This PDF is a selection from a published volume
from the National Bureau of Economic Research
Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2001,
Volume 16
Volume Author/Editor: Ben S. Bernanke and Kenneth
Rogoff, editors
Volume Publisher: MIT Press
Volume ISBN: 0-262-02520-5
Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern02-1
Conference Date: April 20-21, 2001
Publication Date: January 2002
Title: Do We Really Know that Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation? A Monetary Alternative
Author: Robert B. Barsky, Lutz Kilian
URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11065
Robert
B.
Barsky
and
Lutz Kilian
UNIVERSITY
OF
MICHIGAN AND
NBER;
AND
UNIVERSITY OF
MICHIGAN,
EUROPEAN CENTRAL
BANK,
AND CEPR
Do
We
Really
Know
that
Oil
Caused
the
Great
Stagflation?
A
Monetary
Alternative
1.
Introduction
There
continues to be considerable
interest,
both
among policymakers
and
in
the
popular press,
in
the
origins
of
stagflation
and the
possibility
of its recurrence.
The traditional
explanation
of the
stagflation
of the
1970s found
in
intermediate textbooks is
an adverse shift
in
the
aggregate
supply
curve that lowers
output
and
raises
prices
on
impact.1
Indeed,
it
is
hard to see
in
such
a
static
framework how
a
shift
in
aggregate
demand
could have induced
anything
but a
move of
output
and
prices
in
the
same direction. This fact has lent credence to the
popular
view
that
exogenous
oil
supply
shocks
in
1973-1974
and 1978-1979 were
primarily
responsible
for
the
unique experience
of the 1970s
and
early
1980s.
For
example,
The
Economist
(November
27,
1999)
writes:
Could
the
bad
old
days
of inflation be about to return? Since OPEC
agreed
to
supply-cuts
in
March,
the
price
of crude oil has
jumped
to almost
$26
a
barrel,
up
from
less
than
$10
last December
and
its
highest
since the Gulf
war in
We
have benefited from comments
by
numerous
colleagues
at
Michigan
and
elsewhere.
We
especially
thank
Susanto
Basu,
Ben
Bernanke,
Olivier
Blanchard,
Alan
Blinder,
Mark
Gertler,
Jim
Hamilton,
Miles
Kimball,
Ken
Rogoff,
Andre
Plourde,
Matthew
Shapiro,
and
Mark
Watson. We
acknowledge
an
intellectual debt to
Larry
Summers,
who stimulated our
interest
in
the
endogeneity
of oil
prices.
Allison
Saulog
provided
able
research assistance.
Barsky
acknowledges
the
generous
financial
support
of the Sloan
Foundation. The
opin-
ions
expressed
in
this
paper
are those of the authors and do not
necessarily
reflect
views of
the
European
Central
Bank.
1.
For
example,
Abel
and
Bernanke
(1998,
p.
433)
write that-after a
sharp
increase
in
the
price
of
oil-"in the short run
the
economy
experiences stagflation,
with
both a
drop
in
output
and a
burst
in
inflation."
138
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
1991.
This
near-tripling
of oil
prices
evokes
scary
memories
of the 1973 oil
shock,
when
prices
quadrupled,
and
1979-80,
when
they
also almost
tripled.
Both
previous
shocks
resulted
in
double-digit
inflation
and
global
reces-
sion.
. .
.
Even
if
the
impact
will
be more
modest
this
time than
in
the
past,
dear
oil
will
still leave some mark.
Inflation will
be
higher
and
output
will
be
lower
than
they
would be
otherwise.
Academic
economists,
even
those who
may
not
fully agree
with
the
prevailing
view,
have done
little to
qualify
these
accounts
of
stagflation.
On
the
one
hand,
the recent
scholarly
literature has
focused on the
relationship
between
energy
prices
and
economic
activity
without
explic-
itly addressing stagflation
(see,
e.g., Hamilton,
1983, 1985, 1988, 1999;
Rotemberg
and
Woodford,
1996).
