Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
July 5, 2024
Monetary Policy rePort
July 5, 2024
Letter of transmittaL
B  G  
F R S
Washington, D.C., July 5, 2024
T P   S
T S   H  R
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report pursuant to
section 2B of the Federal Reserve Act.
Sincerely,
Jerome H. Powell, Chair
statement on Longer-run goaLs and monetary PoLicy strategy
Adopted effective January24, 2012; as reafrmed effective January30, 2024
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) is rmly committed to fullling its statutory mandate from
the Congress of promoting maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. The
Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions to the public as clearly as possible. Such clarity
facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and nancial
uncertainty, increases the eectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability,
which are essential in a democratic society.
Employment, ination, and long-term interest rates uctuate over time in response to economic and nancial
disturbances. Monetary policy plays an important role in stabilizing the economy in response to these
disturbances. The Committee’s primary means of adjusting the stance of monetary policy is through changes
in the target range for the federal funds rate. The Committee judges that the level of the federal funds rate
consistent with maximum employment and price stability over the longer run has declined relative to its
historical average. Therefore, the federal funds rate is likely to be constrained by its eective lower bound
more frequently than in the past. Owing in part to the proximity of interest rates to the eective lower bound,
the Committee judges that downward risks to employment and ination have increased. The Committee is
prepared to use its full range of tools to achieve its maximum employment and price stability goals.
The maximum level of employment is a broad-based and inclusive goal that is not directly measurable
and changes over time owing largely to nonmonetary factors that aect the structure and dynamics of the
labor market. Consequently, it would not be appropriate to specify a xed goal for employment; rather, the
Committee’s policy decisions must be informed by assessments of the shortfalls of employment from its
maximum level, recognizing that such assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision. The
Committee considers a wide range of indicators in making these assessments.
The ination rate over the longer run is primarily determined by monetary policy, and hence the Committee
has the ability to specify a longer-run goal for ination. The Committee rearms its judgment that ination
at the rate of 2percent, as measured by the annual change in the price index for personal consumption
expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate. The
Committee judges that longer-term ination expectations that are well anchored at 2percent foster price
stability and moderate long-term interest rates and enhance the Committee’s ability to promote maximum
employment in the face of signicant economic disturbances. In order to anchor longer-term ination
expectations at this level, the Committee seeks to achieve ination that averages 2percent over time, and
therefore judges that, following periods when ination has been running persistently below 2percent,
appropriate monetary policy will likely aim to achieve ination moderately above 2percent for some time.
Monetary policy actions tend to inuence economic activity, employment, and prices with a lag. In setting
monetary policy, the Committee seeks over time to mitigate shortfalls of employment from the Committee’s
assessment of its maximum level and deviations of ination from its longer-run goal. Moreover, sustainably
achieving maximum employment and price stability depends on a stable nancial system. Therefore, the
Committee’s policy decisions reect its longer-run goals, its medium-term outlook, and its assessments of
the balance of risks, including risks to the nancial system that could impede the attainment of the
Committee’s goals.
The Committee’s employment and ination objectives are generally complementary. However, under
circumstances in which the Committee judges that the objectives are not complementary, it takes into account
the employment shortfalls and ination deviations and the potentially dierent time horizons over which
employment and ination are projected to return to levels judged consistent with its mandate.
The Committee intends to review these principles and to make adjustments as appropriate at its annual
organizational meeting each January, and to undertake roughly every 5years a thorough public review of its
monetary policy strategy, tools, and communication practices.
Summary .................................................................1
Recent Economic and Financial Developments ................................... 1
Monetary Policy ........................................................... 3
Special Topics ............................................................. 3
Part 1: Recent Economic and Financial Developments .....................5
Domestic Developments. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
Financial Developments .................................................... 30
International Developments ................................................. 36
Part 2: Monetary Policy ..................................................41
Part 3: Summary of Economic Projections ................................53
Abbreviations ............................................................71
contents
contents
Note: This report reects information that was publicly available as of noon EDT on July2, 2024.
Unless otherwise stated, the time series in the gures extend through, for daily data, June28, 2024; for monthly data,
May2024; and, for quarterly data, 2024:Q1. In bar charts, except as noted, the change for a given period is measured to
its nal quarter from the nal quarter of the preceding period.
For gures 26, 37, and 43, note that the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index, the S&P 500 Index, and the Dow Jones Bank Index are
products of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC and/or its afliates and have been licensed for use by the Board. Copyright © 2024 S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, a
division of S&P Global, and/or its afliates. All rights reserved. Redistribution, reproduction, and/or photocopying in whole or in part are prohibited without
written permission of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC. For more information on any of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC’s indices, please visit www.spdji.com.
S&P® is a registered trademark of Standard & Poor’s Financial Services LLC, and Dow Jones® is a registered trademark of Dow Jones Trademark Holdings
LLC. Neither S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates, nor their third-party licensors make any representation or
warranty, express or implied, as to the ability of any index to accurately represent the asset class or market sector that it purports to represent, and neither
S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC, Dow Jones Trademark Holdings LLC, their afliates, nor their third-party licensors shall have any liability for any errors, omis-
sions, or interruptions of any index or the data included therein.
List of Boxes
Housing Services Ination and Market Rent Measures .............................. 9
Employment and Earnings across Demographic Groups ............................ 16
Developments Related to Financial Stability ..................................... 33
Monetary Policy Independence, Transparency, and Accountability .................... 42
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and Money Markets .............. 47
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment ................................ 50
Forecast Uncertainty ....................................................... 68
1
Ination eased notably last year and has
shown modest further progress so far this
year, but it remains above the Federal Open
Market Committee’s (FOMC) objective of
2percent. Job gains have been strong, and the
unemployment rate is still low. Meanwhile, as
job vacancies continued to decline and labor
supply continued to increase, the labor market
moved into better balance over the rst half of
the year. Real gross domestic product (GDP)
growth was modest in the rst quarter, while
growth in private domestic demand remained
robust, supported by slower but still-solid
increases in consumer spending, moderate
growth in capital spending, and a sharp pickup
in residential investment.
The FOMC has maintained the target range
for the federal funds rate at 5¼ to 5½percent
since its July2023 meeting. In addition,
the Committee has continued to reduce its
holdings of Treasury securities and agency
mortgage-backed securities. The Committee
does not expect it will be appropriate to
reduce the target range until it has gained
greater condence that ination is moving
sustainably toward 2percent. Reducing policy
restraint too soon or too much could result in
a reversal of the progress on ination. At the
same time, reducing policy restraint too late
or too little could unduly weaken economic
activity and employment. In considering any
adjustments to the target range for the federal
funds rate, the Committee will carefully assess
incoming data, the evolving outlook, and the
balance of risks.
The FOMC is strongly committed to
returning ination to its 2percent objective.
The Committee remains highly attentive
to ination risks and is acutely aware that
high ination imposes signicant hardship,
especially on those least able to meet the higher
costs of essentials.
Recent Economic and Financial
Developments
Ination. Although personal consumption
expenditures (PCE) price ination slowed
notably last year and has shown modest
further progress this year, it remains above the
FOMC’s longer-run objective of 2percent.
The PCE price index rose 2.6percent over
the 12months ending in May, down from the
4.0percent pace over the preceding 12 months
and a peak of 7.1percent in June2022.
The core PCE price index—which excludes
food and energy prices and is generally
considered a better guide to the direction
of future ination—also rose 2.6percent in
the 12months ending in May, down from
4.7percent a year ago and slower than the
2.9percent pace at the end of last year. On a
12-month basis, core goods price ination and
housing services price ination continued to
ease over the rst part of the year, while core
nonhousing services price ination attened
out after slowing notably last year. Measures
of longer-term ination expectations are
within the range of values seen in the decade
before the pandemic and continue to be
broadly consistent with the FOMC’s longer-
run objective of 2percent.
The labor market. The labor market continued
to rebalance over the rst half of this year,
and it remained strong. Job gains were solid,
averaging 248,000 per month over the rst ve
months of the year, and the unemployment
rate remained low. Labor demand has eased, as
job openings have declined in many sectors of
the economy, and labor supply has continued
to increase, supported by a strong pace of
immigration. With cooling labor demand and
rising labor supply, the unemployment rate
edged up to 4.0percent in May. The balance
between labor demand and supply appears
similar to that in the period immediately
summary
2 SUMMARY
before the pandemic, when the labor market
was relatively tight but not overheated.
Nominal wage growth continued to slow in
the rst part of the year but remains above a
pace consistent with 2percent ination over
the longer term, given prevailing trends in
productivity growth.
Economic activity. Real GDP growth is
reported to have moderated in the rst
quarter after having increased at a robust
pace in the second half of last year. Much
of the slowdown was due to sizable drags
in the volatile categories of net exports and
inventory investment; growth in private
domestic nal purchases—which includes
consumer spending, business xed investment,
and residential investment—also moved a
little lower in the rst quarter but remained
solid. Real consumption growth slowed in the
rst quarter from a strong pace in the second
half of last year, reecting a decline in goods
spending. Real business xed investment
grew at a moderate pace in the rst quarter
despite high interest rates, supported by strong
sales growth and improvements in business
sentiment and prot expectations. Activity in
the housing sector picked up sharply in the
rst quarter as a result of a jump in existing
home sales and rising construction of single-
family homes.
Financial conditions. Financial conditions
appear somewhat restrictive on balance.
Treasury yields and the market-implied
expected path of the federal funds rate have
moved up, on net, since the beginning of
the year, while broad equity prices have
increased. Credit remains generally available
to most households and businesses but at
elevated interest rates, which have weighed on
nancing activity. The pace of bank lending
to households and businesses increased in the
rst ve months of the year but continues
to be somewhat tepid. Delinquency rates on
small business loans stayed slightly above
pre-pandemic levels, and delinquency rates for
credit cards, auto loans, and commercial real
estate loans continued to increase in the rst
quarter of 2024 to levels above their longer-
run averages.
Financial stability. The nancial system
remains sound and resilient. The balance
sheets of nonnancial businesses and
households stayed strong, with the combined
credit-to-GDP ratio standing near its two-
decade low. Business debt continued to decline
in real terms, and debt-servicing capacity
remained solid for most public rms, in
large part due to strong earnings, large cash
buers, and low borrowing costs on existing
debt. However, there were also signs of
vulnerabilities building in the nancial system.
In asset markets, corporate bond spreads
narrowed, equity prices rose faster than
expected earnings, and residential property
prices remained high relative to market rents.
Moreover, in the banking sector, some banks’
fair value losses on xed-rate assets remained
sizable, despite most of them continuing to
report solid capital levels. Additionally, parts
of banks’ commercial real estate portfolios
are facing stress. Some banks’ reliance on
uninsured deposits remained high. Even so,
liquidity at most domestic banks remained
ample, with limited reliance on short-term
wholesale funding. Bond mutual funds’
exposure to interest rate risk stayed elevated,
and data through the third quarter of 2023
show that hedge fund leverage had grown to
historical highs, driven primarily by borrowing
by the largest hedge funds. (See the box
“Developments Related to Financial Stability”
in Part 1.)
International developments. Foreign economic
activity appears to have improved in the rst
quarter after a soft patch in the second half
of last year. In advanced foreign economies,
growth rates returned to moderate levels
despite the eects of restrictive monetary
policy as lower ination improved real
household incomes. In emerging market
economies, growth was supported by a
recovery in exports and rising global demand
for high-tech products, with the rise in activity
in China in the rst quarter being particularly
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 3
outsized. Nonetheless, other factors continued
to weigh on economic growth: Data indicated
ongoing weakness in China’s property sector,
and in Europe, energy-intensive sectors
continue to struggle, reecting their ongoing
adjustment to past increases in energy prices
following Russia’s 2022 invasion of Ukraine.
Foreign headline ination has continued to
decline since the middle of last year, but the
pace of disination has been gradual and
uneven across countries and economic sectors.
Still, many foreign central banks have noted
this progress in lowering ination, and some
have begun to cut their policy rates. A notable
exception is Japan, which ended its negative
interest rate policy and yield curve control in
March amid persistently high ination. The
trade-weighted exchange value of the dollar
rose signicantly, consistent with widening
gaps between U.S. and foreign interest rates.
Monetary Policy
Interest rate policy. The FOMC has
maintained the target range for the policy
rate at 5¼ to 5½percent since its July2023
meeting. The Committee judges that the risks
to achieving its employment and ination
goals have moved toward better balance
over the past year. The Committee perceives
the economic outlook to be uncertain
and remains highly attentive to ination
risks. The Committee has indicated that
it does not expect it will be appropriate to
reduce the target range until it has gained
greater condence that ination is moving
sustainably toward 2percent. Policy is
well positioned todeal with the risks and
uncertainties the Committee faces in pursuing
both sides of its dual mandate. In considering
any adjustments to the target range for
the federal funds rate, the Committee will
carefully assess incoming data, the evolving
outlook, and the balance of risks.
Balance sheet policy. The Federal Reserve
has continued the process of signicantly
reducing its holdings of Treasury and agency
securities in a predictable manner.
1
Beginning
in June2022, principal payments from
securities held in the System Open Market
Account have been reinvested only to the
extent that they exceeded monthly caps. Under
this policy, the Federal Reserve has reduced
its securities holdings about $1.7trillion since
the start of balance sheet reduction. The
FOMC has stated that it intends to maintain
securities holdings at amounts consistent with
implementing monetary policy eciently and
eectively in its ample-reserves regime. To
ensure a smooth transition from abundant to
ample reserve balances, the FOMC slowed
the pace of decline of its securities holdings
at the beginning of June and intends to
stop reductions when reserve balances are
somewhat above the level that the Committee
judges to be consistent with ample reserves.
Special Topics
Housing services ination. The PCE price
index for housing services started accelerating
in 2021, notably increasing its contribution
to core PCE ination. Because this index
calculates average rent for all tenants—both
new tenants and existing tenants—its changes
tend to lag changes in market rent measures
for new leases. Therefore, measures of market
rent growth for new leases can help predict
future changes in the PCE price index. Since
mid-2022, market rents have decelerated
and returned to a growth rate similar to or
below their average pre-pandemic pace, while
the PCE index continues to show elevated
ination, reecting the gradual pass-through
of market rates to existing tenants. As this
process continues, PCE housing services
ination should gradually decline, though
much uncertainty remains about the extent
1. See the May4, 2022, press release regarding the
Plans for Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet, available on the Board’s website at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20220504b.htm.
4 SUMMARY
and timing. (See the box “Housing Services
Ination and Market Rent Measures
in Part 1.)
Employment and earnings across groups. A
strong labor market over the past two years
has been especially benecial for historically
disadvantaged groups of workers. As a
result, many of the long-standing disparities
in employment and wages by sex, race,
ethnicity, and education have narrowed, and
some gaps reached historical lows in 2023
and the rst half of 2024. However, despite
this narrowing, signicant disparities in
absolute levels across groups remain. (See
the box “Employment and Earnings across
Demographic Groups in Part 1.)
Monetary policy independence, transparency,
and accountability. Congress has established
a statutory framework that species the
long-run objectives of monetary policy—
maximum employment and stable prices—
and gives the Federal Reserve operational
independence in conducting monetary policy.
In this framework, the Federal Reserve
makes determinations about the monetary
policy actions that are most appropriate
for achieving the dual-mandate goals that
Congress has assigned to it. The Federal
Reserve recognizes that independence is
a trust given to it by Congress and the
American people and that with independence
comes the need to be transparent about,
and accountable for, its monetary policy
decisions. Transparency also improves
monetary policy’s eectiveness. The Federal
Reserve promotes transparency by providing
information about FOMC decisions through
policy communications and a variety of
publications. The means by which the Federal
Reserve informs the American people
about its monetary policy decisions include
ocial FOMC statements, monetary policy
reports, and Committee meeting minutes
and transcripts, as well as speeches, press
conferences, and congressional testimony
given by Federal Reserve ocials. (See
the box “Monetary Policy Independence,
Transparency, and Accountability in Part 2.)
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and money
markets. The size of the Federal Reserve’s
balance sheet has continued to decrease
since February as the FOMC has reduced
its securities holdings. Reserve balances, the
largest liability on the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet, and usage of the overnight reverse
repurchase agreement facility—another Federal
Reserve liability—both declined. (See the
box “Developments in the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet and Money Markets in Part2.)
Monetary policy rules. Simple monetary policy
rules, which prescribe a setting for the policy
interest rate in response to the behavior of
a small number of economic variables, can
provide useful guidance to policymakers. With
ination easing over the past year, the policy
rate prescriptions of most simple monetary
policy rules have decreased recently and now
call for levels of the federal funds rate that are
close to or below the current target range for
the federal funds rate. (See the box “Monetary
Policy Rules in the Current Environment”
inPart2.)
5
Domestic Developments
Ination eased notably last year and
has shown modest further progress in
recentmonths
Ination stepped down markedly last year
and has shown modest further progress so
far this year. Ination remains elevated,
though, and is still above the Federal Open
Market Committee’s (FOMC) longer-run
objective of 2percent. The price index for
personal consumption expenditures (PCE)
rose 2.6percent over the 12 months ending in
May, down from the 4.0percent pace a year
ago but little changed since the end of last year
(gure1). After having slowed markedly in the
second half of 2023, monthly core PCE price
ination—which excludes food and energy
prices and is generally considered a better
guide to the direction of future ination—
rmed in the rst quarter of this year and
then eased somewhat in April and May. As a
result, the 12-month change in core PCE prices
declined from the 4.7percent pace in May
of last year to 2.9percent in December and
moved down further this year, to 2.6percent
in May (gure2). A similar message is
evident from the trimmed mean measure
of PCE prices constructed by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, which provides an
alternative approach to reducing the inuence
of idiosyncratic price movements. The index
increased 2.8percent over the 12months
ending in May, a pace that is somewhat slower
than at the end of last year (as shown in
gure1).
Consumer energy prices have
increased, while food price ination has
attenedout
PCE energy prices increased 4.8percent in the
12 months ending in May after having declined
12.3percent over the preceding 12 months
Part 1
recent economic and financiaL deveLoPments
Total
Excluding food and energy
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Percent change from year earlier
20242023202220212020201920182017
1. Personal consumption expenditures price indexes
Monthly
SOURCE: For trimmed mean, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; for a
ll
else, Bureau of Economic Analysis; all via Haver Analytics.
Trimmed mean
6-month change
12-month change
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Percent, annual rate
20242023202220212020201920182017
2. Core personal consumption expenditures price index
Monthly
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, personal consumption
expenditures via Haver Analytics.
3-month change
6 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
(gure3, left panel). Oil prices increased, on
net, in the rst half of this year (gure4).
Prices rose amid concerns about escalation
of the conict in the Middle East, additional
costs of rerouting some oil shipping away
from the Red Sea, and ongoing production
cuts by OPEC (Organization of the Petroleum
Exporting Countries) and its allies. Continuing
geopolitical tensions, including tensions
emanating from the conicts in the Middle
East and Ukraine, pose an upside risk to
energy prices.
