in the region on trade taxes as a source of revenue. In almost all of these countries, trade
taxes are over 10 percent of total revenue. Moreover, past experience indicates that it has
been difficult for low-income countries to replace lost tariff revenue with revenue from other
sources. Clearly, serious efforts will need to be made to broaden the tax base and develop
alternate sources of revenue. Another challenge relates to the wide disparities among the
trade regimes of member countries in COMESA and SADC, which will make it difficult for
them to harmonize and agree on a CET that is liberalizing and beneficial for all countries.
- 35 -
An interesting feature that comes out in our discussion is that the initial tariff
structures of the countries in the region are very different. Agreeing on a common external
tariff based on categorizing goods into raw materials, capital goods, intermediate goods and
finished goods (as in COMESA/EAC) will require substantial changes in the tariffs on
individual lines. This has also been an area of discord in the COMESA and EAC
negotiations. We point out that protracted negotiations have a cost in terms of delaying the
agreement and causing implementation problems down the road. In addition, they can
diminish the potential gains from policy credibility, since some countries may be perceived
as having protectionist intent. An additional result of our analysis is that the CET might result
in an apparent conflict with WTO bindings for some of the countries.
We also examine several issues regarding the EPA negotiations with ACP countries
in Africa. One of the upcoming challenges, once again, relates to the potential loss of fiscal
revenue since the EU is an important trading partner for the region. As discussed previously,
significant adjustment efforts will need to be made in order to compensate for the loss of
revenue. Another significant concern is the impact of the EPAs on the multilateral
liberalization efforts of individual African countries and on the multilateral trading system.
Given the emphasis on reinforcing RTAs and the push for the formation of customs unions, it
will be important to take the opportunity and implement a low and uniform CET—not doing
so will slow down future liberalization and has the potential to fragment the multilateral
trading system. The tendencies opposing multilateral liberalization are likely to be
aggravated with the creation of vested interests that would like to preserve their special
market access privileges granted under the EPAs.
At this time, it is not clear whether the EPAs will prove beneficial for African
countries over the long term. The EPAs’ emphasis on reinforcing RTAs can be beneficial
because countries will be required to rationalize their overlapping memberships and because
it counteracts the formation of “hub-and-spoke” agreements. If EPAs succeed in
strengthening the commitment to nondiscriminatory trade liberalization and harmonization in
various areas, African countries can gain from more policy credibility and better-integrated
regional markets. Technical assistance provided in standards etc. will also be very welcome.
In conclusion, it should be emphasized that in the past regional integration has not
yielded results for Africa in terms of economic performance. Going forward, it is important
to heed the lessons and pursue nondiscriminatory liberalization concomitantly with regional
integration. Deep integration and open regionalism are considered desirable attributes for
RTAs; there is a need for political will and commitment to ensure that COMESA and SADC
can effectively pursue these objectives in the greater interest of promoting trade. They must
meet several challenges to achieve these goals, but the cost to them of not pursuing reforms
may ultimately be greater.
- 36 - ANNEX I
Annex I. Features of SADC and COMESA
SADC
The SADC FTA commenced operation in September 2001, with participation from eleven of
the thirteen SADC member states.
26
Under the accord, participating countries agreed to phase
out tariffs on 85 percent of intra-SADC trade by 2008; sensitive products will be liberalized
by 2012. Sensitive industries comprise mainly textiles, clothing and motor vehicles. A small
number of sectors are explicitly excluded from liberalization.
Sugar is treated separately under the SADC trade protocol as it is viewed as a sensitive
industry in most member states. The agreement allows for nonreciprocal duty free market
access into SACU by non-SACU SADC members on a quota basis. The agreement envisages
the liberalization of the sugar market in accordance with the liberalization of the world sugar
market over the long term.
The agreement provides for asymmetry of treatment between members states at different
levels of development. The most developed member, South Africa, is to lower tariffs on
intraregional imports on the fastest schedule, while the LDC members, Malawi,
Mozambique, Tanzania, and Zambia are to do so on the slowest schedule.
The rules of origin (see Box 2) are product specific in response to levels of value addition
and complexity of processing and are restrictive in order to protect domestic SADC
industries (textiles and garments, sugar, wheat flour and food products using wheat flour,
coffee, tea and spices, mineral fuels, machinery, and electrical equipment, motor vehicles and
components, and certain products in Chapter 90). Work on the rules of origin is not yet
complete in a number of areas.
The trade protocol provides for trade facilitation and harmonization and cooperation with
regard to customs documents and procedures. In this regard, a single customs declaration
form has been adopted, and a SADC certificate of origin is also in place.
Antidumping and safeguard measures and protection for infant industries are allowed under
the agreement. The agreement provides for the settlement of disputes through diplomatic
consultation, failing which the matter could be referred to a panel of trade experts which
would be appointed by the council of ministers responsible for trade matters.
26
The thirteen member countries of SADC are: Angola, Botswana, Democratic Republic of Congo, Lesotho,
Malawi, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, South Africa, Swaziland, Tanzania, Zambia and Zimbabwe. Of
these, Angola and the Democratic Republic of Congo are not members of the FTA.