On the
other
hand,
some
authors
(e.g.,
Bohi, 1989;
Bernanke,
Gertler,
and
Watson,
1997)
have stressed not
the direct effects of oil
price
increases on
output
and
inflation,
but
possi-
ble indirect effects
arising
from the
Federal
Reserve's
response
to the
inflation
presumably
caused
by
oil
price
increases.
A
common
thread
in
the
popular press,
in
textbook
treatments,
and
in
the academic literature is that oil
price
shocks are
an
essential
part
of
the
explanation
of
stagflation.
In
contrast,
in
this
paper
we
make the case
that
the oil
price
increases were
not
nearly
as essential a
part
of
the
causal mechanism
generating
the
stagflation
of the 1970s as is often
thought.
We discuss reasons for
being skeptical
of the
importance
of
commodity
supply
shocks
in
general,
and the 1973-1974 and
1979-1980
oil
price
shocks
in
particular,
as the
primary explanation
of the
stagfla-
tion
of the 1970s.
First,
we show that there
were
dramatic and
across-
the-board
increases
in
the
prices
of industrial
commodities
in
the
early
1970s
that
preceded
the OPEC oil
price
increases. These
price
increases
do
not
appear
to be related to
commodity-specific supply
shocks,
but
are
consistent
with an
economic
boom fueled
by monetary expansion.
Sec-
ond,
there
is
reason
to doubt
that
the observed
high
and
persistent
inflation
in
the deflator
in
the
early
and late 1970s can be
explained
by
the 1973-1974
and
1979-1980 oil
price
shocks.
The
argument
that
oil
price
shocks caused
the Great
Stagflation depends
on the
claim
that
oil
price
shocks
are
inflationary. Using
a
simple
model,
we show
that
a
one-
time oil
price
increase
will
increase
gross output price
measures such
as
the
CPI,
but not
necessarily
the
price
of value
added,
as
proxied
by
the
GDP
deflator.
Indeed,
an
oil
price
increase
may
lower
the deflator.
Fur-
ther,
the
data show
that
only
two
of
the
five
major
oil
price
shocks
since
1970
have been followed
by significant changes
in
the inflation
rate of
the GDP
deflator,
though
in all
cases the CPI
inflation rate
changed
sharply
relative to the deflator.
Although
we
come
to the same conclu-
Do
We
Really
Know
that Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
139
sion as Blinder
(1979)
that oil caused
a
spike
in
consumer-price
inflation
during
the two most
stagflationary
episodes,
we
show
that oil
prices
do
not
provide
a
plausible explanation
of
the
sustained
inflation that
oc-
curred
in
the GDP deflator as
well
as in the
CPI.
If
oil
price
shocks were not
the
source of the Great
Stagflation,
what
explains
the
striking
coincidence
of
the
major
oil
price
increases
in
the
1970s
and
the
worsening
of
stagflation?
In
this
paper
we
provide
evidence
that
in
the 1970s the rise
in
oil
prices-like
that
in
other
commodity
prices-was
in
significant
measure
a
response
to macroeconomic
forces,
ultimately
driven
by
monetary
conditions. This view coheres well
with
existing
microeconomic theories about the effect of real-interest-rate
varia-
tion
and
output
movements
on
resource
prices,
and
challenges
the con-
ventional wisdom
that
major
oil
price
changes
are
largely exogenous
with
respect
to
macroeconomic variables of OECD
countries.
It is
commonly
held
that
major
oil
price
movements are
ultimately
due to
political
events
in
the
Middle East. Our
analysis
suggests that-although political
factors
were
not
entirely
absent from
the
decision-making
process
of OPEC-the
two
major
OPEC
oil
price
increases
in
the 1970s would have been far less
likely
in
the
absence of conducive macroeconomic
conditions
resulting
in
excess
demand in
the
oil
market.
The
prevailing
view that
exogenous
oil
price
shocks were the
primary
culprits
of
the Great
Stagflation
of the
1970s
goes
hand
in
hand
with
the
perception
that
monetary
factors
do
not
provide
an
adequate explanation
of
stagflation.