Prices of agricultural commodities and
livestock edged up, on net, over the rst half
of this year after having come down markedly
in 2022 and 2023 from the highs reached at the
start of Russia’s war on Ukraine in early 2022
(gure5). As a result of these movements, the
12-month change in PCE food prices slowed
substantially from its peak of 12.2percent in
August2022 to just 1.2percent in May (as
shown in gure3, left panel).
Prices of both energy and food products are
of particular importance for lower-income
households, for which such necessities account
for a large share of expenditures. Reecting the
sharp increases seen in 2021 and 2022, these
price indexes are 25percent and 32percent
higher than in 2019, for food and energy,
respectively.
Food and
beverages
Services
ex. energy
and housing
Goods ex. food, beverages, and energy
20
10
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
4
2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Percent change from year earlier
20242023202220212020201920182017
Food and energy
Percent change from year earlier
Energy
+
+
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent change from year earlier
20242023202220212020201920182017
Components of core prices
Monthly
Housing services
NOTE: The data are monthly.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
3. Subcomponents of personal consumption expenditures price indexes
Brent spot price
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
Dollars per barrel
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
4. Spot and futures prices for crude oil
Weekly
24-month-ahead
futures contracts
N
OTE
: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through
June 28, 2024.
S
OURCE
: ICE Brent Futures via Bloomberg.
Agriculture
and livestock
80
100
120
140
160
180
200
Week ending January 4, 2019 = 100
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
5. Spot prices for commodities
Weekly
Industrial metals
N
OTE
: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through
June 28, 2024.
S
OURCE
: For industrial metals, S&P GSCI Industrial Metals Spot
Index; for agriculture and livestock, S&P GSCI Agriculture & Livestock
Spot Index; both via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 7
4
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
Percent change from year earlier
202420222020201820162014
6. Nonfuel import price index
Monthly
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
Core goods prices increased modestly
this year after having declined sharply in
the second half of 2023
In assessing the outlook for ination, it is
helpful to consider three separate components
of core prices: core goods, housing services,
and core nonhousing services. After posting
notable declines in the second half of last
year, core goods prices increased modestly,
on net, over the rst months of this year. This
development likely reects, in part, movements
in nonfuel import prices, which turned up in
recent months after having declined, on net,
over 2023 (gure6). Smoothing through these
monthly movements, prices for core goods over
the 12 months ending in May moved down
1.1percent, similar to their pre-pandemic rate
of decline, after having increased 2.5percent
over the previous 12-month period (gure3,
right panel). The progress on ination for
core goods reects improvements in supply–
demand imbalances. Indeed, the supply chain
issues and other capacity constraints that had
earlier boosted ination so much continued
to ease, though at a more gradual pace this
year than over the past two years, and supply–
demand conditions in goods markets appear
to be relatively balanced. For example, the
shares of respondents to the Quarterly Survey
of Plant Capacity Utilization citing insucient
supply of labor or materials as reasons
for producing below capacity, which had
increased considerably during the pandemic,
have continued to fall and are now near pre-
pandemic levels (gure7).
Housing services price ination
continued to slow gradually but remains
elevated . . .
The 12-month change in housing services
prices moved down from more than 8percent
in May2023 to 5.5percent in May of this year
but is still well above its pre-pandemic level (as
shown in gure3, right panel). Market rent
ination, which measures increases in rents for
new housing leases to new tenants, has fallen
markedly since late 2022 to near pre-pandemic
rates, and this slowdown points to continued
easing of housing services ination over the
Insucient supply
of labor
0
10
20
30
40
50
Percent
202420232022202120202019
7. Reasons for operating below full capacity
Quarterly
Insucient supply
of materials
N
OTE: The series are the share of rms selecting each reason for
operating below full capacity.
S
OURCE: U.S. Census Bureau: Quarterly Survey of Plant Capacity
Utilization.
8 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
year ahead. (The box “Housing Services
Ination and Market Rent Measures” provides
further details.)
. . . while core nonhousing services price
ination attened out so far this year
Finally, price ination for core nonhousing
services—a broad group that includes services
such as travel and dining, nancial services,
and car repair—slowed last year but attened
out, on net, in the rst ve months of this
year. Core nonhousing services prices rose
3.4percent in the 12months ending in May,
down from 4.7percent a year ago but little
changed since the end of last year (as shown
in gure3, right panel). The lack of further
progress this year is due in large part to price
increases in volatile categories—for example,
portfolio management services, which can
be inuenced by idiosyncratic factors, such
as swings in the stock market, more than
supply and demand conditions. Because
labor is a signicant input to these service
sectors, the ongoing deceleration in labor
costs—supported by softening labor demand
and improvements in labor supply—suggests
that disination will eventually resume for
thiscategory.
Measures of longer-term ination
expectations have been stable; shorter-
term expectations have been volatile but
are generally lower than a year earlier
The generally held view among economists
and policymakers is that ination expectations
inuence actual ination by aecting wage-
and price-setting decisions. Survey-based
measures of expected ination over a longer
horizon have generally been moving sideways
over the past year, within the range seen during
the decade before the pandemic, and they
appear broadly consistent with the FOMC’s
longer-run 2percent ination objective. This
development is seen for surveys of households,
such as the University of Michigan Surveys
of Consumers, and for surveys of professional
forecasters (gure8). For example, the median
forecaster in the Survey of Professional
SPF, next 10 years
Michigan survey, next 5 to 10 years
SPF, 6 to 10 years ahead
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
Percent
20242022202020182016201420122010
8. Measures of ination expectations
N
OTE
: The data for the Michigan survey are monthly and extend
through June 2024. The Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) data
are quarterly and extend through 2024:Q2.
S
OURCE
: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, SPF.
Michigan survey, next 12 months
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 9
(continued on next page)
units, they are typically smaller for continuing tenants
renewing their lease than they are for new tenants.
3
This lag implies that measures of rent growth for
new leases can help predict future changes in the
PCE price index for housing services. Over the past
few decades, private  rms have started publishing
various “market rent” measures that track the average
rent for new leases by new tenants.
4
For example, the
3. See Ben Houck (2022), “Housing Leases in the
U.S. Rental Market,Spotlight on Statistics (Washington:
Bureau of Labor Statistics, September), https://www.bls.gov/
spotlight/2022/housing-leases-in-the-u-s-rental-market/
home.htm.
4. PCE prices for housing services differ from these market
rent measures for reasons beyond the fact that market rent
measures are limited to new leases to new tenants. In addition,
the discrepancy arises from the methodology used for index
construction (for example, the rent measures used in the PCE
price index sample a given residence only once every six
months), the representativeness of the sample, and the way in
which the measure controls for quality adjustments. Moreover,
market rent measures capture the “asking” prices posted by
landlords, while the rent measures used in the PCE price index
gauge the rent that tenants actually pay. Among these factors,
whether all leases are used (as opposed to only new leases)
appears to be the main contributor to this discrepancy. See
Brian Adams, Lara Loewenstein, Hugh Montag, and Randal
Verbrugge (2024), “Disentangling Rent Index Differences:
Data, Methods, and Scope,American Economic Review:
Insights, vol. 6 (June), pp. 230–45.
The price index for housing services includes rents
explicitly paid by renters as well as implicit rents that
homeowners would have to pay if they were renting
their homes known as owners’ equivalent rent (OER).
This index is an important component of the price
index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE),
composing about 15.5percent of the total PCE price
index. Housing services prices started accelerating
in 2021, and, as gure A illustrates, the contribution
of these prices to the 12-month change in the core
PCE price index increased notably, reaching a peak
of 1.4percentage points in 2023. In May2024, the
contribution of this component stood at 1.0percentage
point, down from its peak but still well above the
0.5percentage point that was typical before the
COVID-19 pandemic.
The PCE price index for housing services is derived
from two components of the consumer price index
(CPI): rent of primary residence and OER.
1
The rent of
primary residence index measures the average rent paid
by tenants. OER estimates the rent that homeowners
would pay if they were renting their homes without
furnishings or utilities and is derived from rental data
for units in the same neighborhood, with an adjustment
for structure type.
2
Because the price index for housing services
measures average rent for all tenants—both new
tenants and existing tenants—its changes are more
subdued and tend to lag changes in rent measures for
new leases, described later. Because rental agreements
typically last for 12months, most renters will not see an
immediate increase in their rent even if the rent for new
leases increases sharply. Additionally, the Bureau of
Labor Statistics, the agency responsible for computing
the CPI, reports that when rent increases occur for
1. The sum of the weights of these two components in the
total CPI is 34.4percent, considerably higher than their weight
in the total PCE price index.
2. The typical structure type varies signi cantly across
owner- and tenant-occupied units: Owner-occupied homes
are mostly single-family units, while renter-occupied homes
are roughly evenly divided between single-family and
multifamily units. Constructing the OER measure involves
reweighting the sample of rent quotes for a given area to
re ect the relative importance of owner-occupied housing in
that area. See slide13 of Robert Cage (2019), “Measurement
of Owner Occupied Housing in the U.S. Consumer Price
Index” (Washington: Bureau of Labor Statistics, November15),
https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2019-11/bea_tac_nov2019_
cage.pdf.
Housing Services In ation and Market Rent Measures
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percentage points
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
personal consumption expenditures price index
Monthly
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics;
Core goods
Core services ex. housing
Housing services
10 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Figure B illustrates that, historically, the year-over-
year change in market rents is an informative leading
indicator for the year-over-year change in PCE housing
multifamily apartment buildings. The Apartment List National
Rent Index, available beginning in 2017, measures changes in
median market rents across the entire rental market for both
single-family and multifamily units. To calculate unit-level rent
growth, all these measures, including the CoreLogic index,
use the repeat-rent methodology to control for differences
in property characteristics among the units listed for rent in
different periods.
CoreLogic Single-Family Rent Index measures changes
in average market rents for single-family homes.
Other measures include the Zillow, Apartment List,
and RealPage indexes, which vary in terms of the type
of unit they cover (single-family versus multifamily),
their methodologies, and the representativeness of the
national rental market.
5
5. The Zillow Observed Rent Index for single-family
residences, available beginning in 2015, focuses on changes
in asking rents for single-family units. The RealPage Rent
Index, available beginning in 1996, measures changes
in average market rents across professionally managed
Zillow single-family units
CoreLogic single-family detached units
RealPage multifamily units
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
12
15
18
21
Percent change from year earlier
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
B. Housing rents
Monthly
NOTE: CoreLogic data extend through April 2024, Zillow data start in January 2016, and Apartment List data start in January 2018 and e
xtend
through
June 2024. Zillow, CoreLogic, Apartment List, and RealPage measure market-rate rents—that is, rents for a new lease by a new tenant. PCE i
s
personal consumption expenditures.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, PCE, via Haver Analytics; CoreLogic, Inc.; Zillow, Inc.; Apartment List, Inc. via Haver Analytics; RealPage
,
Inc.; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
PCE housing services
Apartment List single-family and multifamily units
(continued)
Housing Services In ation (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 11
contracts typically last for a year and rents for existing
tenants take some time to catch up to the rents charged
to new tenants. In particular, the rise in measures of
market rents, including the CoreLogic Single-Family
Rent Index and the Zillow Observed Rent Index, from
the onset of the pandemic until now has been larger
than the corresponding increase in the PCE price
index for housing services, suggesting that the PCE
price measure has not yet fully caught up with the
current state of the rental market.
8
However, as long
as market rents continue to increase moderately, PCE
housing services in ation should gradually decline
and eventually return to its pre-pandemic pace as well.
However, signi cant uncertainty remains regarding the
timing of this decline and whether market rent in ation
will, in fact, remain moderate.
8. Between January2020 and April 2024, the CoreLogic
Single-Family Rent Index and the Zillow Observed Rent Index
have increased 32 percent and 38 percent, respectively, while
PCE prices for housing services have increased 23percent.
See Christopher D. Cotton (2024), “A Faster Convergence of
Shelter Prices and Market Rent: Implications for In ation,
Current Policy Perspectives 2024-4 (Boston: Federal Reserve
Bank of Boston, June), https://www.bostonfed.org/-/media/
Documents/Workingpapers/PDF/2024/cpp20240617.pdf.
services prices, with the market rent measure typically
leading the PCE measure by one year.
6
This relationship
is particularly evident in the periods following the
Great Recession and the COVID-19 pandemic. For
example, PCE housing services in ation reached a peak
of 8.3percent in April2023, exactly one year after the
12-month change for the CoreLogic index reached its
peak of 13.8percent.
Since mid-2022, each of these measures of market
rents has decelerated and returned to a growth rate
similar to or below its average pre-pandemic pace.
7
While the PCE price index for housing services also
began decelerating in mid-2023, its current rate of
increase remains well above the average rate seen
in the years before the pandemic. As noted earlier,
changes in the PCE price index for housing services
tend to lag changes in market rents because rental
6. Several studies use market rent measures to predict
housing services in ation. See, for instance, Marijn A. Bolhuis,
Judd N.L. Cramer, and Lawrence H. Summers (2022), “The
Coming Rise in Residential In ation,Review of Finance,
vol.26 (September), pp. 1051–72; and Kevin J. Lansing,
Luiz E. Oliveira, and Adam Hale Shapiro (2022), “Will Rising
Rents Push Up Future In ation?” FRBSF Economic Letter
2022-03 (San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of
SanFrancisco, February), https://www.frbsf.org/wp-content/
uploads/sites/4/el2022-03.pdf.
7. In addition, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has recently
started publishing a quarterly rent index for new tenants (the
New Tenant Rent Index). While the New Tenant Rent Index
is subject to revision with each release, the year-over-year
growth of this index declined from its peak of 12.9percent in
the second quarter of 2022 to 0.4percent in the  rst quarter
of 2024, the lowest reading since the second quarter of 2010.
See Bureau of Labor Statistics (n.d.), “New Tenant Rent Index,”
webpage, https://www.bls.gov/pir/new-tenant-rent.htm.
12 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Forecasters, conducted by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, continued to expect
PCE price ination to average 2percent over
the ve years beginning ve years fromnow.
Ination expectations over a shorter horizon—
which tend to follow observed ination more
closely and tend to be more volatile—have
moved down, on net, since the middle of
2022 to near the range seen during the decade
before the pandemic. In recent months, the
median value for ination expectations over
the next year as measured in theMichigan
survey has been generally lower than readings
from a year earlier. Similarly, expected
ination for the next year as measured in the
Survey of Consumer Expectations, conducted
by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, has
also declined, on average, from a year earlier.
Market-based measures of longer-term
ination compensation, which are based on
nancial instruments linked to ination such
as Treasury Ination-Protected Securities, are
also broadly in line with readings seen in the
years before the pandemic and consistent with
PCE ination returning to 2percent. These
measures have been little changed, on net,
since the beginning of the year (gure9).
The labor market remains strong
Payroll employment gains have been strong,
averaging 248,000 per month over the rst ve
months of the year. Job gains slowed from the
rst half to the second half of last year but
appear to have picked up, on net, so far this
year (gure10). Recent job gains have been
broad based, with over 60percent of industries
expanding their employment, on net, over the
three months ending in May. That said, gains
have been particularly strong in health care
and in state and local governments, where
employment remains below the levels implied
by pre-pandemic trends.
2
2. Administrative data from the Quarterly Census
of Employment and Wages (QCEW) suggest that job
growth last year was solid, but not as strong as reported
in the Current Employment Statistics (CES). The CES
5-year
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
Percent
202420232022202120202019201820172016
9. Ination compensation implied by Treasury
Ination-Protected Securities
Daily
5-to-10-year
N
OTE:The data are at a business-day frequency and are estimated
from smoothed nominal and ination-indexed Treasury yield curves.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board
sta calculations.
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
800
Thousands of jobs
2024202320222021
10. Nonfarm payroll employment
Monthly
N
OTE
: The data shown are a 3-month moving average of the change in
nonfarm payroll employment.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 13
The unemployment rate has edged up since the
middle of 2023 but was still at a historically
low level of 4.0percent in May. Through
May, the unemployment rate has remained
at or below 4percent for over two years
(gure11). Unemployment rates among most
age, educational attainment, sex, and ethnic
and racial groups remain near their respective
historical lows (gure12).
Labor demand has been gradually
cooling. . .
Demand for labor remained strong in the
rst half of 2024 but has continued to cool
gradually, on net, from its very elevated levels
of early 2022. Job openings, as measured in
the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), have continued to fall from their all-
time high recorded in March2022 but are
payroll data will be revised in early 2025, when the
Bureau of Labor Statistics benchmarks these data to
employment counts from the QCEW as part of its annual
benchmarking process.
Black or African American
Asian
Hispanic or Latino
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Percent
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
12. Unemployment rate, by race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
N
OTE
: Unemployment rate measures total unemployed as a percentage of the labor force. Persons whose ethnicity is identied as Hispanic or Latino
may
be of any race. Small sample sizes preclude reliable estimates for Native Americans and other groups for which monthly data are not reported b
y
the Bureau of Labor Statistics.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
Percent
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
11. Civilian unemployment rate
Monthly
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
14 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
still slightly above pre-pandemic levels.
3
An
alternative measure of job vacancies using job
postings data from the large online job board
Indeed also shows that while vacancies have
proceeded to move gradually lower through
the rst half of 2024, they have remained
above pre-pandemic levels.
4
Consistent with
the decline in job vacancies, the National
Federation of Independent Business (NFIB)
survey indicated that on net, in May, fewer
rms planned to add workers over the next
three months than was the case at the end of
2023; rms’ hiring plans reported in the NFIB
survey have been trending down since the
middle of 2021.
The cooling in labor demand has been
mostly due to reductions in rm hiring, as
indicators of layos, such as initial claims
for unemployment insurance and the rate of
layos and discharges in the JOLTS report,
have remained at historically low levels.
. . . and labor supply has increased
further . . .
Meanwhile, the supply of labor has continued
to increase on net. While labor force
participation has leveled o over the past year,
the U.S. population increased strongly because
of high levels of immigration.
The labor force participation rate (LFPR)—
which measures the share of people either
working or actively seeking work—increased
solidly from the beginning of 2021 through
the middle of 2023 but appears to have
3. Some analysts have noted that the vacancy-posting
behavior of rms may have changed since 2019 in ways
that lift the number of vacancies. For example, multi-
establishment rms may be posting vacancies for a
single job opening at several or all of its establishments
if the new job allows workers to work remotely from
any establishment. These multiple job postings may
result in overcounting of job vacancies in establishment-
level measures, such as those from JOLTS and Indeed.
Alternatively, after having experienced an exceptionally
strong labor market in 2022, rms may now be more
willing to post vacancies for positions that they are
unlikely to ll immediately.