- 37 - ANNEX I
The protocol calls for elimination of NTBs—national authorities are cooperating with the
intention of harmonizing and developing common sub-regional standards and technical
regulations. No commitments have been made so far.
There are no clear institutional mechanisms for dispute settlement in SADC.
The protocol calls for the liberalization of services trade—this is a futuristic provision and
does not have much force at present.
The protocol calls for an industrialization strategy to improve the competitiveness of member
states.
Additional active areas of cooperation include the monetary and financial areas—training
and capacity building in central banks, development and harmonization of payments, clearing
and settlement systems, are some of initiatives.
SADC has announced plans for the establishment of a SADC customs union and
implementation of a common external tariff by 2010, a common market pact by 2012, and
establishment of a SADC central bank and preparation for a single SADC currency by 2016.
COMESA
The COMESA FTA was launched in October 2000, with participation from nine of the
nineteen member states.
27
Under the agreement, participating countries agreed to eliminate
all tariffs on intraregional trade. Rwanda and Burundi joined the FTA in January 2004. The
countries not yet part of the FTA have continued to trade on preferential terms.
28
No products are excluded from the FTA agreement. As in SADC, the agreement calls for
liberalization of services but this is mostly a futuristic provision.
The COMESA FTA has taken a variable speed and geometry approach by allowing
nonparticipants in the FTA to join when they are ready to reciprocate the terms of the
arrangement—it does not provide for asymmetry of treatment between LDC and developing
country members.
COMESA has fairly liberal rules of origin that are not product specific. Goods qualify for
preferential treatment if they undergo substantial transformation such that they contain a
27
The nine countries are Djibouti, Egypt, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Sudan, Zambia, and
Zimbabwe.
28
A PTA was launched in 1982. The FTA is the culmination of efforts made over the 1990s to reduce
intraregional barriers to trade.
- 38 - ANNEX I
minimum of 35 percent regional value-added, or include non-COMESA imported materials
worth no more than 60 percent of the value of total inputs used, or undergo a single change
of tariff heading. There is a list of “goods of economic importance” to member states,
according to which the domestic value added requirement is relaxed to 25 percent.
The COMESA agreement calls for the elimination of NTBs which are reported to the
Secretariat from time to time. They have been active in seeking their removal through
diplomatic channels and are in process of developing a formal mechanism for reporting and
resolving NTBs.
While the agreement allows for the creation of a COMESA Fund to provide member states
with budgetary assistance to minimize revenue shortfalls, in truth, this initiative is under-
funded and member countries will have to explore other means of adjusting.
The agreement allows safeguards in the form of exceptional temporary restrictions for
balance of payments reasons. These safeguards have been used in the past by Kenya to
protect sugar and wheat flour sectors from liberalization for a period of 4 years.
The treaty contains provision for the establishment of a Court of Justice to serve as a dispute
settlement mechanism. However, this is not yet operational and most disputes are solved
through diplomatic channels.
COMESA is trying to harmonize sanitary and phytosanitary standards using ISO standards as
a guide. A particular challenge is the issue of changing standards due to threats of
bioterrorism and the like.
A regional competition policy to address dumping, export subsidies and other trade distorting
support measures has been developed but not ratified.
COMESA has an active program on trade facilitation through harmonization and cooperation
in customs procedures and documentation. A draft Customs Management Act to govern
customs operations and procedures such as temporary admission, transit and re-exportation,
has been developed, as have a common tariff nomenclature and a single customs declaration
document. There is in place a “yellow card” uniform vehicle insurance scheme to facilitate
the movement of goods and people across the region. A customs bond guarantee scheme has
also been developed for the same purpose. The Secretariat has assisted member countries in
adopting newer versions of the Harmonized System, ASYCUDA, and the WTO valuation
system.
COMESA became a Common Investment Area in 1998—a draft of a Regional Investment
Framework Agreement is at an advanced stage. A gradual liberalization of the capital
account is being envisaged in the agreement with appropriate BOP safeguards. Here,
harmonization might be difficult since some countries have their own bilateral investment
treaties. the issue is whether they should only liberalize intraregional investment or all
- 39 - ANNEX I
investment? Another issue is whether liberalization and protection should extend to all new
investments or only to existing investments?
Additional areas of cooperation include the monetary and financial areas—development and
harmonization of payments, clearing and settlement systems, are some of initiatives.
COMESA is in the process of drafting a regional commercial policy to address issues of
harmonization in exemptions, free zones and other incentives or duty relief measures.
COMESA’s long term objectives include the establishment of a customs union by end-2004,
monetary union by 2025, harmonizing taxation and business legislation such as company
laws, intellectual property rights and investment and competition policies. Its more
immediate objectives include the establishment of a common market with the attendant free
movement of goods, capital and labor. In addition it is aiming for the liberalization of
services and harmonization of standards.
- 40 -
References
Alexandraki, K., and H. Lankes, 2004, “Estimating the Impact of Preference Erosion on
Middle-Income Countries,” IMF Working Paper 04/169 (Washington: International
Monetary Fund).