In
this
paper
we
develop
more
fully
a
latent
dissent to
the
conventional
view that
monetary
considerations
cannot account for
the
historical
experience
of the 1970s.2
Bruno and
Sachs
(1985)
and,
to
a
lesser
extent,
Blinder
(1979,
p.
77)
discuss
monetary
expansion
as one
impor-
tant
source of
stagflation,
but their
emphasis
is
on the
inadequacy
of
money
as an
explanation
of
the bulk
of
stagflation
and
commodity price
movements.3 In
contrast,
we
show how
in
a
stylized
dynamic
model
of
the
macroeconomy stagflation
may
arise
endogenously
in
response
to
a
sustained
monetary
expansion
even in
the
absence of
supply
shocks.
The
data
generated
by
the
model
are
broadly
consistent,
both
qualitatively
2.
References that
we
identify
with the
traditional view
include
Samuelson
(1974),
Blinder
(1979),
and
Bruno and
Sachs
(1985).
Precursors of our
alternative
explanation
of
stagfla-
tion and its
association with oil
prices
include Friedman
(1975),
Cagan
(1979),
McKinnon
(1982),
Houthakker
(1987),
and
De
Long
(1997).
3.
For
example,
Bruno and
Sachs
(1985,
p.
6)
stress
the
inadequacy
of
purely
demand-side
models of
stagflation
and
propose
that
contractionary
movements in
aggregate
supply
(such
as
oil
price
shocks)
are
needed
to
explain
the
slide into
stagflation.
Blinder
(1979,
pp.
102,
209)
states that
the
inflation
of
1973-1974
was
simply
not
a
"monetary
phenome-
non." As
the causes of
the
inflationary surge
in
the
mid-1970s,
and
also
of the
recession
that
followed,
he
identifies
"special
factors"
such as
food
price
shocks
in
1972-1974,
the
oil
price
shock
in
1973,
and
the
dismantling
of
price
controls
in
1974.
140
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
and
quantitatively,
with
the
dynamic properties
of
the actual
output
and
inflation data
for
1971-1975.
Our model
captures
the notion
that
eco-
nomic
agents
in
the 1970s
responded only
gradually
to
shifts
in
the mone-
tary policy
regime.
We
link
these shifts to the breakdown of the Bretton
Woods
system
and to
changes
in
policy
objectives.
Several indicators
of
monetary
policy
stance show
that
monetary policy
in
the
United
States,
in
particular,
exhibited
a
go-and-stop pattern
in
the 1970s.
Moreover,
episodes
of
stagflation
were associated
with
swings
in
worldwide
liquid-
ity
that
dwarf
monetary
fluctuations elsewhere
in
our
sample.
The
remainder of
the
paper
is
organized
as follows.
We
begin
with an
outline
of
the
basic facts of the
stagflation
of
the
1970s
in
Section
2.
Section
3
presents
a
monetary
explanation
of
stagflation.
In
Section
4
we
examine
the
empirical support
for this
monetary explanation,
and
in
Section
5 the
reasons for
the shifts
in
monetary
policy
stance
that
in
this view
ulti-
mately triggered
the Great
Stagflation.
In
Section
6 we discuss theoretical
and
empirical
arguments against
the
oil-supply-shock
explanation
of
stag-
flation.
Finally,
in
Sections
7 and
8 we discuss the theoretical reasons
for
a
close
relationship
between
oil
prices
and macroeconomic
variables
and
provide
evidence
that oil
prices
were
in
substantial
part
responding
to
macroeconomic
forces,
rather
than
merely
political
events
in
the
Middle
East. Additional
evidence
from the most recent
oil
price
increase
is dis-
cussed
in
Section
9. Section
10 contains the
concluding
remarks.
2. Basic
Facts
This
section
describes some
of
the salient features
of
stagflation
and of
the
evolution
of oil
prices
in the
postwar period.
The 1970s
and
early
1980s
were
an
unusual
period
by
historical
standards.
Table
1
describes
the
pattern
of
inflation
and of GDP
growth
for each
of the
NBER
business-cycle
contractions
and
expansions.