4. Indeed job postings data are available on the
company’s Hiring Lab portal at https://data.indeed.com/
#/postings.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 15
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
Percent
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
13. Labor force participation rate
Monthly
NOTE:Data are monthly, and values before January 2024 are
estimated by Federal Reserve Board sta in order to eliminate
discontinuities in the published history.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
attened out at a relatively high level since
then. The LFPR was 62.5percent in May,
a touch below its average level over the past
12 months (gure13). Notably, the post-
pandemic recovery in the LFPR has diered
widely across demographic groups, with the
participation rate for women aged 25 to 54
reaching all-time highs in recent months and
the participation rate for individuals older
than 55 exhibiting no signs of recovery. (The
box “Employment and Earnings across
Demographic Groups” provides further
details.)
Labor supply has also been boosted in recent
years by relatively strong population growth
due to a notable expansion in immigration.
Though ocial estimates by the Census
Bureau show a robust increase in population
growth in 2022 and 2023, recent estimates
by the Congressional Budget Oce indicate
that actual population growth may have been
considerably higher. The most recent data
suggest that immigration is somewhat slower
than the strong rates seen late last year.
5
. . . resulting in a normalization of labor
market conditions
With cooling labor demand and rising labor
supply, the labor market became gradually less
tight over the rst half of this year, although
it nevertheless remains strong. The balance
between demand and supply in the labor
market appears similar to that during the
period immediately before the pandemic.
5. A recent report from the Congressional Budget
Oce (CBO) estimates that immigration in 2022 and
2023 was considerably higher than in the Census Bureau’s
estimates. See Congressional Budget Oce (2024), The
Demographic Outlook: 2024 to 2054 (Washington: CBO,
January), https://www.cbo.gov/publication/59697. Recent
studies have put more weight on the CBO estimates, in
part because the Census Bureau is using lagged estimates
of immigration from the American Community Survey,
while the CBO is using more recent, high-frequency data.
See Wendy Edelberg and Tara Watson (2024), “New
Immigration Estimates Help Make Sense of the Pace of
Employment, Hamilton Project (Washington: Brookings
Institution, March), https://www.brookings.edu/
wp-content/uploads/2024/03/20240307_Immigration
Employment_Paper.pdf.
16 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Among prime-age people (aged 25 to 54), the
employment-to-population (EPOP) ratio for Black or
African American workers remained near its historical
peak in the  rst half of 2024, and the gap in the EPOP
ratio between prime-age Black and white workers
fell to its lowest point in almost 50years. Similarly,
prime-age Hispanic or Latino workers’ EPOP ratio
has increased notably over the  rst part of 2024 and
is now more than 1percentage point above its 2019
level ( gure A, top-left panel). That improvement has
further reduced the EPOP ratio gap between Hispanic
or Latino workers and white workers from already
At the aggregate level, solid labor demand and
improved labor supply, together with ongoing gains
in productivity and falling in ation, have resulted in
high rates of employment and rising real wages over
the past year. This solid labor market performance has
been broadly shared and has been especially bene cial
for historically disadvantaged groups of workers.
As a result, many of the long-standing disparities in
employment and wages by sex, race, ethnicity, and
education have narrowed, and some gaps reached
historical lows in 2023 and the  rst half of 2024.
However, despite this narrowing, signi cant disparities
in absolute levels across groups remain.
Employment and Earnings across Demographic Groups
(continued)
Black or African American
Men, some college or more
Men, high school or lessAsian
Hispanic or Latino
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
Percentage points
202420232022202120202019
Race and ethnicity
Monthly
White
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
Percentage points
202420232022202120202019
Sex and educational attainment
Monthly
Women, some college or more
Women, high school or less
A. Prime-age employment-to-population ratios compared with the 2019 average ratio, by group
People without a disability
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
12
Percentage points
202420232022202120202019
Disability
Monthly
N
OTE
: Prime age is 25 to 54. All series are seasonally adjusted by the Federal Reserve Board sta.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
People with a disability
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 17
the average employment rate for this group.
4
For
persons without a disability, the EPOP ratio is little
changed from its 2019 level.
Although most groups have shown robust
employment gains over the past few years, the
EPOP ratio for people aged 55 or older remains
approximately 2percentage points below its 2019
level and has changed little since late 2021 ( gure B).
This shortfall is attributable to a persistent increase in
the rate of retirement among this group. Most of the
increase in retirement relative to 2019 is due to the
continued aging of the baby-boom generation, a trend
that was expected to have occurred even without the
pandemic.
5
However, retirements have also been
4. The increase in the number of persons with a disability
may be linked to cases of long COVID, which, while
debilitating, might not limit work as much as other types
of disabilities. As a result, an in ux of relatively higher-
employment individuals into the disabled category could have
raised employment rates for this group even if no individual’s
employment changed.
5. For example, as baby boomers have continued to age,
the median age of the population aged 55 or older increased
from 66 in 2019 to 67 in the  rst half of 2024, and the median
age of that group is expected to continue increasing into
the future. This shift in the composition of the 55-or-older
population has naturally lowered the observed EPOP ratio for
this group nearly 0.5percentage point per year, as EPOP ratios
are lower at older ages.
historically low levels. Although the EPOP ratio for
prime-age Asian workers has moved somewhat lower
over the past year, it remains historically high and
above its 2019 level.
1
The EPOP ratio for prime-age women has continued
to increase steadily, reaching another record high in the
rst few months of 2024, whereas the EPOP ratio for
prime-age men has been mostly  at over the past year,
near its level in the year before the pandemic ( gureA,
top-right panel). As a result, the EPOP ratio gap
between prime-age men and women fell to a record
low this year. The increase in the female EPOP ratio
relative to the pre-pandemic period is (almost) entirely
attributable to rising labor force participation, which
had also been increasing briskly before the pandemic,
consistent with a growing share of women with a
college degree.
2
Other factors, including strong labor
market conditions and greater availability of remote-
work options, may have also contributed to rising
prime-age female labor force participation.
3
Among prime-age persons with a disability, the
EPOP ratio has surged well above its 2019 level during
the past few years ( gure A, bottom panel). Some of
this increase is likely due to the unique labor market
circumstances of the past few years. With tight labor
market conditions, employers may have been relatively
more likely to hire persons with a disability than in
other times. Additionally, the rise of remote work may
have enabled persons with a disability to work without
the challenges of on-site work. However, some of the
increase could stem from a change in the composition
of this group, as the number of persons with a disability
rose following the pandemic, which may have raised
1. As monthly series have greater sampling variability
for smaller groups, we do not plot EPOP ratio estimates for
American Indians or Alaska Natives.
2. For a discussion of the contribution of educational
attainment to prime-age female labor force participation
before the pandemic, see Didem Tüzemen and Thao Tran
(2019), “The Uneven Recovery in Prime-Age Labor Force
Participation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,Economic
Review, vol. 104 (Third Quarter), pp. 21–41, https://www.
kansascityfed.org/Economic%20Review/documents/652/2019-
The%20Uneven%20Recovery%20in%20Prime-Age%20
Labor%20Force%20Participation.pdf.
3. For a discussion on access to remote work and
participation rates, see Maria D. Tito (2024), “Does the
Ability to Work Remotely Alter Labor Force Attachment?
An Analysis of Female Labor Force Participation,” FEDS
Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, January19), https://doi.org/10.17016/2380-
7172.3433.
(continued on next page)
Ages 16 to 24
Ages 55+
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
Percentage points
202420232022202120202019
B. Employment-to-population ratios relative to 2019
average, by age
Monthly
Ages 25 to 54
NOTE:Data before January 2023 are estimated by Federal R
eserve
Board sta in order to eliminate discontinuities in the published history.
S
OURCE:Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Census Bureau, Curren
t
Population Survey; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
18 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
C. Median real wage growth, by group
4th quartile
White
1st quartile3rd quartile
3
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Wage quartiles
Monthly
2nd quartile
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Race
Monthly
Nonwhite
Men
High school or less
Bachelor’s degree or more
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Sex
Monthly
N
OTE
: The data extend through March 2024. Series show 12-month moving averages of the median percent change in the hourly wage of individuals
observed 12 months apart, deated by the 12-month moving average of the 12-month percent change in the personal consumption expenditures price
index. In the top-left panel, workers are assigned to wage quartiles based on the average of their wage reports in both Current Population Survey
outgoing rotation group interviews; workers in the lowest 25 percent of the average wage distribution are assigned to the 1st quartile, and those in the
top 25 percent are assigned to the 4th quartile.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Wage Growth Tracker; Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey.
Women
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Educational attainment
Monthly
Associate’s degree
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s Wage Growth
Tracker and de ated by the personal consumption
expenditures price index—was consistently stronger for
workers in lower wage quartiles compared with the top
quartiles during the pandemic and early recovery, but
now all quartiles are experiencing similar growth.
7
Strong wage growth across the income distribution
is re ected in the experiences of different demographic
groups. Wage growth for nonwhite workers has been a
bit stronger than that for white workers for much of the
past year ( gure C, top-right panel). Wages for women
and men have grown essentially in tandem over the
past year ( gure C, bottom-left panel).
8
Real wage
growth for workers with a high school diploma or less
remains strong and has been rising a bit faster than for
workers with more education, on average, over the past
few years ( gure C, bottom-right panel).
7. To reduce noise due to sampling variation, which can
be pronounced when considering disaggregated groups’
wage changes, the series shown in  gure C are the 12-month
moving averages of the groups’ median 12-month real wage
changes. Thus, by construction, these series lag the actual real
wage changes. Wage data extend through March2024 only to
avoid complications stemming from changes in the underlying
data source.
8. The measure of real wage growth shown in the  gure
uses the same price index for all groups, but in ation
experiences can differ across demographic groups because
of differences in what they purchase or where they shop.
See Jacob Orchard (2021), “Cyclical Demand Shifts and
Cost of Living Inequality,” working paper, February (revised
September2022).
elevated above the level expected from aging alone,
mostly for individuals aged 65 or older.
6
While employment disparities across many
demographic groups are now within historically narrow
ranges, substantial gender, racial, and ethnic gaps
remain, underscoring long-standing structural factors.
Currently, prime-age women are employed at a rate
10 percentage points less than men, while prime-age
Black and Hispanic workers are employed at a rate
3to4percentage points less than white workers.
Similar to employment, a continued strong labor
market has supported strong nominal wage growth, and
as in ation has come down, that strong nominal wage
growth has translated into higher real wage growth.
Real wage growth has been comparatively robust for
historically disadvantaged groups. As shown in the top-
left panel of  gure C, real wage growth—as measured
6. For an analysis on the increase in retirements following
the pandemic, see Joshua Montes, Christopher Smith, and
Juliana Dajon (2022), “ ‘The Great Retirement Boom’: The
Pandemic-Era Surge in Retirements and Implications for Future
Labor Force Participation,” Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2022-081 (Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, November), https://doi.org/10.17016/
FEDS.2022.081.
(continued)
Employment and Earnings (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 19
C. Median real wage growth, by group
4th quartile
White
1st quartile3rd quartile
3
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Wage quartiles
Monthly
2nd quartile
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Race
Monthly
Nonwhite
Men
High school or less
Bachelor’s degree or more
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Sex
Monthly
N
OTE
: The data extend through March 2024. Series show 12-month moving averages of the median percent change in the hourly wage of individual
s
observed
12 months apart, deated by the 12-month moving average of the 12-month percent change in the personal consumption expenditures p
rice
index.
In the top-left panel, workers are assigned to wage quartiles based on the average of their wage reports in both Current Population Surve
y
outgoing
rotation group interviews; workers in the lowest 25 percent of the average wage distribution are assigned to the 1st quartile, and those in
the
top 25 percent are assigned to the 4th quartile.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Wage Growth Tracker; Bureau of Labor Statistics; U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey.
Women
2
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
Percent
202420232022202120202019
Educational attainment
Monthly
Associate’s degree
20 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
A variety of labor market indicators support
this assessment. The ratio of job openings
to unemployment has fallen notably from its
peak of about 2.0 in spring 2022 to 1.2 in May,
the same as its average in 2019. Similarly, the
gap between the number of total available
jobs (measured by employed workers plus job
openings) and the number of available workers
(measured by the size of the labor force) has
also moved down markedly from its peak of
6.1million in spring 2022 to 1.4million in
May and is only a bit above its 2019 average of
1.2million (gure14). The unemployment rate
has continued to edge up this year and reached
4.0percent in May, modestly higher than in
2019. In addition, the percentage of workers
quitting their jobs each month, an indicator
of the availability of attractive job prospects,
has continued to move down this year and,
though still elevated, is now modestly below
its pre-pandemic level. Similarly, the share
of respondents to the Conference Board
Consumer Condence Survey reporting that
jobs are plentiful has continued to move down
and is somewhat lower than its level in 2019.
Furthermore, the NFIB survey indicates that
rms’ perceptions of labor market tightness
have come down from their recent peaks and
returned to their pre-pandemic range. Finally,
business contacts surveyed for the Federal
Reserve’s May2024 Beige Book reported signs
of a cooling labor market—including easing
in hiring plans, better labor availability, and
modest wage growth—and, similar to 2019,
cited some diculty nding workers in selected
industries or areas.
6
Wage growth remains elevated but
hasslowed
Consistent with the easing in labor market
tightness, nominal wage growth continued to
slow so far this year, though it remains above
its pre-pandemic pace and likely too high,
given productivity trends, to be consistent with
2percent ination over time (gure15). Total
hourly compensation, as measured by the
6. See the May2024 Beige Book, available on the
Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/beigebook202405.htm.
Available workers
135
140
145
150
155
160
165
170
175
Millions
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
14. Available jobs versus available workers
Monthly
N
OTE
: Available jobs are employment plus job openings as of the end
of the previous month. Available workers are the labor force. Data for
employment and labor force before January 2024 are estimated by
Federal Reserve Board sta in order to eliminate discontinuities in the
published history.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics; U.S. Census
Bureau; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
Available jobs
Average hourly earnings, private sector
Employment cost index, private sector
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
Percent change from year earlier
202420232022202120202019201820172016
15. Measures of change in hourly compensation
N
OTE
: For the private-sector employment cost index, change is over
Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker
the 12 months ending in the last month of each quarter; for private-
sector average hourly earnings, the data are 12-month percent changes;
for the Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker, the data are shown as a
3-month moving average of the 12-month percent change and
extend
through March 2024.
S: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
Wage Growth Tracker; all via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 21
employment cost index, increased 4.1percent
over the 12months ending in March, a
noticeable slowing from the peak increase
of 5.5percent in mid-2022. Other aggregate
measures of labor compensation, such as
average hourly earnings (a less comprehensive
measure of compensation) and the Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s Wage Growth
Tracker (which reports the median 12-month
wage growth of individuals responding to
the Current Population Survey), have also
continued to slow from their recent peaks in
2022 but remain well above their pre-pandemic
growth rates. Wage growth has not normalized
to the same extent as the measures of labor
market tightness cited earlier, suggesting that
there is some persistence in the adjustment
process to past shocks. With PCE prices
having risen 2.6percent over the 12 months
through May, these nominal wage measures
suggest that most workers saw increases in
the purchasing power of their wages over the
pastyear.
Labor productivity has increased at a
moderate pace with signicant volatility
The extent to which nominal wage gains raise
rms’ costs and act as a source of ination
pressure depends importantly on the pace of
productivity growth. Labor productivity in the
business sector—the ratio of output to hours
worked—has been extremely volatile since the
pandemic began. It increased sharply in 2020,
moved roughly sideways in 2021, declined
strongly in 2022, and then rebounded solidly
in 2023 (gure16). Averaging through these
large swings, business-sector productivity has
increased at a moderate annual average rate of
1½percent since the onset of the pandemic, in
line with the average rate of growth observed
during the previous business cycle (from the
fourth quarter of 2007 to the fourth quarter
of2019).
The pace of future productivity growth
is highly uncertain. It is possible that
productivity growth could remain at around
its current moderate pace. However, it is
also possible that the rapid adoption of new
technologies like articial intelligence (AI)
94
96
98
100
102
104
106
108
110
112
2017 average = 100
202420222020201820162014
16. U.S. labor productivity
Quarterly
NOTE:The data are output per hour in the business sector.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
22 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
and robotics, as well as the high rate of new
business formation brought about by the
pandemic, could boost productivity growth
above that pace in coming years.
Growth in gross domestic product
moderated in the rst quarter, but private
domestic demand remained solid
After expanding at a robust pace in the second
half of last year despite restrictive nancial
conditions, real gross domestic product (GDP)
decelerated to a moderate annual growth
rate of 1.4percent in the rst quarter of this
year (gure17). The step-down was due in
large part to sizable drags from net exports
and inventory investment; these categories
of expenditures tend to be volatile even in
normal times and have been even more so since
the pandemic. Growth in private domestic
nal purchases—that is, consumer spending,
business xed investment, and residential
investment—also moderated in the rst quarter
but remained solid.
7
Among these components
of GDP, consumer spending rose strongly in
the second half of last year and decelerated in
the rst quarter as goods spending declined
while services spending continued to rise
solidly. Business xed investment increased at
a moderate pace in the rst quarter as a result
of strength in nontransportation equipment
spending and intellectual property investment,
while nonresidential structures slowed after
surging in 2023. Residential investment grew
rapidly in the rst quarter, reecting, for the
most part, increases in existing home sales and
construction of single-family homes.
7. Real gross domestic income (GDI) has been
notably weaker than GDP in recent years; both series
measure the same economic concept, and any dierence
between the two gures reects measurement error in
one or both series. GDI is reported to have increased
at a pace only slightly slower than GDP in the rst
quarter but had risen notably less than GDP over the
previous three years. As a result, productivity calculated
from the income side of the national accounts would be
considerably weaker than the published gures over the
past three years.
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent, annual rate
202420232022202120202019201820172016
17. Change in real gross domestic product and gross
domestic income
Q1
H1
H2
NOTE: The key identies bars in order from left to right.
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 23
After having returned to pre-pandemic levels
in late 2021, manufacturing output has been
little changed, on net, since then. While motor
vehicle production has continued to rebound
from earlier disruptions, factory production
outside of motor vehicles has drifted down
somewhat. The diusion indexes of new orders
from various national and regional surveys of
manufacturers remained mostly soft in June,
suggesting continued modest weakness in
coming months.
Consumer spending growth has been
resilient but eased this year
Consumer spending adjusted for ination grew
at a solid rate of 2.7percent in 2023 but slowed
in the rst quarter to a moderate 1.5 percent
pace (gure18). The resilience in consumer
spending last year in the face of high interest
rates likely reected strong job gains and rising
real wages. Indeed, real disposable personal
income increased at a robust 3.8percent rate
in 2023. In addition, last year’s spending was
bolstered by households drawing down their
liquid assets, such as checking accounts, and
relying more on credit.
More recently, the easing in consumer
spending growth in the rst quarter was
accompanied by a softening in some
household spending fundamentals along with
somewhat restrictive nancial conditions.