Aryeetey, E., 1997, “Sub-Saharan Experiences with Regional Integration,” in Trade Reform
and Regional Integration in Africa, ed. by Z. Iqbal and M. Khan, (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Baldwin, R., 2003, “Openness and Growth: What’s the Empirical Relationship,” NBER
Working Paper 9578 (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Baunsgaard, T., and M. Keen, forthcoming, “Tax Revenue and (or?) Trade Liberalization,”
IMF Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Chauvin, S., and G. Gaulier, 2002, “Regional Integration in Southern Africa,” CEPII
Working Paper 2002-12 (Paris: CEP).
COMESA Secretariat, 2003a, Negotiating Guidelines for ESA-EU Economic Partnership
Agreement with the EU (Lusaka), unpublished.
——, 2003b, Preparations for the COMESA Customs Union (Lusaka).
Ebrill, L., J. Stotsky, and R. Gropp, 1999, Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization, IMF
Occasional Paper No.180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
European Union, 2003, Draft Joint Report on the all ACP – EC phase of EPA negotiations,
Brussels, October, unpublished.
Flatters, F., 2002, “SADC Rules of Origin: Undermining Regional Free Trade,” TIPS Annual
Forum, available on the web at
http://qed.econ.queensu.ca/pub/faculty/flatters/main/writings.html.
Hinkle, L., and M. Schiff, 2004, “Economic Partnership Agreements between Sub-Saharan
Africa and the EU: A Development Perspective,” The World Economy, Vol. 27,
No. 9, pp. 1321–33, available on the web at http://ssrn.com/abstract=602672.
Iqbal, Z., and M. Khan, eds., 1997, Trade Reform and Regional Integration in Africa
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Jebuni, C., 1997, “Trade Liberalization and Regional Integration in Africa,” in Regional
Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa, Vol. 1, Framework,
Issues and Methodological Perspectives, ed. By A. Oyedjide, I. Elbadawi, and
P. Collier (New York: St. Martin’s Press).
- 41 -
Kritzinger-van Niekerk, L., and E. Moreira, 2002, “Regional Integration in Southern Africa:
Overview of Recent Developments,” World Bank Discussion Paper, (Washington:
World Bank).
Lawrence, R., 1997, “Preferential Trading Arrangements: The Traditional and the New,” in
Regional Partners in Global Markets: Limits and Possibilities of the Euro-Med
Agreements, ed. by A. Galal and B. Hoekman (London: CEPR/ECES).
Lewis, J., S. Robinson, and K. Thierfelder, 2003, “Free Trade Agreements and the SADC
Economies,” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 12, No. 2, pp. 156–206.
Mussa, M., 1997, “Trade Liberalization: The Road to Uruguay,” in Trade Reform and
Regional Integration in Africa, ed. by Z. Iqbal and M. Khan, (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Oyejide, A., 1997, “Trade Policy and Regional Integration in Sub-Saharan Africa,” in Trade
Reform and Regional Integration in Africa, ed. by Z. Iqbal and M. Khan,
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
———, I. Elbadawi and S. Yeo, 1999, Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in
Sub-Saharan Africa, Vol. 3, Regional Case Studies (London: Macmillan Press).
Nhara, N., 2003, “SADC User’s Guide: What is SADC? Towards Implementation of the
Trade Protocol,” Trade and Development Studies, Issue 23, available on the web at:
http://www.tradescentre.org.zw/publications/index.html.
SADC Secretariat, “Regional Indicative Strategic Development Plan,” available on the web
at http://www.sadc.int/index.php?action=a1001&page_id=risdp.
Schiff, M., and A. Winters, 2003, Regional Integration and Development (Washington:
World Bank).
Subramanian, A., E. Gelbard, R. Harmsen, K. Elborgh-Woytek, and P. Nagy, 2000, “Trade
and Trade Policies in Eastern and Southern Africa,” IMF Occasional Paper No.196
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Tsikata, Y., 1999, “Southern Africa: Trade, Liberalization and Implications for a Free Trade
Area,” TIPS Annual Forum, available on the web at http://www.acp-eu-
trade.org/documents/113_tsikata_tips.pdf.
Wacziarg, R., and K. Welch, 2003, “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence,”
Stanford University Graduate School of Business Research Paper No. 1826.
- 42 -
Warner, A., 2003, “Once More Into the Breach: Economic Growth and Integration,” Center
for Global Development Working Paper 34, Washington DC.
World Bank, 2004, Global Economic Prospects 2005: Trade, Regionalism and Development,
(Washington: World Bank).
World Trade Organization, 2000, “Trade Policy Review: Tanzania,” (Geneva).
——, 2003, “Trade Policy Review: Southern Africa Customs Union,” (Geneva).
Yeats, A., 1998, “What can be Expected from African Regional Trade Arrangements? Some
Empirical Evidence,” World Bank, available on the web at
http://www.worldbank.org/html/dec/Publications/Workpapers/wps2000series/
wps2004/wps2004-abstract.html