For each
phase,
we
present
data on nominal
GDP
growth
and its breakdown
into real
and
price
components.
Two
critical observations
arise
immediately
from
Table
1.
First,
with one
exception,
the
phase
average
of the
rate of
inflation
rose
steadily
from
1960.2
to
1981.2,
and
declined
over
time
thereafter.
The
exception
is that
inflation
was 2.5
percentage
points
lower
(9.56%
com-
pared
with
6.98%)
during
the 1975.1-1980.1
expansion
than
in
the
pre-
ceding
contraction
period
from 1973.4
to
1975.1.
The
second,
and most
important,
observation
is
the
appearance
of
stagflation
in
the
data.
Stagflation
appears
in
Table
1
as
an
increase
in
inflation
as
the
economy
moves
from an
expansion
to
a
contraction
phase.
There
were
three
episodes
in
which
inflation,
as
measured
by
the
growth
in
the GDP
deflator,
was near
9%
per
annum.
In
two of
these
Do We
Really
Know that Oil Caused
the
Great
Stagflation?
*
141
Table
1 REAL
GROWTH, INFLATION,
AND NOMINAL
GROWTH
IN
THE
UNITED STATES
NBER business-
State
of
the
Percent
change per
annum
NBER business-
State
of
the
cycle
dates
economy
Real
growth Inflation
Nominal
growth
1960.2-1961.1
Contraction
-1.03
+1.22
+0.19
1961.1-1969.4
Expansion
+4.64
+2.59 +7.23
1969.4-1970.4
Contraction
-0.49
+4.93
+4.44
1970.4-1973.4
Expansion
+4.34
+5.22 +9.56
1973.4-1975.1 Contraction
-1.76 +9.56
+7.80
1975.1-1980.1
Expansion
+3.80
+6.98 +10.78
1980.1-1980.2 Contraction
-3.46 +8.88 +5.42
1980.2-1981.2
Expansion
+0.62
+9.11 +9.73
1981.2-1982.4 Contraction
-1.34
+6.07 +4.73
1982.4-1990.2
Expansion
+4.07 +3.29
+7.36
1990.2-1991.1 Contraction
-1.27
+4.12
+2.85
1991.1-2001.1
Expansion
+3.46
+2.10 +5.56
Source: Based on
quarterly chain-weighted
GDP
and
GDP
deflator data from
DRI
for 1960.1-2001.1. The
business-cycle
dates
are based on the NBER
dating.
The last
expansion
is
incomplete.
three
episodes
real
output
contracted
sharply
(i.e.,
in
1973.4-1975.1
and
1980.1-1980.2),
and
in
the
third it
grew
very
slowly
(i.e.,
in
1980.2-
1981.2).
Indeed,
in
all but
one contraction
(i.e.,
with
the
exception
of the
second Volcker recession
in
1981.2-1982.4),
average
inflation
during
the
contraction was
higher
than
during
the
previous
expansion.
Figure
1
shows the
percentage change
in
the nominal
price
of
oil since
March
1971,
when
the
U.S. became
dependent
on oil
imports
from the
Middle East
(see
Section
8).
Episodes
of so-called oil shocks are
indicated
by
vertical bars
and
include the 1973-1974 OPEC oil
price
increase
after
the October
war
of
1973,
the 1979-1980
price
increases
following
the
Iranian
revolution
in
late 1978 and the
outbreak of the
Iran-Iraq
war
in
late
1980,
the
collapse
of OPEC
and
of the oil
price
in
early
1986,
the
oil
price spike
following
the invasion of Kuwait
in
1990,
and
the most
recent
period
of
OPEC
price management
since March 1999.
The
coincidence of
two
large
increases
in
the
price
of
imported
oil
in
the
1970s
and
two
periods
of
strong stagflation
has
spurred
interest
in
a
causal link
from
"oil
shocks" to
stagflation,
although
casual
inspection
of
Figure
1
and
Table
1
suggests
that
this
link
is
far
less
apparent
for other
episodes.