Disposable personal income growth moderated
in the rst quarter after a robust pace last
year. While household nances appear
healthy in the aggregate, credit card and
auto loan delinquencies continued to rise in
the rst quarter, suggesting that a growing
share of households are experiencing some
nancialstress.
Despite the recent easing in consumer
spending growth, households continue to
spend more of their income than is typical.
The saving rate—the dierence between
current income and spending, as a share of
income—was 3.8percent in the rst quarter
and has been well below its pre-pandemic
average of over 6percent for nine consecutive
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Percent, annual rate
202420232022202120202019201820172016
18. Change in real personal consumption expenditures
H1
H2
Q1
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
24 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
quarters (gure19). This low saving rate likely
reects in large part the eects of high wealth
and still-strong balance sheets of higher-
incomehouseholds.
Consumer spending since the pandemic has
been more robust than measures of consumer
sentiment would suggest. The indexes of
consumer sentiment published by both the
University of Michigan and the Conference
Board remain well below their pre-pandemic
levels. Although the Michigan survey index
has improved markedly since spring 2022, it
is further below its pre-pandemic level than
the Conference Board index, which puts more
weight on labor market conditions (gure20).
Consumer nancing conditions remain
somewhat restrictive
Consumer nancing conditions have been
somewhat restrictive, reecting high borrowing
costs and tight bank lending standards. Interest
rates for consumer credit products such as
new credit cards and auto loans edged down
in recent months but remained elevated. In the
April Senior Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices (SLOOS), conducted
by the Federal Reserve Board, banks reported
continued tightening of lending standards
for consumer loans in the rst quarter, likely
reecting increases in delinquency rates.
Indeed, credit card and auto loan delinquency
rates—measured as the fraction of balances
that are at least 30 days past due—have
increased from their 2021 lows and are above
the levels observed just before the pandemic.
Even so, nancing has been generally available
to support consumer spending. Consumer
credit expanded moderately, on net, during
the rst four months of the year, driven by
still-solid growth in credit card balances and
modest growth in auto loans and student loans
(gure21).
Michigan survey
50
60
70
80
90
100
110
February 1966 = 100
25
45
65
85
105
125
145
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
1985 average = 100
20. Indexes of consumer sentiment
Conference Board
N
OTE
: The data are monthly and extend through June 2024.
S
OURCE
: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; Conference
Board.
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
Billions of dollars, monthly rate
2024202220202018201620142012
21. Consumer credit ows
Q1
Apr.
NOTE: Credit card balances were little changed in 2011 and 2012.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release G.19,
Consumer
Credit.”
Student loans
Auto loans
Credit cards
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
PercentMonthly
202420222020201820162014
19. Personal saving rate
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 25
Residential investment turned around and
has increased since mid-2023
After rising sharply between early 2022 and
late 2023, mortgage interest rates have fallen
back some since last fall but, at around
7percent, remain well above their pre-
pandemic peak in 2018 (gure22). Following
the sharp rise in mortgage rates, residential
investment declined steeply in 2022 and fell
further in the rst half of last year but has
picked up since mid-2023. Solid income
growth and the declines in interest rates late
last year have provided support for residential
investment demand so far this year. Indeed,
residential investment rose sharply in the
rstquarter.
Sales of existing homes have moved up a
touch this year but remain at very low levels.
Relatively high mortgage interest rates and
house prices have reduced aordability and
depressed homebuying sentiment. Moreover,
though new listings of existing homes have
increased modestly this year, the supply of
existing homes for sale remains quite low,
as many homeowners are reportedly “rate
locked”—unwilling to move and take out
a new mortgage while mortgage rates are
relatively high. Many households purchased
homes or renanced when xed mortgage rates
were at historically low levels in 2020 and 2021,
and, as a result, the majority of outstanding
mortgages have interest rates below 4percent
(gure23).
In contrast to existing home sales, sales of
new homes declined when mortgage rates
rst increased, but they bounced back fairly
quickly and have remained around their pre-
pandemic levels. The new home market has
likely been supported by demand from buyers
who are unable to nd homes in the existing
home market and by homebuilder interest rate
incentives (gure24).
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
Percent
20242022202020182016
22. Mortgage interest rates
Weekly
NOTE: The data are contract rates on 30-year, xed-rate conventional
home mortgage commitments and extend through June 27, 2024.
S
OURCE: Freddie Mac Primary Mortgage Market Survey via Haver
Analytics.
Below 5 percent
Below 6 percent
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
Percent
20242022202020182016201420122010
23. Distribution of interest rates on outstanding mortgages
Monthly
Below 4 percent
N
OTE
: The sample only includes outstanding mortgages current on
their payments.
S
OURCE
: ICE, McDash®.
Existing home sales
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
Millions, annual rate
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
24. New and existing home sales
Millions, annual rate
New home sales
N
OTE:The data are monthly. New and existing home sales include
only single-family sales.
S
OURCE: For new home sales, U.S. Census Bureau; for existing home
sales, National Association of Realtors; all via Haver Analytics.
26 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
The relative strength in new home demand
encouraged builders to increase housing
construction last year, boosting starts and
permits for single-family housing (gure25).
In recent months, though, single-family
housing starts and permits have drifted
back down, likely because of high builder
inventories and some easing in new home
demand. Reecting these demand and supply
factors, house price growth slowed rapidly in
2022 from a historically high pace and has
remained moderate since then (gure26).
The balance of demand and supply in the
multifamily housing market is fundamentally
dierent from that in the single-family housing
market, as it is dominated by rental units.
Sharp increases in rents in 2021 and 2022
encouraged a dramatic increase in multifamily
starts in those years, creating large amounts
of new supply. With many units still under
construction and weak rental growth since
2022, multifamily starts have been declining
since last year (as shown in gure25).
8
Capital spending increased at a
moderatepace
Business investment spending rose moderately
in 2023 and in the rst quarter of this
year, supported by strong sales growth and
improvements in business sentiment and
prot expectations—and despite high interest
rates (gure27). However, the sources of
strength in business investment shifted
recently. Investment in structures—which
had surged in early 2023 because of a boom
in manufacturing construction, especially
for factories that produce semiconductors or
electric vehicle batteries—decelerated in the
second half of 2023 and has slowed further so
far this year, although the level of structures
investment remains much higher than in
8. For additional discussion, see the box “Recent
Housing Market Developments” in Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System (2024), Monetary Policy
Report (Washington: Board of Governors, March),
pp.19–21, https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/
files/20240301_mprfullreport.pdf.
Single-family permits
Multifamily starts
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
Millions of units, annual rate
202420222020201820162014201220102008
25. Private housing starts and permits
Monthly
S
OURCE
: U.S. Census Bureau via Haver Analytics.
Single-family starts
Zillow
CoreLogic
20
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
25
Percent change from year earlier
20242019201420092004199919941989
26. Growth rate in house prices
Monthly
NOTE: S&P/Case-Shiller data extend through April 2024.
S
OURCE: CoreLogic, Inc., Home Price Index; Zillow, Inc., Real Estat
e
Data; S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index. The
S&P/Case-Shiller index is a product of S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC
and/or its aliates. (For Dow Jones Indices licensing information, see
the note on the Contents page.)
S&P/Case-Shiller
15
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
25
Percent, annual rate
20242022202020182016
27. Change in real business xed investment
H1
H2
Q1
NOTE: Business xed investment is known asprivate nonresidential
xed investment” in the national income and product accounts. The
key
identies bars in order from left to right.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Structures
Equipment and intangible capital
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 27
previous years. Starting late last year, growth
in business investment in nontransportation
equipment and intellectual property stepped
up, supported by gains in high-technology
equipment spending and software investment.
Business nancing conditions are
somewhat restrictive, but credit remains
generally available
Although businesses face somewhat restrictive
nancing conditions, as interest rates are still
elevated, credit remains generally available
to most nonnancial corporations. Banks
continued to tighten lending standards for
all business loan types over the rst quarter
of this year, and even though business loan
growth at banks increased in the rst ve
months of the year, it stayed tepid. In contrast,
issuance of corporate bonds remained strong
so far this year, although well below the
levels that prevailed at the beginning of the
tightening cycle.
For small businesses, which are more reliant
on bank nancing than large businesses, credit
conditions remained tight but stable over the
rst half of this year. Surveys indicate that
credit supply for small businesses tightened
modestly, while interest rates on loans to
small businesses were little changed, staying
near the top of the range observed since
2008. In addition, while loan default rates
have continued to increase, delinquency rates
stabilized in the rst part of the year at levels
that slightly exceeded their pre-pandemic
rates. Finally, loan originations have remained
stable over the past year and above the range
observed before the pandemic, suggesting
that credit continues to be available for small
businesses.
Net exports were a drag on GDP growth
On balance, net exports subtracted
0.7percentage point from U.S. GDP growth
in the rst quarter of this year after having
contributed about one-tenth to annualized
GDP growth in the second half of last year.
After moderate growth in the second half of
28 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
last year, real imports of goods and services
have stepped up further this year despite some
deceleration in U.S. GDP growth. By contrast,
real export growth has slowed signicantly,
as some categories with especially strong
growth in the second half of last year declined
this year, particularly industrial supplies and
materials (gure28). The current account
decit as a share of GDP widened slightly in
the rst quarter of 2024 and remains wider
than before the pandemic.
Federal scal policy actions were roughly
neutral for GDP growth last year and so
far this year
Federal purchases grew modestly in 2023 and
moved sideways in the rst quarter of the
year. The overall contribution of discretionary
federal scal policy to real GDP growth
appears to have been roughly neutral last year
and in the rst quarter of this year, as the
unwinding of pandemic-related policies oset
the boost to consumption and investment from
policies enacted after the pandemic.
The budget decit and federal debt
remain elevated
After surging to about 15percent of GDP in
scal year 2020, the budget decit declined
through scal 2022 as the imprint of the
pandemic faded (gure29). The budget decit
moved up to 6.3percent of GDP in scal
2023 as net interest outlays increased, while
tax receipts declined from their elevated level
in 2022. Debt service costs have moved up
sharply in recent years—as a result of higher
interest rates and a higher level of debt—and
are at their highest level in over two decades.
The primary decit—the dierence between
noninterest outlays and receipts—has moved
down, on net, since scal 2020 and moved
sideways in 2022 to 2023, as the eects of a
decline in noninterest outlays as a share of
GDP were oset by a decline in receipts as a
share ofGDP.
As a result of the unprecedented scal support
enacted early in the pandemic, federal debt held
by the public jumped roughly 20percentage
Expenditures
14
16
18
20
22
24
26
28
30
32
Percent of nominal GDP
2024202120182015201220092006200320001997
Annual
29. Federal receipts and expenditures
Receipts
N
OTE: Through 2023, the receipts and expenditures data are on a
unied-budget basis and are for scal years (October to September);
gross domestic product (GDP) is for the 4 quarters ending in Q3. For
2024, receipts and expenditures are for the 12 months ending in May;
GDP is the average of 2023:Q4 and 2024:Q1.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury, Financial Management Service;
Oce of Management and Budget and Bureau of Economic Analysis via
Haver Analytics.
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
Percent, annual rate
202420232022202120202019201820172016
28. Change in real imports and exports of goods
and services
H1
H2
Q1
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Imports
Exports
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 29
points to close to 100percent of GDP in
2020—the highest debt-to-GDP ratio since
1947 (gure30). The debt-to-GDP ratio has
moved roughly sideways since then, as upward
pressure from large primary decits has been
oset by strong nominal GDPgrowth.
Most state and local government budget
positions remained strong . . .
Federal policymakers provided a historically
high level of scal support to state and local
governments during the pandemic; this aid,
together with robust state tax collections
in 2021 and 2022, left the sector in a strong
budget position overall (gure31). Although
state tax revenues weakened in 2023 and early
this year—mainly reecting a normalization
of receipts from elevated levels in 2022, as
well as the eects of recently enacted tax
cuts in some states—taxes as a percentage
of GDP remained near recent historical
norms. Moreover, states’ total balances—that
is, including rainy day fund balances and
previous-year surplus funds—continued to
be near all-time highs. Nevertheless, budget
situations varied widely across states, with
some states—particularly those that depend
heavily on capital gains tax collections—facing
tighter budget conditions. At the local level,
overall property tax receipts rose briskly in
2023 and continued to increase at an elevated
rate in the rst quarter.
. . . contributing to brisk growth in
employment and construction spending
Employment in state and local governments
rose strongly in 2023 and early this year and
has now recovered from the drop during the
pandemic, though it is still below the level
implied by the pre-pandemic trend (gure32).
This surge in state and local employment
reects the waning of pandemic-related
headwinds such as a big increase in retirements
early in the pandemic and slower wage growth
relative to that in the private sector. Similarly,
real construction outlays grew at a historically
high rate last year, reecting easing bottlenecks
and support from federal grants, and are now
somewhat above their pre-pandemic levels.
Debt held by
the public
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
Percent of nominal GDP
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
30. Federal government debt and net interest outlays
Percent of nominal GDP
1904 1924 1944 1964 1984 2004 2024
Net interest outlays
on federal debt
N
OTE
: The data for net interest outlays are annual, begin in 1948, and
extend through 2023. Net interest outlays are the cost of servicing the
debt held by the public, oset by certain types of interest income the
government receives. Federal debt held by the public equals federal debt
excluding most intragovernmental debt, evaluated at the end of the
quarter. The data for federal debt are annual from 1901 to 1951 and a
4-quarter moving average thereafter. GDP is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE
: For GDP, Bureau of Economic Analysis via Haver
Analytics; for federal debt, Congressional Budget Oce and Federal
Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financial Accounts of the
United States.”
Total state taxes
10
5
+
_
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
Percent change from year earlier
2024202220202018201620142012
31. State and local tax receipts
Quarterly
N
OTE
: Receipts shown are year-over-year percent changes of 4-quarter
moving averages and begin in 2012:Q4. Property taxes are p
rimarily
collected by local governments.
S
OURCE
: U.S. Census Bureau, Quarterly Summary of State and L
ocal
Government Tax Revenue.
Property taxes
30 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Financial Developments
The expected level of the federal funds
rate over the next few years is higher
since the beginning of the year
Over the late winter and early spring, the
market-implied federal funds rate path moved
up, boosted by above-expectations ination
data that prompted market participants to
reassess the monetary policy restraint required
to return ination to 2percent. The rise in
the path was partially reversed since late
April amid mixed but generally softer-than-
expected data on real activity and ination.
Since the beginning of the year, on net, the
market-implied federal funds rate path rose
substantially (gure33). Financial market
prices currently suggest that investors expect
the federal funds rate to decline to about
4.9percent and 4.0percent by year-ends 2024
and 2025, respectively. Roughly consistent with
market-implied measures, respondents to the
Blue Chip Financial Forecasts survey have
signicantly revised upward their expectations
for the path of the federal funds rate, with
the average respondent in the July survey
expecting the federal funds rate to decline to
5.0percent in the fourth quarter of 2024—
0.6percentage point higher than anticipated at
the end of last year.
Yields on U.S. nominal Treasury securities
are higher on net
Consistent with the upward revision in the
market-implied federal funds rate path,
yields on shorter-term Treasury securities
rose notably between mid-February and late
April before retracing some of the increase
afterward. Yields on longer-term nominal
Treasury securities moved similarly with yields
on shorter-term nominal Treasury securities.
On balance, nominal Treasury yields are
moderately higher than at the beginning of the
year across the maturity spectrum (gure34).
An increase in real yields—as measured
by yields on Treasury Ination-Protected
Securities—accounted for a large portion of
the rise in nominal Treasury yields, especially
at longer maturities.
December 29, 2023
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
Percent
202820272026202520242023
33. Market-implied federal funds rate path
Quarterly
June 28, 2024
N
OTE
: The federal funds rate path is implied by quotes on overnight
index swaps—a derivative contract tied to the eective federal funds rate.
The implied path as of December 29, 2023, is compared with that as of
June 28, 2024. The path is estimated with a spline approach, assuming a
term premium of 0 basis points. The December 29, 2023, path extends
through 2027:Q4 and the June 28, 2024, path through 2028:Q2.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
2-year
5-year
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
20242023202220212020201920182017
34. Yields on nominal Treasury securities
Daily
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury via Haver Analytics.
10-year
18.5
19.0
19.5
20.0
20.5
Millions of jobs
2024202220202018201620142012201020082006
Monthly
32. State and local government payroll employment
S
OURCE
: Bureau of Labor Statistics via Haver Analytics.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 31
Yields on other long-term debt uctuated
with Treasury yields
Yields on corporate bonds generally followed
the movements in longer-term Treasury yields
and increased since the beginning of the year
for both the investment- and speculative-grade
segments of the market (gure35). Both yield
spreads on investment- and speculative-grade
corporate bonds over comparable-maturity
Treasury securities remain near the low end
of their respective historical distributions
as corporate bond investors appeared to be
pricing in a generally optimistic outlook.
Yields on municipal bonds remain at elevated
levels relative to rates prevailing before the
recent tightening cycle, having increased
moderately since January. Meanwhile,
spreads of municipal bond yields to yields
on comparable-maturity Treasury securities
were relatively little changed, on net, and are
at compressed levels relative to their historical
distribution. Yields on agency mortgage-
backed securities (MBS)—an important
inuence on home mortgage interest rates—
increased since the start of the year (gure36).
Agency MBS spreads to Treasury securities
remain elevated relative to pre-pandemic levels,
due in part to elevated interest rate volatility,
which increases the risk of holding MBS.
Broad equity price indexes increased
Broad equity price indexes rose substantially
since the start of the year, on net, led by large
technology rms (gure37). While equity
prices remained sensitive to ination news,
equity investors appeared to be generally
sanguine about the prospect of ination
coming down without a sharp downturn in
activity. First-quarter corporate earnings
releases, which were generally solid, also
supported equity valuations. Meanwhile,
equity prices for small-cap rms were little
changed. Equity prices for large banks
increased, on net, while equity prices for
regional banks declined, reecting lingering
concerns about the health of these banks
related in part to the quality of their
commercial real estate loans. One-month
option-implied volatility on the S&P 500
High-yield corporate
Municipal
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
Percent
20242023202220212020201920182017
35. Corporate bond yields, by securities rating, and
municipal bond yield
Daily
Investment-grade corporate
N
OTE: Investment-grade corporate reects the eective yield of the
ICE Bank of America Merrill Lynch (BofAML) triple-B U.S.
Corporate
Index (C0A4). High-yield corporate reects the eective yield of the ICE
BofAML High Yield Index (H0A0). Municipal reects the yield to worst
of the ICE BofAML U.S. Municipal Securities Index (U0A0).
S
OURCE
:ICE Data Indices, LLC, used with permission.
Yield
0
50
100
150
200
250
Basis points
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
20242023202220212020201920182017
36. Yield and spread on agency mortgage-backed
securities
Percent
Spread
N
OTE: The data are daily. Yield shown is for the uniform
mortgage-backed securities 30-year current coupon, the coupon rate at
which new mortgage-backed securities would be priced at par, or face,
value for dates after May 31, 2019; for earlier dates, the yield shown is for
the Fannie Mae 30-year current coupon. Spread shown is to the average
of the 5-year and 10-year nominal Treasury yields.
S
OURCE: Department of the Treasury; J.P. Morgan. Courtesy of J.P.
Morgan Chase & Co., Copyright 2024.
32 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
index—the VIX—uctuated somewhat,
reaching its peak so far this year in early
April amid increased ination concerns and
geopolitical tensions, but quickly retraced and
ended the period little changed (gure38).
Currently, the VIX stands close to its typical
historical level that was observed before the
pandemic. (For a discussion of nancial
stability issues, see the box “Developments
Related to Financial Stability.”)
Major asset markets functioned in an
orderly manner, despite some indicators
pointing to low liquidity
Functioning of the Treasury securities market
has continued to be orderly. While a number
of measures of Treasury market liquidity
remain low by historical standards, some of
these measures—such as on-the-run securities
market depth, a measure of the availability
of securities to transact at the best quoted
prices—improved modestly since January.
Liquidity in the equity market remained low
compared with pre-pandemic levels, and
liquidity conditions deteriorated slightly since
the beginning of the year. The depth of the
S&P 500 futures market decreased a bit, and
the price impact increased slightly. Corporate
and municipal bond markets continued
to function well, and trading conditions
remained stable; transaction costs in these
markets continued to be fairly low by historical
standards.
Short-term funding market conditions
remained stable
Conditions in overnight money markets
remained stable, with spreads of money
market rates to the Federal Reserve’s
administered rates roughly unchanged outside
of month-end dates. Since the beginning of
the year, the eective federal funds rate has
stayed 7 basis points below the interest rate
on reserve balances, and other unsecured
overnight rates have been around similar levels
with limited volatility. The Secured Overnight
Financing Rate has remained 1 or 2 basis
points above the oering rate on the overnight
S&P 500 index
50
75
100
125
150
175
December 31, 2019 = 100
20242023202220212020201920182017
37. Equity prices
Daily
Dow Jones bank index
S
OURCE: S&P Dow Jones Indices LLC via Bloomberg. (For Dow
Jones Indices licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
VIX
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Percent
20242022202020182016
38. S&P 500 volatility
Daily
Expected volatility
N
OTE
: The VIX is an option-implied volatility measure that represents
the expected annualized variability of the S&P 500 index over the
S
OURCE
: Cboe Volatility Index® (VIX®) via Bloomberg; Renitiv
DataScope; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
following 30 days. The expected volatility series shows a forecast of
1-month realized volatility, using a heterogeneous autoregressive model
based on 5-minute S&P 500 returns.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 33
This discussion reviews vulnerabilities in the U.S.
nancial system. The framework used by the Federal
Reserve Board for assessing the resilience of the U.S.
nancial system focuses on  nancial vulnerabilities
in four broad areas: asset valuations, business and
household debt, leverage in the  nancial sector, and
funding risks. All told, the  nancial system remains
sound and resilient. Valuations increased to levels that
were high relative to fundamentals across major asset
classes, with equity prices growing faster than expected
earnings and residential property prices remaining
high relative to market rents. Credit to non nancial
businesses and households relative to gross domestic
product (GDP) continued to decline, falling to nearly a
two-decade low. Most banks continued to report solid
capital levels, but fair value losses on  xed-rate assets
remained sizable. In addition, some banks continued
to rely signi cantly on uninsured deposits. Hedge fund
leverage grew to historical highs, driven primarily by
borrowing by the largest hedge funds.
Valuations rose further to levels that were high
relative to fundamentals across major asset classes.
Equity prices grew faster than expected earnings,
pushing the compensation for equity risk—computed
as the difference between the inverse of the forward
price-to-earnings ratio and expected real yields on
10-year Treasury securities—to its lowest level since
2007. Corporate bond spreads narrowed and currently
stand at levels close to historical lows. Amid limited
supply of homes available for sale, residential property
prices remained high relative to market rents, standing
near their peaks. Conditions in commercial real estate
(CRE) markets continued to deteriorate, with declining
transaction prices in most segments re ecting weak
demand. Nominal long-term Treasury yields increased
moderately since the beginning of the year and stayed
close to their highest levels over the past decade and
ahalf.
The balance sheets of non nancial businesses and
households remained strong. The combined debt of
both sectors as a share of GDP continued to decline
and sat close to its lowest level in two decades
( gureA). The decline is due to decreases in both
business- and household-sector debt relative to GDP
( gure B). Furthermore, business debt continued to
decline in real terms, and debt-servicing capacity
.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
Ratio
2024201720102003199619891982
A. Private nonnancial-sector credit-to-GDP ratio
Quarterly
NOTE: The shaded bars with top caps indicate periods of
business
recession as dened by the National Bureau of Economic
Research:
January 1980 to July 1980, July 1981 to November 1982, July 1990
to
March 1991, March 2001 to November 2001, December 2007 to
June
2009, and February 2020 to April 2020. GDP is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financia
l
Accounts of the United States”; Bureau of Economic Analysis,
national
income and product accounts; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
(continued on next page)
Developments Related to Financial Stability
Nonnancial business
.4
.5
.6
.7
.8
.9
1.0
Ratio
.3
.4
.5
.6
.7
.8
.9
1.0
1.1
2024201720102003199619891982
B. Nonnancial business and household debt-to-GDP
ratios
Ratio
NOTE: The data are quarterly. The shaded bars with top caps
indicate
periods of business recession as dened by the National Bureau o
f
Economic Research: July 1981 to November 1982, July 1990 to Marc
h
1991, March 2001 to November 2001, December 2007 to June 2009, an
d
February 2020 to April 2020. GDP is gross domestic product.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release Z.1, “Financia
l
Accounts of the United States”; Bureau of Economic Analysis,
national
income and product accounts; Federal Reserve Board sta calculations.
Household
34 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
for CRE and consumer loans—could put downward
pressure on banks’ pro ts and their ability to build
capital through retained earnings. Outside the banking
sector, hedge fund leverage stayed near historical highs,
partly due to funds’ substantial positions in the Treasury
futures basis trade. Leverage at broker-dealers continued
to be near historically low levels, but limited capacity or
willingness of broker-dealers to intermediate in Treasury
markets during market stress remained a structural
vulnerability. Life insurers’ leverage increased and stood
around its median.
Liquidity at most domestic banks remained ample,
with limited reliance on short-term wholesale funding.
However, some banks’ reliance on uninsured deposits
remained high, and bond mutual funds’ exposure to
interest rate risk continued to be signi cant. Structural
vulnerabilities remained in other short-term funding
markets. Prime and tax-exempt money market funds, as
well as other cash-investment vehicles and stablecoins,
continued to be vulnerable to runs. Bond and loan
funds remain susceptible to redemptions during
periods of stress, with more severe pressures possible
if assets become more illiquid or redemptions become
unusually large. In addition, life insurers continued to
rely on a higher-than-average share of nontraditional
liabilities.
stayed solid for most public  rms—in large part due to
strong earnings, large cash buffers, and low borrowing
costs on existing debt. In addition, the pass-through of
higher interest rates into debt-servicing costs continues
to be muted because the share of long-term,  xed-rate
liabilities remained sizable. Corporate bond default
rates have returned to their average levels, rising from
their low points in 2021 but declining from their peaks
in the second half of 2023, suggesting that credit
quality is stabilizing with pockets of stress continuing
for the riskiest borrowers. Expectations of year-ahead
defaults stayed somewhat elevated relative to their
history. Household balance sheets are still sound, as
most homeowners have ample home equity cushions
and strong credit histories. Borrowers with prime credit
scores—for whom delinquency rates remained low and
stable across credit markets—correspond to more than
60percent of all borrowers and continued to account
for most of household debt outstanding.
Regarding vulnerabilities in the  nancial sector, most
banks continued to report capital levels well above
regulatory requirements. However, fair value losses on
xed-rate assets remained sizable for some banks, while
parts of banks’ CRE portfolios are facing stress. Despite a
moderation in deposit out ows, higher funding costs—
together with expected increases in loss provisions
Developments Related to Financial Stability (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 35
reverse repurchase agreement (ON RRP)
facility, except for short-lived upward pressure
around month-ends. Take-up at the ON RRP
facility declined in the rst quarter, reecting
an increase in the net supply of Treasury bills
and the associated upward pressure on bill
yields relative to the oered rate on ON RRP
investments as well as relatively more attractive
rates on other short-term investments such as
private repurchase agreements. However, the
pace of decline in take-up slowed somewhat
in the second quarter, primarily because
of a decline in net bill supply. (See the box
“Developments in the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet and Money Markets” in Part 2.)
Assets under management of prime and
government money market funds (MMFs),
the largest investors in the ON RRP
facility, trended up as they continued to
oer favorable yields relative to most bank
deposits. Prime MMFs increased liquid
asset holdings and decreased weighted
average maturities to satisfy the Securities
and Exchange Commissions reform
requirements that became eective in April.
Several institutional prime funds announced
conversions to government funds, while
a handful announced closures, citing the
reform’s liquidity fees starting in October as
the main driver behind the decision. However,
these announced conversions and closures are
unlikely to materially aect the funds’ usage
of the ON RRP facility, because only minor
additional portfolio changes will be required
for conversions and because the decline in
money fund assets due to funds closing is
likely too small relative to total investments in
thefacility.
Bank credit continued to expand at a
slow pace
Banks’ total loan holdings grew at about
a 2percent annualized rate in the rst ve
months of the year, modestly up from a
1.3percent rate in the fourth quarter of 2023.
The still-tepid loan growth likely reects
the eects of higher interest rates, tighter
credit standards, and economic uncertainty
36 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
(gure39). Banks in the SLOOS reported
generally tighter standards and weaker demand
over the rst quarter of 2024, extending
trends for standards and demand that have
been reported since the middle of 2022.
Delinquency rates continued to climb to above
their longer-run average for commercial real
estate and consumer loans in the rst quarter
of 2024 but remained in ranges observed
before the pandemic across most other credit
segments. Bank protability picked up in the
rst quarter—reversing the dip in the fourth
quarter of 2023—mainly driven by recent
rising noninterest income and reduced loan
loss provisions. Bank protability levels are
still below those that prevailed before the
pandemic, reecting rising funding costs and
subdued loan demand (gure40).
International Developments
Foreign economic growth rose after a soft
patch in the second half of2023
After a soft patch in the second half of 2023,
foreign activity appears to have improved in
both advanced foreign economies (AFEs)
and emerging market economies (EMEs).
In AFEs, growth rates returned to moderate
levels despite the eects of restrictive
monetary policy as lower ination improved
real household incomes. In Europe, energy-
intensive sectors continue to struggle amid
ongoing structural adjustment to past
increases in energy prices following Russia’s
2022 invasion of Ukraine.
In EMEs, economic growth was supported by
a rebound in exports. In addition, industrial
production in emerging Asia was supported by
rising global demand for high-tech products,
driven in part by the AI and electric vehicle
sectors. China was a signicant contributor
to the pickup in foreign aggregate growth,
boosted by both strong exports and scal
policy support, even though household
spending expanded only moderately. Notably,
activity in China’s property sector remained
extremely weak and house prices fell sharply,
55
60
65
70
75
Percent
2024202120182015201220092006
39. Ratio of total commercial bank credit to nominal
gross domestic product
Quarterly
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.8, “Assets a
nd
Liabilities
of Commercial Banks in the United States”; Bureau o
f
Economic Analysis via Haver Analytics.
Return on assets
30
20
10
+
_
0
10
20
30
Percent, annual rate
2.0
1.5
1.0
.5
+
_
0
.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 2024
40. Protability of bank holding companies
Percent, annual rate
Return on equity
N
OTE
:The data are quarterly.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-9C,
Consolidated
Financial Statements for Holding Companies.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 37
prompting the authorities to introduce new
policy support measures.
Ination abroad continued to ease but
remains above central bank targets in
most regions
Foreign headline ination has continued to
stabilize overall since the middle of last year,
primarily reecting disination in AFE food
and energy prices (gures 41 and 42). That
said, the pace of disination has proved to
be slower than expected and uneven across
countries and economic sectors. As in the
U.S., the deceleration in goods prices abroad
has generally outpaced that in services prices.
Ination remains above target in Europe
but has been near zero in China. In many
economies, the main risks to continued
disination include both domestic factors,
such as sustained wage pressures, and external
geopolitical factors, such as Russia’s war
against Ukraine and developments in the
Middle East, which pose risks for supply chain
disruptions, increased trade costs, and higher
energy prices.
AFEs ex. Japan
Foreign
2
+
_
0
2
4
6
8
10
Percent change from year earlier
2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
41. Consumer price ination in foreign economies
Monthly
EMEs ex. China
N
OTE
: The advanced foreign economy (AFE) aggregate is the average
of Canada, the euro area, and the U.K., weighted by shares of U.S.
non-oil goods imports. The emerging market economy (EME) aggregate
is the average of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Israel, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines, Russia, Saudi
Arabia, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam,
weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil goods imports. The foreign aggregate
is the import-weighted average of all aforementioned countries. The
ination measure is the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices for the
euro area and the consumer price index for other economies.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations; Haver Analytics.
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Percent
2017–19
avg.
2020–21
avg.
2022 2023:H1 2023:H2 2024:Q1
Advanced foreign economies
NOTE: The advanced foreign economy aggregate is the average of Canada, the euro area, and the U.K., weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil goods
imports.
The emerging market economy aggregate is the average of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Israel, Malaysia,
Mexico,
the Philippines, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam, weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil goods
imports,
and begins in 2017:Q2. The ination measure is the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices for the euro area and the consumer price index for
other economies. The data show percent changes from year-ago levels.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations; Haver Analytics.
Energy
Food
Core
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
Percent
2017–19
avg.
2020–21
avg.
2022 2023:H12023:H2 2024:Q1
Emerging market economies
Energy
Food
Core
42. Components of foreign consumer price ination
38 PART 1: RECENT ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS
Foreign central banks cut policy rates but
remain cautious
Many foreign central banks have noted
progress in lowering ination and easing
resource tightness and have indicated that they
expect further progress. Some have begun to
cut their policy rates while continuing to stress
a data-dependent approach.
In EMEs, several central banks began easing
monetary policy late in 2023. AFE central
banks began to cut rates in the second quarter.
The Swiss National Bank, Swedens Riksbank,
the Bank of Canada, and the European
Central Bank all cut their policy rates amid
easing ination. Policy rate paths implied by
nancial market pricing indicate that markets
expect other AFE central banks to begin
reducing interest rates later this year. Still,
most foreign central bank communications
have also emphasized upside risks to ination
from persistent core services ination, currency
depreciation, and geopolitical tensions.
Japan has been a notable exception: Amid
persistently high Japanese ination, the Bank
of Japan (BOJ) ended its negative interest rate
policy and yield curve control in March.
Equity prices rose even as sovereign bond
yields in advanced foreign economies
increased
Foreign equity indexes rose signicantly
across AFEs and EMEs, consistent with
above-expectations economic data and
strong corporate earnings in many economies
(gure43). Nevertheless, investors withdrew
from EME-focused investment funds as higher
advanced-economy yields weighed on their
demand for EME assets. In addition, some
recent elections abroad contributed to notable
movements in equities and other asset prices.
AFE sovereign bond yields increased
signicantly in early 2024 and are up notably
since the start of the year in Germany, Japan,
and the U.K. (gure44). These increases
were driven by stronger-than-expected global
activity data and spillovers from higher U.S.
yields. Relative to late 2023, market-implied
Japan
U.K.
Euro area
75
100
125
150
175
200
Week ending January 4, 2019 = 100
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
43. Equity indexes for selected foreign economies
Weekly
NOTE: The data are weekly averages of daily data and extend through
June 28, 2024.
S
OURCE: For the euro area, Dow Jones Euro Stoxx Index; for Japan
,
Tokyo Stock Price Index; for China, Shanghai Composite Index; for the
U.K., FTSE 100 Index; all via Bloomberg. (For Dow Jones Indices
licensing information, see the note on the Contents page.)
China
Germany
Japan
Canada
1
+
_
0
1
2
3
4
5
Percent
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
44. Nominal 10-year government bond yields in
selected advanced foreign economies
Weekly
N
OTE
: The data are weekly averages of daily benchmark yields and
extend through June 28, 2024.
S
OURCE
: Bloomberg.
U.K.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 39
paths for policy rates now indicate a later start
to easing and fewer rate cuts by many central
banks. In Japan, yields were further supported
by three BOJ tightening actions: raising policy
rates from negative 0.1percent to a band of
0 to 0.1percent, discontinuing the yield curve
control framework, and issuing guidance
pointing to a potential reduction in sovereign
bond purchases.
The exchange value of the dollar rose
notably
Since year-end 2023, the broad dollar index—a
measure of the exchange value of the dollar
against a trade-weighted basket of foreign
currencies—increased signicantly, on net,
reecting dollar appreciation against both
AFE and EME currencies (gure45). The
increase in the dollar index was consistent
with a widening of interest rate dierentials
between the U.S. and the rest of the world.
75
80
85
90
95
100
105
110
115
Week ending December 27, 2019 = 100
2014 2016 2018 2020 2022 2024
45. U.S. dollar exchange rate index
Weekly
Dollar appreciation
N
OTE:The data, which are in foreign currency units per dollar, are
weekly averages of daily values of the broad dollar index and
extend
through June 28, 2024. As indicated by the arrow, increases in the data
reect U.S. dollar appreciation and decreases reect U.S. dollar
depreciation.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board sta calculations; Federal Reserve
Board, Statistical Release H.10, “Foreign Exchange Rates.”
41
The Federal Open Market Committee has
held the federal funds rate steady . . .
The Federal Reserve conducts monetary
policy to promote its statutory goals of
maximum employment and price stability.
(See the box “Monetary Policy Independence,
Transparency, and Accountability.”) Ination
has eased over the past year but has remained
elevated while the economy has continued
to expand at a solid pace. Job gains have
been strong, and the unemployment rate has
remained low. Against this backdrop, the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
has maintained a restrictive stance of policy
at recent meetings to keep demand in line
with supply and reduce inationary pressures.
Since its July2023 meeting, the Committee
has maintained the target range for the federal
funds rate at 5¼ to 5½percent, after having
raised the target range a total of 525 basis
points starting in early 2022 (gure46). The
FOMC’s policy tightening actions and current
policy stance reect the Committee’s strong
commitment to return ination to its 2percent
objective. Restoring price stability is essential
to achieving maximum employment and
stable prices over the long run that benet all
Americans.