The
decade of
the 1970s also
coincided
with
fundamental
changes
in
monetary policy
and in
attitudes
toward
inflation,
as the Bretton
Woods
system
collapsed.
Monetary policy
became much
more
expansionary
on
average
and
more
unstable
in
the
1970s
than in
the
1960s. One
reason
that
these
developments
are
often
considered less
important
in
discus-
142
*
BARSKY
&
KILIAN
Figure
1
PERCENTAGE CHANGE IN NOMINAL
PRICE
OF OIL
50-
40-
30-
20-
10-
0
-10-
-20-
-30
-
-40-
-50
Source:
The
underlying
oil
price
series is
refiner's
acquisition
cost of
imported
crude
oil
(DRI
code:
EEPRPI)
for
January
1974 to
July
2000. We use the U.S.
producer
price
index for oil
(DRI
code:
PW561)
and
the
composite
index for refiner's
acquisition
cost of
imported
and domestic
crude oil
(DRI
code:
EEPRPC)
to
extend
the data
back
to March
1971.
sions
of
stagflation
is the
perception
that
monetary
factors are
unlikely
to
generate stagflation
of sufficient
magnitude
(see
Blinder,
1979).
As
we
will
show
in
Section
3,
this
perception
is incorrect. Another reason for
the
popularity
of
the
oil-price-shock
explanation
of
stagflation
is
the
fact that
both
the
phenomenon
of
stagflation
and that
of
major
upheavals
in
the oil
market
occurred for the
first
time
in
the
1970s,
although
Table 1
suggests
that
stagflation predates
the
first
oil
price
shock
of late
1973.
Although
oil
price
shocks continue
to
occur,
there
have been
no
major episodes
of
stagflation
since the 1970s.
In
this
paper
we
question
the
extent
to
which
we
really
know
that oil
price
shocks
played
a
central role
in
generating
stagflation.
We
will
show
that a
monetary
approach
can
explain
not
only
the
evolution of
the
Great
Stagflation,
but
also
that of
the
price
of
oil
during
that
period.
We
will
present
a
coherent
explanation
for the
almost simultaneous occurrence
I
Do We
Really
Know
that Oil
Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
143
of
high
oil
prices
and
stagflation
in
the
1970s,
and
for the absence
of
such
a
relationship
in
subsequent
periods.
3.
Purely Monetary Explanation
of
the
Great
Stagflation of
the 1970s
In
this
section,
we
describe
a
stylized
monetary
model
that
illustrates
how
substantial
stagflation may
arise even
in
the
absence of
supply
shocks
when
inflation is
inherently
"sluggish"
or
persistent,
and
particularly
when
the
monetary
authority
also
follows
a
rule
that
prescribes
a
sharp
contractionary
response
to increases in inflation.
In
this model
as well
as
in
the
data,
inflation
continues to rise after
output
has
reached
its
maxi-
mum and
peaks
only
with a
long
delay. Impulse-response
estimates
from
structural
vector
autoregressions
(VARs)
indicate
that a
monetary expan-
sion is
followed
by
a
prolonged
rise not
just
in
the
price
level,
but in
inflation,
a
phenomenon
that
Nelson
(1998)
calls
"sluggish
inflation."
Likewise,
it is
widely
accepted
that
output
exhibits
a
hump-shaped
re-
sponse
to
a
monetary
expansion.
An
important empirical
regularity
in
VAR
studies is that the
response
of
output
peaks
after about
4-8
quarters,
followed
by
a
peak
in
inflation
after about 9-13
quarters
(e.g.,
Bernanke
and
Gertler, 1995;
Christiano,
Eichenbaum,
and
Evans, 1996;
Leeper,
1997).
Thus,
the
peak
response
of
output
occurs about
one
year
before the
inflation
response
reaches its maximum.4
What
is the
source
of
sluggish
inflation?
Sluggish
inflation is
not
a
property
of
the most
commonly
used
monetary
business-cycle
models
(Taylor,
1979;
Rotemberg,
1982,1996;
Calvo,
1983).