With labor market tightness continuing to ease
gradually and ination easing over the past
year, the risks to achieving the Committee’s
employment and ination goals have moved
toward better balance. The Committee remains
highly attentive to ination risks and is acutely
aware that high ination imposes signicant
hardship, especially on those least able to
meet the higher costs of essentials, like food,
housing, and transportation. In considering
any adjustments to the target range for the
federal funds rate, the Committee will carefully
assess incoming data, the evolving outlook,
and the balance of risks. The Committee does
not expect it will be appropriate to reduce
the target range until it has gained greater
condence that ination is moving sustainably
toward 2percent.
Part 2
monetary PoLicy
Target federal funds rate
2-year Treasury rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Percent
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
46. Selected interest rates
Daily
10-year Treasury rate
N
OTE
: The 2-year and 10-year Treasury rates are the constant-maturity yields based on the most actively traded securities.
S
OURCE
: Department of the Treasury; Federal Reserve Board.
42 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
monetary policy has become an international norm,
and economic research indicates that economic
performance has tended to be better when central
banks have such independence.
2
Because the Federal Reserve is accountable to
Congress and has been granted independence in
See PaulA. Volcker (1982), “Panel Discussion,” in Federal
Reserve’s First Monetary Policy Report for 1982, hearings
before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,
U.S. Senate, February11 and 25, Senate Hearing 97-48,
97th Cong. (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Of ce),
quoted text on p. 28, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/monetary-
policy-oversight-671/federal-reserve-s- rst-monetary-policy-
report-1982-22312; Paul A. Volcker (1987), remarks in Federal
Reserve’s Second Monetary Policy Report for 1987, hearing
before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban
Affairs, U.S. Senate, July23, 100th Cong. (Washington: U.S.
Government Printing Of ce), quoted text on p. 45, https://
fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/monetary-policy-oversight-671/
federal-reserve-s-second-monetary-policy-report-1987-22373;
Alan Greenspan (1994), remarks in The Federal Reserve
Accountability Act of 1993, hearing before the Committee
on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs, U.S. House of
Representatives, October13, 1993, 103rd Cong. (Washington:
U.S. Government Printing Of ce), quoted text on p. 40,
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/federal-reserve-accountability-
act-1993-1154; Ben S. Bernanke (2010), “Central Bank
Independence, Transparency, and Accountability,” speech
delivered at the Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies
International Conference, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, May25,
quoted text in paragraph 2, https://www.federalreserve.gov/
newsevents/speech/bernanke20100525a.htm; Janet L. Yellen
(2010), “Macroprudential Supervision and Monetary Policy in
the Post-crisis World,” speech delivered at the Annual Meeting
of the National Association for Business Economics, Denver,
Colo., October11, quoted text in paragraph 44, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20101011a.
htm; and Jerome H. Powell (2023), “Panel on ‘Central Bank
Independence and the Mandate—Evolving Views,’ ” speech
delivered at the Symposium on Central Bank Independence,
Sveriges Riksbank, Stockholm, Sweden, January10,
quoted text in paragraph 2, https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/speech/powell20230110a.htm. A detailed
discussion of the issues involved is provided by Paul Tucker
(2018), Unelected Power: The Quest for Legitimacy in Central
Banking and the Regulatory State (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press).
2. See, for example, Christopher Crowe and Ellen E. Meade
(2008), “Central Bank Independence and Transparency:
Evolution and Effectiveness,European Journal of Political
Economy, vol. 24 (December), pp. 763–77.
Monetary policy is carried out by the Federal
Reserve in pursuit of maximum employment and price
stability—the dual-mandate goals assigned to it by
Congress. Congress has also given the Federal Reserve
operational independence. Under this arrangement,
the Federal Reserve, rather than other parts of the
government, makes determinations about the monetary
policy actions that are most appropriate for achieving
the dual-mandate goals. This arrangement allows
monetary policy decisions to be insulated from short-
term political in uences.
There is broad support for the principles underlying
independent monetary policy. It is widely understood
that the monetary policy actions that deliver maximum
employment and price stability in the longer run may
involve restraining measures that entail short-run
economic costs, while actions that raise output and
employment to unsustainable levels have no long-run
real bene ts and may lead to elevated in ation rates.
These considerations highlight the value of monetary
policy being carried out by an independent agency
whose decisions are based on the congressionally
assigned dual mandate.
1
Operational independence of
1. The same basic case for independence has been sketched
by successive Federal Reserve Chairs. For example, Paul
Volcker noted in congressional testimony in February1982
that “Congress deliberately set us up with an insulation from
that kind of political pressure, and that that is a trust that
you have given us and that we mean to discharge,” and he
elaborated in July1987: “[Not] responding to all the short-
term political considerations that exist to produce easier
money than the basic situation warrants and the long-term
health of the currency and the economy warrants . . . [is]
the basic justi cation for the independence of the Federal
Reserve.Alan Greenspan testi ed in October1993 that
there was “an awareness that independence of the central
bank is an element in keeping in ation down.” Ben Bernanke
remarked in May2010: “It is important that we maintain and
protect . . . the ability of central banks to make monetary
policy decisions based on what is good for the economy
in the longer run, independent of short-term political
considerations.Also in 2010, Janet Yellen (who was at the
time Vice Chair of the Federal Reserve Board and who later
served as Federal Reserve Chair) observed: “The principle
of central bank independence in the conduct of monetary
policy is widely accepted as vital to achieving maximum
employment and price stability.” Chair Jerome Powell likewise
stated in January2023 that “the case for monetary policy
independence lies in the bene ts of insulating monetary
policy decisions from short-term political considerations.”
(continued)
Monetary Policy Independence, Transparency, and
Accountability
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 43
the 1980s regularly gave congressional testimony and
speeches on monetary policy. Nevertheless, important
aspects of transparency were missing. The FOMC
in these decades did not provide, in a systematic
and timely manner, information on its monetary
policy decisions.
4
In particular, it did not follow a
regular practice of issuing, after policy meetings, an
announcement of Committee policy actions and the
rationale for those actions. The situation changed
starting in the mid-1990s. Re ecting on this change,
in 2023 Chair Powell noted: “Over the past several
decades we have steadily broadened our efforts to
provide meaningful transparency about the basis for,
and consequences of, the decisions we make.
5
The shift to greater transparency has re ected
not only the fact that transparency supports the
Federal Reserve’s accountability, but also widespread
acceptance that transparency can contribute to the
effectiveness of monetary policy. Explanations to the
general public of the FOMC’s decisions, strategy, and
plans tend to enhance the effects of monetary policy
actions on  nancial conditions, economic activity,
and in ation. For example, a numerical in ation
objective can be helpful in anchoring longer-run
in ation expectations, while forward guidance (which
is at times provided in FOMC statements) about the
federal funds rate can in uence key longer-term interest
rates by shaping the private sector’s assessment of the
likely future course of the funds rate. Consequently,
the FOMC has observed that clarity about monetary
4. See David E. Lindsey (2003), “A Modern History of
FOMC Communication: 1975–2002,” memorandum to the
Federal Open Market Committee, Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary Affairs,
June24, https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/
FOMC20030624memo01.pdf; and Ben S. Bernanke (2013),
A Century of US Central Banking: Goals, Frameworks,
Accountability,Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 27
(Fall), pp. 3–16.
5. See Powell, “Panel on ‘Central Bank Independence,’”
in box note 1 (quoted text in paragraph 4). See also Alan
S. Blinder (2002), “Through the Looking Glass: Central
Bank Transparency,” CEPS Working Paper 86 (Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Department of Economics,
December), https://gceps.princeton.edu/wp-content/
uploads/2017/01/86blinder.pdf.
the setting of monetary policy, it is vitally important
that the Federal Reserve be transparent to Congress
and the American people about its monetary policy
actions. Transparency requires that the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) explain the reasons for
its monetary policy decisions, including how these
decisions relate to its statutory goals. This feature of
transparency underlies the FOMC’s assessment that
“transparency and accountability . . . are essential in a
democraticsociety.
3
Speci cally, monetary policy transparency consists
of the process in which the Federal Reserve provides to
the American people and their elected representatives
information about the objectives and strategy of
monetary policy, announces its decisions regarding the
setting of its policy instruments, explains the reasoning
behind those decisions, and provides detailed records
of monetary policy committee meetings. The Federal
Reserve promotes monetary policy transparency in
multiple ways, including through testimony given
by Federal Reserve policymakers at congressional
hearings, speeches by the Chair and other FOMC
meeting participants on economic and policy
developments, the FOMC’s postmeeting statements,
the published minutes and transcripts of each
FOMC meeting, the quarterly Summary of Economic
Projections (SEP), the Chair’s press conferences, and
dialogues between FOMC participants and community
representatives across thecountry.
A strong emphasis on transparency has
characterized the past 30years of U.S. monetary policy.
Previously, Federal Reserve of cials from the 1950s to
3. See the FOMC’s Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy (quoted text in paragraph 1),
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomc_longerrungoals.pdf. More
speci cally, paragraph 1 of this statement indicates that “the
Committee seeks to explain its monetary policy decisions
to the public as clearly as possible” and that “such clarity
facilitates . . . transparency and accountability, which are
essential in a democratic society.” In the same spirit, a major
contribution to the research literature on the practice of
monetary policy—the 1999 book In ation Targeting—earlier
observed: “Transparency and communication together
enhance accountability.” See Ben S. Bernanke, Thomas
Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S. Posen (1999),
In ation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience
(Princeton N.J.: Princeton University Press), quoted text
on p.296.
(continued on next page)
44 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
At the end of 2007, the FOMC began publishing,
on a quarterly basis, the SEP, which distills information
about individual meeting participants’ economic
projections. Since then, numerous features have been
added to the SEP, including longer-run projections
in 2009 and federal funds rate projections in 2012.
In 2011, Chair Bernanke started holding regular
postmeeting press conferences. In 2019, Chair Powell
initiated the practice of holding press conferences after
every FOMC meeting.
With regard to its strategy, in January2012 the
FOMC issued a Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy, or “consensus statement.The
consensus statement has been reaf rmed in the years
since 2012, and it has been revised several times. From
its inception, the consensus statement made the price-
stability component of the dual mandate numerically
precise by indicating that Federal Reserve policymakers
interpret it as corresponding to a 2percent longer-
run in ation rate (in the personal consumption
expenditures price index). Also in the area of strategy,
in 2018 the Federal Reserve launched the practice of
having a review of monetary policy strategy, tools, and
communication practices roughly every  ve years. The
rst such framework review took place from 2019 to
2020. An innovation of this review was the holding,
around the country, of Fed Listens events, consisting
of a dialogue between Federal Reserve policymakers
and community members on monetary policy and
economic issues. The Federal Reserve has continued
to hold Fed Listens events between the periods of
framework review.
The framework review process also included
internal FOMC deliberations. These deliberations took
place at Committee meetings and were detailed in
the publicly released FOMC meeting minutes. The
Federal Reserve staff memos that served as an input
into these deliberations were released publicly after the
completion of the 2019–20 review. The next framework
review is scheduled to begin later this year.
Along with the transparency-enhancing activities,
documents, and statements described earlier, further
information on monetary policy decisions is provided
in the frequent speeches, interviews, and testimony
given by FOMC meeting participants.
policy decisions “increases the effectiveness of
monetarypolicy.
6
Today the acceptance of the need for, and bene ts
of, monetary policy transparency is re ected in the
large volume of material that the FOMC and the
individual Committee participants provide about their
decisions and thinking.
7
A major step in the direction
of greater transparency took place in 1994, when
announcements of policy changes began to be issued
after FOMC meetings. By the end of the decade, these
releases had evolved into the now standard and key
part of the Committee’s policy communications—a
statement released by the Committee after each
meeting that announces the decision on the federal
funds rate target range and any other policy actions,
puts that decision in the context of the Committee’s
assessment of incoming data and the economic
outlook, and gives the record of the vote on the action.
8
Further information about Committee decisions is
provided via FOMC meeting minutes, released three
weeks after each FOMC meeting (a shorter lag than
that prevailing until the mid-2000s). After  ve years,
transcripts of the FOMC meetings are made public.
6. See the FOMC’s Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy, in box note 3 (quoted text in
paragraph 1).
7. For further details, see Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System (2019), “Review of Monetary Policy
Strategy, Tools, and Communications,” webpage, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-
strategy-tools-and-communications-fed-listens-timelines.htm;
and Jerome H. Powell (2024), “Opening Remarks,” speech
delivered at the Stanford Business, Government, and Society
Forum, Stanford Graduate School of Business, Stanford, Calif.,
April3, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/
powell20240403a.htm.
8. In the past 15years, information about the Committee’s
balance sheet policy has been an important part of the
postmeeting statement and related FOMC statements.
A detailed account of key communications on balance
sheet policy that the Committee has issued in recent years
is provided in Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2024), “FOMC Communications Related to Policy
Normalization,” webpage, https://www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/policy-normalization.htm. A longer-term
chronology, covering developments over the past decade,
is available at Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2024), “History of the FOMC’s Policy Normalization
Discussions and Communications,” webpage, https://www.
federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/policy-normalization-
discussions-communications-history.htm.
Monetary Policy Independence (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 45
. . . and has continued the process of
signicantly reducing its holdings of
Treasury and agency securities
The FOMC began reducing its securities
holdings in June2022 and, since then,
has continued to implement its plan for
signicantly reducing the size of the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet in a predictable
manner.
9
For some time, principal payments
from securities held in the System Open
Market Account (SOMA) had been reinvested
only to the extent that they exceeded monthly
caps of $60billion per month for Treasury
securities and $35billion per month for agency
debt and agency mortgage-backed securities
(MBS). On June1, the Committee slowed
the pace of decline of its securities holdings,
consistent with its Plans for Reducing the
Size of the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet.
Specically, the Committee reduced the
redemption cap on Treasury securities to
$25billion per month and maintained the
redemption cap on agency debt and agency
MBS at $35billion per month. Any proceeds
9. See the May4, 2022, press release regarding the
Plans for Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet, available on the Board’s website at https://
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/
monetary20220504b.htm.
in excess of the agency debt and agency
MBS cap would be reinvested into Treasury
securities, consistent with the Committee’s
intention to hold primarily Treasury securities
in the longer run. The decision to slow the
pace of balance sheet runo does not have
implications for the stance of monetary
policy and does not mean that the balance
sheet will ultimately shrink by less than it
would otherwise. Rather, a slower pace of
balance sheet runo helps facilitate a smooth
transition from abundant to ample reserve
balances and gives the Committee more time
to assess market conditions as the balance
sheet continues to shrink. It will also allow
banks, and short-term funding markets more
generally, additional time to adjust to the lower
level of reserves, thus reducing the probability
that money markets experience undue stress
that could require an early end to runo.
The SOMA holdings of Treasury and agency
securities have declined about $1.7trillion
since the start of the balance sheet reduction
and about $260billion since February2024
to around $6.8trillion, a level equivalent to
24percent of U.S. nominal gross domestic
product, down from its peak of 35percent
reached at the end of 2021 (gure47). Also,
since February2024, reserve balances—
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
Trillions of dollars
20242023202220212020201920182017201620152014201320122011201020092008
47. Federal Reserve assets and liabilities
Weekly
Other assets
Credit and liquidity facilities
Agency debt and mortgage-backed securities holdings
Treasury securities held outright
Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Deposits of depository institutions (reserves)
Reverse repurchase agreements
Capital and other liabilities
N
OTE
: “Other assets” includes repurchase agreements, FIMA (Foreign and International Monetary Authorities) repurchase agreements, and unamortized
premiums
and discounts on securities held outright. “Credit and liquidity facilities” consists of primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; term auction credit;
central
bank liquidity swaps; support for Maiden Lane, Bear Stearns Companies, Inc., and AIG; and other credit and liquidity facilities, including the
Primary
Dealer Credit Facility, the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility, the Commercial Paper Funding
Facility,
the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, the Primary and Secondary Market Corporate Credit Facilities, the Paycheck Protection Program
Liquidity Facility, the Municipal Liquidity Facility, and the Main Street Lending Program. “Agency debt and mortgage-backed sec
urities holdings” includes
agency
residential mortgage-backed securities and agency commercial mortgage-backed securities. “Capital and other liabilities” includes the U.S. Treasury
General
Account and the U.S. Treasury Supplementary Financing Account. The key identies shaded areas in order from top to bottom. The data extend
through June 19, 2024.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors Aecting Reserve Balances.”
46 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the largest liability item on the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet—have declined about
$180billion to a level of around $3.4trillion.
The smaller decline of reserve balances
compared with the decline in SOMA holdings
reects decreases in nonreserve liabilities such
as balances at the overnight reverse repurchase
agreement facility. (See the box “Developments
in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and
Money Markets.”)
The FOMC has stated that it intends to
maintain securities holdings at amounts
consistent with implementing monetary
policy eciently and eectively in its ample-
reserves regime—that is, a regime in which an
ample supply of reserves ensures that control
over the level of the federal funds rate and
other short-term interest rates is exercised
primarily through the setting of the Federal
Reserve’s administered rates and in which
active management of the supply of reserves
is not required. To ensure a smooth transition
to ample reserve balances, the FOMC slowed
the pace of decline of its securities holdings
in June2024 and intends to stop reductions in
its securities holdings when reserve balances
are somewhat above the level that the FOMC
judges to be consistent with ample reserves.
Once balance sheet runo has ceased, reserve
balances will likely continue to decline at
a slower pace—reecting growth in other
Federal Reserve liabilities—until the FOMC
judges that reserve balances are at an ample
level. Thereafter, the FOMC will manage
securities holdings as needed to maintain
ample reserves over time.
The FOMC will continue to monitor the
implications of incoming information for
the economic outlook and the balance
ofrisks
As already indicated, the FOMC is strongly
committed to returning ination to its
2percent objective, and, in considering any
adjustments to the target range for the federal
funds rate, the Committee will carefully assess
incoming data, the evolving outlook, and
the balance of risks. Its assessments will take
into account a wide range of information,
including readings on labor market conditions,
ination pressures and ination expectations,
and nancial and international developments.
The Committee has noted that it is also
prepared to adjust its approach to reducing the
size of the balance sheet in light of economic
and nancial developments.
In addition to considering a wide range of
economic and nancial data, the FOMC
gathers information from business contacts
and other informed parties around the
country, as summarized in the Beige Book.
The Federal Reserve has regular arrangements
under which it hears from a broad range of
participants in the U.S. economy about how
monetary policy aects people’s daily lives
and livelihoods. In particular, the Federal
Reserve has continued to gather insights into
these matters through the Fed Listens initiative
and the Federal Reserve System’s community
development outreach.
Policymakers also routinely consult
prescriptions for the policy interest rate
provided by various monetary policy rules.
These rule prescriptions can provide useful
benchmarks for the conduct of monetary
policy. However, simple rules cannot capture
all of the complex considerations that go
into the formation of appropriate monetary
policy, and many practical considerations
make it undesirable for the FOMC to adhere
strictly to the prescriptions of any specic
rule. Nevertheless, some principles of good
monetary policy are embedded in these simple
rules. (See the box“Monetary Policy Rules in
the Current Environment.”)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 47
announced that beginning in June, the Committee
would slow the pace of decline of its securities
holdings, consistent with its Plans for Reducing the Size
of the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet.
2
dated February29, 2024. As a result, this discussion refers
to changes in the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet since late
February.
2. See the May4, 2022, press release regarding the Plans
for Reducing the Size of the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet,
available on the Board’s website at https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20220504b.htm.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
continued to reduce the size of the Federal Reserve’s
System Open Market Account (SOMA) portfolio. Since
the previous report, total Federal Reserve assets have
decreased $315billion, leaving the total size of the
balance sheet at $7.3trillion, $1.7trillion smaller since
the reduction in the size of the SOMA portfolio began
in June2022 ( gures A and B).
1
On May1, the FOMC
1. The last Federal Reserve Board statistical release H.4.1
(“Factors Affecting Reserve Balances”) before the publication
of the previous Monetary Policy Report on March1 was
Developments in the Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet
and Money Markets
A. Balance sheet comparison
Billions of dollars
June 19, 2024 February 28, 2024
Change
(since February
2024)
Memo:
Change (since
Fed’s balance sheet
reduction began on
June 1, 2022)
Assets
Total securities
Treasury securities 4,453 4,661 −208 −1,318
Agency debt and MBS 2,357 2,406 −49 −353
Unamortized premiums 265 274 −8 −72
Repurchase agreements 0 0 0 0
Loans and lending facilities
PPPLF 3 3 0 −17
Discount window 7 2 5 6
BTFP 107 163 −56 107
Other loans and lending facilities
11 15 −4 −23
Central bank liquidity swaps 0 0 0 0
Other assets 49 44 6 7
Total assets 7,253 7,568 −315 −1,663
Liabilities
Federal Reserve notes 2,301 2,282 18 70
Reserves held by depository institutions 3,366 3,541 −175 9
Reverse repurchase agreements
Foreign o cial and international accounts 389 339 50 124
Others 376 570 −194 −1,589
U.S. Treasury General Account 782 768 14 2
Other deposits 158 162 −4 −90
Other liabilities and capital −120 −94 −25 −188
Total liabilities and capital 7,253 7,568 315 1,663
N: MBS is mortgage-backed securities. PPPLF is Paycheck Protection Program Liquidity Facility. BTFP is Bank Term Funding Program. Components may not sum to
totals because of rounding.
S: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors A ecting Reserve Balances.”
(continued on next page)
48 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
reserve-draining effect of balance sheet runoff was
more than offset by a $1.6trillion decline in balances at
the overnight reverse repurchase agreement (ONRRP)
facility. Since February2024, usage of the ON RRP
facility has continued to decline, albeit at a slower pace
than that seen over the second half of 2023. Usage
of the facility has averaged around $450billion since
the end of February ( gure C). Reduced usage of the
ON RRP facility largely re ects money market mutual
funds shifting their portfolios toward higher-yielding
investments, including Treasury bills and private-market
repurchase agreements.
Conditions in overnight money markets remained
stable. The ON RRP facility continued to serve its
intended purpose of supporting the control of the
effective federal funds rate (EFFR), and the Federal
Reserve’s administered rates—the interest rate on
reserve balances and the ON RRP offering rate—
remained highly effective at maintaining the EFFR
within the target range.
The Federal Reserve’s expenses have continued to
exceed its income over recent months. The Federal
Reserve’s deferred asset has increased $23billion
since late February to a level of around $175billion.
4
Negative net income and the associated deferred asset
4. The deferred asset is equal to the cumulative shortfall of
net income and represents the amount of future net income
that will need to be realized before remittances to the Treasury
resume. Although remittances are suspended at the time of this
Reserves, the largest liability item on the Federal
Reserve’s balance sheet, have declined $175billion
since late February2024 to a level of about
$3.4trillion.
3
Since the beginning of balance sheet
runoff, reserves have been little changed because the
3. Reserve balances consist of deposits held at the
Federal Reserve Banks by depository institutions (DIs), such
as commercial banks, savings banks, credit unions, thrift
institutions, and U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks.
(continued)
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Trillions of dollars
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
B. Federal Reserve assets
Weekly
N
OTE
: MBS is mortgage-backed securities. The key identies shaded areas
in order from top to bottom. The data extend through June 19, 2024.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1, “Factors
Aecting Reserve Balances.”
Other assets
Loans
Central bank liquidity swaps
Repurchase agreements
Agency debt and MBS
Treasury securities
held outright
Federal Reserve’s Balance Sheet and Money Markets (continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 49
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
Trillions of dollars
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
C. Federal Reserve liabilities
Weekly
NOTE: “Capital and other liabilities” includes the liability for e
arnings
remittances
due to the U.S. Treasury and contributions from the
U.S.
Treasury.
The current sum is negative on June 19, 2024, because of
the
deferred asset that the Federal Reserve reports. The key identies shaded areas
in order from top to bottom. The data extend through June 19, 2024.
S
OURCE: Federal Reserve Board, Statistical Release H.4.1,
“Factors
Aecting Reserve Balances.”
Overnight reverse repurchase (ON RRP) agreements
Deposits of depository institutions (reserves)
U.S. Treasury General Account
Other deposits
Capital and other liabilities
Federal Reserve notes
While the reduction in the size of the SOMA
portfolio has continued as planned, amid the banking-
sector developments of spring 2023, the Federal
Reserve provided liquidity to help ensure the stability
of the banking system and the ongoing provision of
money and credit to the economy. Loans extended
under the Bank Term Funding Program (BTFP)—which
made longer-term funding and liquidity available to
eligible depository institutions to support American
households and businesses and ceased making
new loans as scheduled on March11, 2024—have
decreased $56billion to a level of $107billion since
February2024.
6
expenses will fall over time in line with the decline in the
Federal Reserve’s liabilities.
6. The BTFP was established under section 13(3) of the
Federal Reserve Act with the approval of the Secretary of the
Treasury. The BTFP offered loans of up to one year to banks,
savings associations, credit unions, and other eligible DIs
against collateral such as U.S. Treasury securities, U.S. agency
securities, and U.S. agency mortgage-backed securities. For
more details, see Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System (2024), “Bank Term Funding Program,” webpage,
June11, https://www.federalreserve.gov/ nancial-stability/
bank-term-funding-program.htm.
do not affect the Federal Reserve’s conduct of monetary
policy or its ability to meet its  nancial obligations.
5
report, over the past decade and a half, the Federal Reserve
has remitted over $1trillion to the Treasury.
5. Net income is expected to turn positive again as interest
expenses fall, and remittances will resume once the temporary
deferred asset falls to zero. As a result of the ongoing reduction
in the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet, interest
50 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
reduce its holdings of Treasury securities and agency
debt and agency mortgage-backed securities.
Selected Policy Rules: Descriptions
In many economic models, desirable economic
outcomes can be achieved over time if monetary
policy responds to changes in economic conditions
in a manner that is predictable and adheres to some
key design principles. In recognition of this idea,
economists have analyzed many monetary policy
rules, including the well-known Taylor (1993) rule,
the “balanced approach” rule, the “adjusted Taylor
(1993)” rule, and the “ rst difference” rule.
1
Figure A
shows these rules, along with a “balanced approach
1. The Taylor(1993) rule was introduced in John
B. Taylor (1993), “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39
(December), pp. 195–214. The balanced-approach rule was
analyzed in John B. Taylor (1999), “A Historical Analysis of
Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy
Rules (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 319–41. The
adjusted Taylor(1993) rule was studied in David Reifschneider
and John C. Williams (2000), “Three Lessons for Monetary
Policy in a Low-In ation Era,Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, vol. 32 (November), pp. 936–66. The  rst-difference
rule is based on a rule suggested by Athanasios Orphanides
(2003), “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor
Rule,Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July),
As part of their monetary policy deliberations,
policymakers regularly consult the prescriptions
of a variety of simple interest rate rules without
mechanically following the prescriptions of any
particular rule. Simple interest rate rules relate a
policy interest rate, such as the federal funds rate, to a
small number of other economic variables—typically
including the current deviation of in ation from its
target value and a measure of resource slack in
the economy.
Since 2021, in ation has run above the Federal
Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) 2percent longer-
run objective, and labor market conditions have been
tight. Although in ation remains elevated, it has eased
over the past year, and labor supply and demand
have come into better balance. Against this backdrop,
the simple monetary policy rules considered in this
discussion have called for levels of the policy interest
rate over 2021, 2022, and the  rst half of 2023 that
were elevated relative to the FOMC’s target range for
the federal funds rate. However, the rates prescribed
by these rules for the  rst quarter of 2024, the most
recent quarter for which data are available, are close
to or below the current target range for the federal
funds rate at 5¼ to 5½percent. In support of its
goals of maximum employment and in ation at the
rate of 2percent over the longer run, the FOMC has
maintained the target range for the federal funds rate
at 5¼ to 5½percent since last July while continuing to
(continued)
A. Monetary policy rules
Balanced-approach rule
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
N: R
t
T93
, R
t
BA
, R
t
BAS
, R
t
T93adj
, and R
t
FD
represent the values of the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by the Taylor (1993),
balanc
ed-approach, balanced-approach (shortfalls), adjusted Taylor (1993), and rst-dierence rules, respectively.
R
t−1
denotes the midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate for quarter t1, u
t
is the unemployment rate in quarter t, and r
t
LR
is the
le
vel of the neutral real federal funds rate in the longer run that is expected to be consistent with sustaining maximum employment and keepin
g
in
ation at the Federal Open Market Committee’s 2percent longer-run objective, represented by π
LR
. π
t
denotes the realized 4-quarter price
in
ation for quarter t. In addition, u
t
LR
is the rate of unemployment expected in the longer run. Z
t
is the cumulative sum of past deviations of
th
e federal funds rate from the prescriptions of the Taylor (1993) rule when that rule prescribes setting the federal funds rate below an eective
lo
wer bound (ELB) of 12.5 basis points.
The Taylor (1993) rule and other policy rules generally respond to the deviation of real output from its full capacity level. In these equations,
th
e output gap has been replaced with the gap between the rate of unemployment in the longer run and its actual level (using a relationship known
as
Okun’s law) to represent the rules in terms of the unemployment rate. The rules are implemented as responding to core personal consumption
ex
penditures (PCE) ination rather than to headline PCE ination because current and near-term core ination rates tend to outperform headline
ination rates as predictors of the medium-term behavior of headline ination. Box note 1 provides references for the policy rules.
R
t
T93
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + (u
t
LR
u
t
)
R
t
FD
= R
t−1
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + (u
t
LR
u
t
) − (u
t
L
R
4
u
t−4
)
R
t
T93adj
= max{R
t
T93
Z
t
,
ELB}
R
t
BAS
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + 2min{(u
t
LR
u
t
), 0}
R
t
BA
= r
t
LR
+ π
t
+ 0.5(π
t
π
LR
) + 2(u
t
LR
u
t
)
Monetary Policy Rules in the Current Environment
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 51
Unlike the other simple rules featured here, the
adjusted Taylor (1993) rule recognizes that the federal
funds rate cannot be reduced materially below the
effective lower bound (ELB). By contrast, the standard
Taylor (1993) rule prescribed policy rates that, during
the pandemic-induced recession, were far below
zero. To make up for the cumulative shortfall in policy
accommodation following a recession during which the
federal funds rate is constrained by its ELB, the adjusted
Taylor (1993) rule prescribes delaying the return of the
policy rate to the (positive) levels prescribed by the
standard Taylor (1993) rule.
Policy Rules: Limitations
As benchmarks for monetary policy, simple
policy rules have important limitations. One of these
limitations is that the simple policy rules mechanically
respond to only a small set of economic variables and
thus necessarily abstract from many of the factors that
the FOMC considers when it assesses the appropriate
setting of the policy rate. In addition, the structure of
the economy and current economic conditions differ
in important respects from those prevailing when
the simple policy rules were originally devised and
proposed. As a result, most simple policy rules do not
take into account the ELB on interest rates, which limits
the extent to which the policy rate can be lowered to
support the economy. This constraint was particularly
evident during the pandemic-driven recession, when
the lower bound on the policy rate motivated the
FOMC’s other policy actions to support the economy.
Relatedly, another limitation is that simple policy rules
do not explicitly take into account other important tools
of monetary policy, such as balance sheet policies.
Finally, simple policy rules are not forward looking
and do not allow for important risk-management
considerations, associated with uncertainty about
economic relationships and the evolution of the
economy, that factor into FOMC decisions.
Selected Policy Rules: Prescriptions
Figure B shows historical prescriptions for the federal
funds rate under the  ve simple rules considered. For
each quarterly period, the  gure reports the policy rates
prescribed by the rules, taking as given the prevailing
economic conditions and survey-based estimates of u
t
LR
and r
t
LR
at the time. All of the rules considered called for
a highly accommodative stance of monetary policy in
response to the pandemic-driven recession, followed by
(shortfalls)” rule, which responds to the unemployment
rate only when it is higher than its estimated longer-
run level.
2
All of the simple rules shown embody key
design principles of good monetary policy, including
the requirement that the policy rate should be adjusted
by enough over time to ensure a return of in ation to
the central bank’s longer-run objective and to anchor
longer-term in ation expectations at levels consistent
with that objective.
All  ve rules feature the difference between in ation
and the FOMC’s longer-run objective of 2percent. The
ve rules use the unemployment rate gap, measured
as the difference between an estimate of the rate of
unemployment in the longer run (u
t
LR
) and the current
unemployment rate; the  rst-difference rule includes
the change in the unemployment rate gap rather than
its level.
3
All but the  rst-difference rule include an
estimate of the neutral real interest rate in the longer
run (r
t
LR
).
4
pp.983–1022. A review of policy rules is provided in John
B. Taylor and John C. Williams (2011), “Simple and Robust
Rules for Monetary Policy,” in Benjamin M. Friedman and
Michael Woodford, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics,
vol.3B (Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 829–59. The same
volume of the Handbook of Monetary Economics also
discusses approaches to deriving policy rate prescriptions
other than through the use of simple rules.
2. The balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule responds
asymmetrically to unemployment rates above or below their
estimated longer-run value: When unemployment is above
that value, the policy rates are identical to those prescribed by
the balanced-approach rule, whereas when unemployment
is below that value, policy rates do not rise because of
further declines in the unemployment rate. As a result, the
prescription of the balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule has
been less restrictive than that of the balanced-approach rule
since the  rst quarter of 2022.
3. Implementations of simple rules often use the output
gap as a measure of resource slack in the economy. The rules
described in  gureA instead use the unemployment rate gap
because that gap better captures the FOMC’s statutory goal
to promote maximum employment. Movements in these
alternative measures of resource utilization tend to be highly
correlated. For more information, see the note associated with
gureA.
4. The neutral real interest rate in the longer run (
r
t
LR
) is
the level of the real federal funds rate that is expected to be
consistent, in the longer run, with maximum employment
and stable in ation. Like u
t
LR
,
r
t
LR
is determined largely by
nonmonetary factors. The  rst-difference rule shown in
gureA does not require an estimate of
r
t
LR
, a feature that is
touted by proponents of such rules as providing an element of
robustness. However, this rule has its own shortcomings. For
example, research suggests that this sort of rule often results
in greater volatility in employment and in ation than what
would be obtained under the Taylor(1993) and balanced-
approach rules.
(continued on next page)
52 PART 2: MONETARY POLICY
the federal funds rate were well above the prescriptions
observed before the pandemic, re ecting, in large
part, elevated in ation readings. Because in ation has
recently run notably below levels observed at its peak
in 2022, the policy rates prescribed by these rules have
now declined. The current prescriptions from these
rules are close to or below the current target range
for the federal funds rate, though higher than survey-
based estimates of the longer-run value of the federal
funds rate.
discussion in the Monetary Policy Report, where
z
t
cumulated
from the fourth quarter of 2020.
positive values as in ation picked up and labor market
conditions strengthened.
5
In 2022 and during the  rst
half of 2023, the prescriptions of the simple rules for
5. For the adjusted Taylor(1993) rule,
z
t
—the cumulative
sum of past deviations of the federal funds rate from the
prescriptions of the Taylor(1993) rule when that rule
prescribes setting the federal funds rate below an ELB of
12.5basis points—is positive in the third quarter of 2020,
one quarter after the prescription of the Taylor(1993) rule
falls below the ELB, through to the  rst quarter of 2022. This
approach is a slight adjustment from previous editions of this
First-dierence rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Balanced-approach rule
Federal funds rate
Balanced-approach (shortfalls) rule
18
15
12
9
6
3
+
_
0
3
6
9
Percent
2024202320222021202020192018
B. Historical federal funds rate prescriptions from simple policy rules
N
OTE
: The rules use historical values of core personal consumption expenditures ination, the unemployment rate, and, where applicable,
historical
values
of the midpoint of the target range for the federal funds rate. Quarterly projections of longer-run values for the federal funds rate,
the
unemployment
rate, and ination used in the computation of the rules’ prescriptions are interpolations to quarterly values of projections from
the
Survey
of Primary Dealers. The rules’ prescriptions are quarterly, and the federal funds rate data are the monthly average of the daily midpoint of
the
target range for the federal funds rate and extend through June 2024.
S
OURCE
: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Survey of Primary Dealers; Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Federal Reserve Economic Data
,
DFEDTARL and DFEDTARU; Federal Reserve Board sta estimates.
Adjusted Taylor (1993) rule
Monetary Policy Rules (continued)
53
In conjunction with the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) meeting held on
June11–12, 2024, meeting participants
submitted their projections of the most likely
outcomes for real gross domestic product
(GDP) growth, the unemployment rate, and
ination for each year from 2024 to 2026
and over the longer run. Each participant’s
projections were based on information
available at the time of the meeting, together
with her or his assessment of appropriate
monetary policy—including a path for the
federal funds rate and its longer-run value—
and assumptions about other factors likely
to aect economic outcomes. The longer-
run projections represent each participant’s
assessment of the value to which each variable
would be expected to converge, over time,
under appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks to the economy.
Appropriate monetary policy” is dened as
the future path of policy that each participant
deems most likely to foster outcomes for
economic activity and ination that best
satisfy his or her individual interpretation of
the statutory mandate to promote maximum
employment and price stability.
Part 3
summary of economic Projections
The following material was released after the conclusion of the June11–12, 2024, meeting of the
Federal Open Market Committee.
Table 1. Economic projections of Federal Reserve Board members and Federal Reserve Bank presidents, under their
individual assumptions of projected appropriate monetary policy, June2024
Percent
Variable
Median
1
Central tendency
2
Range
3
2024 2025 2026
Longer
run
2024 2025 2026
Longer
run
2024 2025 2026
Longer
run
Change in real GDP .....
2.1 2.0 2.0 1.8 1.9–2.3 1.8–2.2 1.8–2.1 1.7–2.0 1.4–2.7 1.5–2.5
1.7–2.5
1.6–2.5
March projection ..... 2.1 2.0 2.0 1.8 2.0–2.4 1.9–2.3 1.8–2.1 1.7–2.0 1.3–2.7 1.7–2.5 1.7–2.5 1.6–2.5
Unemployment rate .....
4.0 4.2 4.1 4.2 4.0–4.1 3.9–4.2 3.9–4.3 3.9–4.3 3.8–4.4 3.8–4.3
3.8–4.3
3.5–4.5
March projection ..... 4.0 4.1 4.0 4.1 3.9–4.1 3.9–4.2 3.9–4.3 3.8–4.3 3.8–4.5 3.7–4.3 3.7–4.3 3.5–4.3
PCE ination ..........
2.6 2.3 2.0 2.0 2.5–2.9 2.2–2.4 2.0–2.1 2.0 2.5–3.0 2.2–2.5
2.0–2.3
2.0
March projection ..... 2.4 2.2 2.0 2.0 2.3–2.7 2.1–2.2 2.0–2.1 2.0 2.2–2.9 2.0–2.5 2.0–2.3 2.0
Core PCE ination
4
.....
2.8 2.3 2.0 2.8–3.0 2.3–2.4 2.0–2.1 2.7–3.2 2.2–2.6
2.0–2.3
March projection .....
2.6 2.2 2.0 2.5–2.8 2.1–2.3 2.0–2.1
2.4–3.0 2.0–2.6
2.0–2.3
Memo: Projected
appropriate policy path
Federal funds rate .......
5.1 4.1 3.1 2.8 4.9–5.4 3.9–4.4 2.9–3.6 2.5–3.5 4.9–5.4 2.9–5.4
2.4–4.9
2.4–3.8
March projection .....
4.6 3.9 3.1 2.6 4.6–5.1 3.4–4.1 2.6–3.4 2.5–3.1 4.4–5.4 2.6–5.4
2.4–4.9
2.4–3.8
N: Projections of change in real gross domestic product (GDP) and projections for both measures of ination are percent changes from the fourth quarter of the previous year to
the fourth quarter of the year indicated. PCE ination and core PCE ination are the percentage rates of change in, respectively, the price index for personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) and the price index for PCE excluding food and energy. Projections for the unemployment rate are for the average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year
indicated. Each participant’s projections are based on his or her assessment of appropriate monetary policy. Longer-run projections represent each participant’s assessment of the rate
to which each variable would be expected to converge under appropriate monetary policy and in the absence of further shocks to the economy. The projections for the federal funds
rate are the value of the midpoint of the projected appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the projected appropriate target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the
specied calendar year or over the longer run. The March projections were made in conjunction with the meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on March19–20, 2024. One
participant did not submit longer-run projections for the change in real GDP, the unemployment rate, or the federal funds rate in conjunction with the March19–20, 2024, meeting.
1. For each period, the median is the middle projection when the projections are arranged from lowest to highest. When the number of projections is even, the median is the average
of the two middle projections.
2. The central tendency excludes the three highest and three lowest projections for each variable in each year.
3. The range for a variable in a given year includes all participants’ projections, from lowest to highest, for that variable in that year.
4. Longer-run projections for core PCE ination are not collected.
54 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
Figure 1. Medians, central tendencies, and ranges of economic projections, 2024–26 and over the longer run
N
: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1. The data for the actual values
of the variables are annual.
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Median of projections
Central tendency of projections
Range of projections
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 20212022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Percent
Unemployment rate
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 20212022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Percent
PCE inflation
Longer
run
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 20212022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Percent
Core PCE inflation
Longer
run
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 55
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
6.0
6.5
7.0
2024 2025 2026
Longer run
Percent
Figure 2. FOMC participants’ assessments of appropriate monetary policy: Midpoint of target range
or target level for the federal funds rate
N: Each shaded circle indicates the value (rounded to the nearest 1/8 percentage point) of an individual
participant’s judgment of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the federal funds rate or the appropriate
target level for the federal funds rate at the end of the specied calendar year or over the longer run.
56 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
Percent range
Number of participants
2025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
Percent range
Number of participants
2026
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.0−
1.1
1.2−
1.3
1.4−
1.5
1.6−
1.7
1.8−
1.9
2.0−
2.1
2.2−
2.3
2.4−
2.5
2.6−
2.7
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.A. Distribution of participants’ projections for the change in real GDP, 2024–26 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 57
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
2025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
2026
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
3.2−
3.3
3.4−
3.5
3.6−
3.7
3.8−
3.9
4.0−
4.1
4.2−
4.3
4.4−
4.5
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.B. Distribution of participants’ projections for the unemployment rate, 2024–26 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
58 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
Percent range
Number of participants
2025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
Percent range
Number of participants
2026
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.C. Distribution of participants’ projections for PCE ination, 2024–26 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 59
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
Percent range
Number of participants
2025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
1.7−
1.8
1.9−
2.0
2.1−
2.2
2.3−
2.4
2.5−
2.6
2.7−
2.8
2.9−
3.0
3.1−
3.2
Percent range
Number of participants
2026
Figure 3.D. Distribution of participants’ projections for core PCE ination, 2024–26
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
60 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
4.63−
4.87
4.88−
5.12
5.13−
5.37
5.38−
5.62
Percent range
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
2024
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
4.63−
4.87
4.88−
5.12
5.13−
5.37
5.38−
5.62
Percent range
Number of participants
2025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
4.63−
4.87
4.88−
5.12
5.13−
5.37
5.38−
5.62
Percent range
Number of participants
2026
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
2.13−
2.37
2.38−
2.62
2.63−
2.87
2.88−
3.12
3.13−
3.37
3.38−
3.62
3.63−
3.87
3.88−
4.12
4.13−
4.37
4.38−
4.62
4.63−
4.87
4.88−
5.12
5.13−
5.37
5.38−
5.62
Percent range
Number of participants
Longer run
Figure 3.E. Distribution of participants’ judgments of the midpoint of the appropriate target range for the
federal funds rate or the appropriate target level for the federal funds rate, 2024–26 and over the longer run
N: Denitions of variables and other explanations are in the notes to table 1.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 61
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
−3
−2
−1
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 202420252026
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
Change in real GDP
FOMC participants’ assessmentsof uncertainty and risksaround their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about GDP growth
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to GDP growth
Figure 4.A. Uncertainty and risks in projections of GDP growth
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the
percent change in real gross domestic product (GDP) from the fourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth quarter of
the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on
root mean squared errors of various private and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information
about these data is available in table 2. Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over
the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors
may not reect FOMC participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these
current assessments are summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about
their projections as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence
interval shown in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their
projections. Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the
condence interval around their projections as app
roximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in
economic projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
62 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
Unemployment rate
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessmentsof uncertainty and risksaround their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about the unemployment rate
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to the unemployment rate
Figure 4.B. Uncertainty and risks in projections of the unemployment rate
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively, of
the average civilian unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around
the median projected values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private
and government forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2.
Because current conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width
and shape of the condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC
participants’ current assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are
summarized in the lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections
as “broadly similar” to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown
in the historical fan chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections.
Likewise, participants who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence
interval around their projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic
projections, see the box “Forecast Uncertainty.”
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 63
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Median of projections
70% confidence interval
Actual
Percent
PCE inflation
Median projection and condence interval based on historical forecast errors
FOMC participants’ assessmentsof uncertainty and risksaround their economic projections
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Lower Broadly
similar
Higher
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Uncertainty about core PCE inflation
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
Weighted to
downside
Broadly
balanced
Weighted to
upside
June projections
March projections
Number of participants
Risks to core PCE inflation
Figure 4.C. Uncertainty and risks in projections of PCE ination
N: The blue and red lines in the top panel show actual values and median projected values, respectively,
of the percent change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) from the fourth quarter of
the previous year to the fourth quarter of the year indicated. The condence interval around the median projected
values is assumed to be symmetric and is based on root mean squared errors of various private and government
forecasts made over the previous 20 years; more information about these data is available in table 2. Because current
conditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the
condence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current
assessments of the uncertainty and risks around their projections; these current assessments are summarized in the
lower panels. Generally speaking, participants who judge the uncertainty about their projections as “broadly similar
to the average levels of the past 20 years would view the width of the condence interval shown in the historical fan
chart as largely consistent with their assessments of the uncertainty about their projections. Likewise, participants
who judge the risks to their projections as “broadly balanced” would view the condence interval around their
projections as approximately symmetric. For denitions of uncertainty and risks in economic projections, see the box
“Forecast Uncertainty.”
64 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
PCE inflation
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Core PCE inflation
Figure 4.D. Diusion indexes of participants’ uncertainty assessments
N: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the
uncertainty attached to your projections relative to the levels of uncertainty over the past 20 years.” Each point
in the diusion indexes represents the number of participants who responded “Higher” minus the number who
responded “Lower,” divided by the total number of participants. Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections
were submitted.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 65
Figure 4.E. Diusion indexes of participants’ risk weightings
N: For each SEP, participants provided responses to the question “Please indicate your judgment of the risk
weighting around your projections.” Each point in the diusion indexes represents the number of participants who
responded “Weighted to the Upside” minus the number who responded “Weighted to the Downside,” divided by the
total number of participants. Figure excludes March 2020 when no projections were submitted.
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20132014 2015 2016 20172018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Change in real GDP
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20132014 2015 2016 20172018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Unemployment rate
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20132014 2015 2016 20172018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
PCE inflation
−1.00
−0.75
−0.50
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 20132014 2015 2016 20172018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024
Diffusion index
Core PCE inflation
66 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 2025 2026
Midpoint of target range
Median of projections
70% confidence interval*
Actual
Percent
Federal funds rate
Figure 5. Uncertainty and risks in projections of the federal funds rate
N
: The blue and red lines are based on actual values and median projected values, respectively, of the
Co
mmittee’s target for the federal funds rate at the end of the year indicated. The actual values are the midpoint of
th
e target range; the median projected values are based on either the midpoint of the target range or the target level.
Th
e condence interval around the median projected values is based on root mean squared errors of various private
an
d government forecasts made over the previous 20 years. The condence interval is not strictly consistent with the
pr
ojections for the federal funds rate, primarily because these projections are not forecasts of the likeliest outcomes
fo
r the federal funds rate, but rather projections of participants’ individual assessments of appropriate monetary
po
licy. Still, historical forecast errors provide a broad sense of the uncertainty around the future path of the federal
fu
nds rate generated by the uncertainty about the macroeconomic variables as well as additional adjustments to
mone
tary policy that may be appropriate to oset the eects of shocks to the economy.
T
he condence interval is assumed to be symmetric except when it is truncated at zero - the bottom of the lowest
ta
rget range for the federal funds rate that has been adopted in the past by the Committee. This truncation would
not b
e intended to indicate the likelihood of the use of negative interest rates to provide additional monetary policy
ac
commodation if doing so was judged appropriate. In such situations, the Committee could also employ other tools,
in
cluding forward guidance and large-scale asset purchases, to provide additional accommodation. Because current
co
nditions may dier from those that prevailed, on average, over the previous 20 years, the width and shape of the
co
ndence interval estimated on the basis of the historical forecast errors may not reect FOMC participants’ current
assessme
nts of the uncertainty and risks around their projections.
* The condence interval is derived from forecasts of the average level of short-term interest rates in the fourth
qu
arter of the year indicated; more information about these data is available in table 2. The shaded area encompasses
less than a 70 percent condence interval if the condence interval has been truncated at zero.
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 67
Table 2. Average historical projection error ranges
Percentage points
Variable 2024 2025 2026
Change in real GDP
1
.........
± 1.7 ± 1.9 ± 2.2
Unemployment rate
1
.........
± 0.9 ± 1.4 ± 1.9
Total consumer prices
2
.......
± 1.0 ± 1.7 ± 1.4
Short-term interest rates
3
....
± 0.7 ± 1.9 ± 2.3
N: Error ranges shown are measured as plus or minus the root mean squared
error of projections for 2004 through 2023 that were released in the summer by
various private and government forecasters. As described in the box “Forecast
Uncertainty,” under certain assumptions, there is about a 70percent probability that
actual outcomes for real GDP, unemployment, consumer prices, and the federal funds
rate will be in ranges implied by the average size of projection errors made in the past.
For more information, see David Reifschneider and Peter Tulip (2017), “Gauging
the Uncertainty of the Economic Outlook Using Historical Forecasting Errors: The
Federal Reserve’s Approach,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-020
(Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February), https://
dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.020.
1. Denitions of variables are in the general note to table1.
2. Measure is the overall consumer price index, the price measure that has been
most widely used in government and private economic forecasts. Projections are
percent changes on a fourth quarter to fourth quarter basis.
3. For Federal Reserve sta forecasts, measure is the federal funds rate. For other
forecasts, measure is the rate on 3-month Treasury bills. Projection errors are calculat-
ed using average levels, in percent, in the fourth quarter.
68 PART 3: SUMMARY OF ECONOMIC PROJECTIONS
reported in table2 would imply a probability of about
70percent that actual GDP would expand within a
range of 1.3 to 4.7percent in the current year, 1.1 to
4.9percent in the second year, and 0.8 to 5.2percent
in the third year. The corresponding 70percent
con dence intervals for overall in ation would be 1.0
to 3.0percent in the current year, 0.3 to 3.7percent
in the second year, and 0.6 to 3.4percent in the third
year. Figures 4.A through 4.C illustrate these con dence
bounds in “fan charts” that are symmetric and centered
on the medians of FOMC participants’ projections for
GDP growth, the unemployment rate, and in ation.
However, in some instances, the risks around the
projections may not be symmetric. In particular, the
unemployment rate cannot be negative; furthermore,
the risks around a particular projection might be tilted
to either the upside or the downside, in which case
the corresponding fan chart would be asymmetrically
positioned around the median projection.
Because current conditions may differ from those
that prevailed, on average, over history, participants
provide judgments as to whether the uncertainty
attached to their projections of each economic variable
is greater than, smaller than, or broadly similar to
typical levels of forecast uncertainty seen in the past
20years, as presented in table2 and re ected in the
widths of the con dence intervals shown in the top
panels of  gures 4.A through 4.C. Participants’ current
assessments of the uncertainty surrounding their
projections are summarized in the bottom-left panels
The economic projections provided by the members
of the Board of Governors and the presidents of
the Federal Reserve Banks inform discussions of
monetary policy among policymakers and can aid
public understanding of the basis for policy actions.
Considerable uncertainty attends these projections,
however. The economic and statistical models and
relationships used to help produce economic forecasts
are necessarily imperfect descriptions of the real world,
and the future path of the economy can be affected
by myriad unforeseen developments and events. Thus,
in setting the stance of monetary policy, participants
consider not only what appears to be the most likely
economic outcome as embodied in their projections,
but also the range of alternative possibilities, the
likelihood of their occurring, and the potential costs to
the economy should they occur.
Table 2 summarizes the average historical accuracy
of a range of forecasts, including those reported in
past Monetary Policy Reports and those prepared
by the Federal Reserve Board’s staff in advance of
meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC). The projection error ranges shown in the
table illustrate the considerable uncertainty associated
with economic forecasts. For example, suppose a
participant projects that real gross domestic product
(GDP) and total consumer prices will rise steadily at
annual rates of, respectively, 3percent and 2percent.
If the uncertainty attending those projections is similar
to that experienced in the past and the risks around
the projections are broadly balanced, the numbers
Forecast Uncertainty
(continued)
MONETARY POLICY REPORT: JULY 2024 69
assessments of appropriate monetary policy and are
on an end-of-year basis. However, the forecast errors
should provide a sense of the uncertainty around the
future path of the federal funds rate generated by the
uncertainty about the macroeconomic variables as
well as additional adjustments to monetary policy that
would be appropriate to offset the effects of shocks to
theeconomy.
If at some point in the future the con dence interval
around the federal funds rate were to extend below
zero, it would be truncated at zero for purposes of
the fan chart shown in  gure5; zero is the bottom of
the lowest target range for the federal funds rate that
has been adopted by the Committee in the past. This
approach to the construction of the federal funds rate
fan chart would be merely a convention; it would
not have any implications for possible future policy
decisions regarding the use of negative interest rates to
provide additional monetary policy accommodation
if doing so were appropriate. In such situations, the
Committee could also employ other tools, including
forward guidance and asset purchases, to provide
additional accommodation.
While  gures 4.A through 4.C provide information
on the uncertainty around the economic projections,
gure1 provides information on the range of views
across FOMC participants. A comparison of  gure1
with  gures 4.A through 4.C shows that the dispersion
of the projections across participants is much smaller
than the average forecast errors over the past 20years.
of those  gures. Participants also provide judgments as
to whether the risks to their projections are weighted
to the upside, are weighted to the downside, or
are broadly balanced. That is, while the symmetric
historical fan charts shown in the top panels of
gures 4.A through 4.C imply that the risks to
participants’ projections are balanced, participants may
judge that there is a greater risk that a given variable
will be above rather than below their projections. These
judgments are summarized in the lower-right panels of
gures 4.A through 4.C.
As with real activity and in ation, the outlook
for the future path of the federal funds rate is subject
to considerable uncertainty. This uncertainty arises
primarily because each participant’s assessment of
the appropriate stance of monetary policy depends
importantly on the evolution of real activity and
in ation over time. If economic conditions evolve
in an unexpected manner, then assessments of the
appropriate setting of the federal funds rate would
change from that point forward. The  nal line in
table2 shows the error ranges for forecasts of short-
term interest rates. They suggest that the historical
con dence intervals associated with projections
of the federal funds rate are quite wide. It should
be noted, however, that these con dence intervals
are not strictly consistent with the projections for
the federal funds rate, as these projections are not
forecasts of the most likely quarterly outcomes but
rather are projections of participants’ individual
71
AFE advanced foreign economy
AI articial intelligence
BOJ Bank of Japan
BTFP Bank Term Funding Program
CBO Congressional Budget Oce
CES Current Employment Statistics
COVID-19 coronavirus disease 2019
CPI consumer price index
CRE commercial real estate
DI depository institution
EFFR eective federal funds rate
ELB eective lower bound
EME emerging market economy
EPOP ratio employment-to-population ratio
FOMC Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee
GDI gross domestic income
GDP gross domestic product
JOLTS Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
LFPR labor force participation rate
MBS mortgage-backed securities
MMF money market fund
NFIB National Federation of Independent Business
OER owners’ equivalent rent
ON RRP overnight reverse repurchase agreement
OPEC Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
PCE personal consumption expenditures
QCEW Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages
SEP Summary of Economic Projections
SLOOS Senior Loan Ocer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices
SOMA System Open Market Account
S&P Standard & Poor’s
VIX implied volatility for the S&P 500 index
abbreviations
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
For use at 11:00 a.m. EDT
July 5, 2024
Monetary Policy rePort
July 5, 2024