In
these
models,
both
inflation
and
output jump
immediately
to their maximal
levels,
followed
by
a
monotonic decline.
Although
recent
research has
demonstrated the
inconsistency
of the
Taylor-Calvo-Rotemberg
model with
the
stylized
facts about
inflation
and
output dynamics
(see
Nelson,
1998),
it
has
not
provided
a
generally
appealing
alternative.
In
this
paper,
we take the
position
that
sluggish
inflation
reflects
the fact that
agents
learn
only
gradually
about shifts in
monetary
policy
(see
Sargent,
1998).
Agents
are
always
processing
new
information,
but
especially
so in a
period
follow-
ing regime
changes
as
dramatic as
the
changes
that
occurred
in
the
1970s.
Given the
low and
stable
inflation
rates of the
1960s,
it
is
plausible
that
agents
were slow
to
revise their
inflationary expectations
when
confronted
with an
unprecedented
monetary
expansion
under Arthur
Burns in
the
early
1970s.
This
interpretation
appears
even
more
plausi-
4.
Nelson
(1998)
presents
estimates that
the
response
of inflation
to a
monetary
innovation
peaks
after 13
quarters,
but
his VAR
only
includes
money
and
the
price
level.
144
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
ble
considering
the financial
turmoil and
uncertainty
associated
with
the
gradual
disappearance
of
the Bretton Woods
regime. Similarly, expecta-
tions
of
inflation
were slow to
adjust
in the
early
1980s,
when Paul
Volcker launched
a new
monetary policy regime resulting
in
much lower
inflation.
We
propose
a
stylized
model that
formalizes
the notion
that in times of
major
shifts
in
monetary policy
inflation is
likely
to
be
particularly slug-
gish.
Consider
a
population
consisting
of two
types
of
firms.
A
fraction
(,t
of
"sleepy"
firms is not convinced
that
a
shift
in
monetary
policy
has
taken
place
and
sets
its
output price
(pt)
at
last
period's
level
adjusted
for
last
period's
inflation
rate. The
remaining
fraction
1
-
w,
of "awake"
firms
is
aware of the
regime
change
and sets its
output
price
at
P?t
=
Pt
+
l3(Yt
-
yf),
where 8
is a
constant,
Yt
the
log
of real
GDP,
and
yf
the
log
of
potential
real GDP.
As time
goes
by,
the fraction
of
agents
that
is
un-
aware of
the
regime
change
evolves
according
to
wt
=
e-At.
These consider-
ations
imply
an
aggregate
price-setting equation
of
the form
Pt =
wtP
+ (1
- t)pt
=
e-'t
(2pt_1
-
Pt2)
+ (1
-
e-t)
[p,
+
(t
- yf)].
(la)
This
price
equation
is the source of
the inflation
persistence
in our
model.
Equation
(la)
is
very
much
in
the
spirit
of
Irving
Fisher's
(1906)
reference
to
an
earlier
monetary expansion
that
"caught
merchants
nap-
ping."
Its
motivation is closer
to that
of the Lucas
supply
schedule
(see
Lucas,
1972,
1973)
than
to that of
sticky-price
models.
Agents
are
always
free
to
adjust prices
without
paying
"menu costs."
Moreover,
by
the
choice
of
appropriate
time-varying
weights
wt,
our
inflation
equation
may
allow
for the
fact that
agents
learn more
quickly
about
some
shifts
in
policy
than about others.
For
expository
purposes,
however,
we
postu-
late
that these
weights
evolve
exogenously.
The second
building
block of
the model
is the
equation
Ayt
=
Amt
-
Apt,
(lb)
where
Apt
is
the
inflation
rate
(which
we
will
associate
with the rate of
change
of the GDP
deflator)
and
Amt
is the
rate of nominal
money
growth.
This
relationship
is
a
very
simple
money
demand
equation.
We
complete
the
model
by
adding
a
policy
reaction function.
We
posit
that
the Fed
cannot
observe
the current
level
of the
GDP
deflator.
We
postulate
a
reaction
function
under which
the
Fed
targets
the rate of
inflation.
Let
"-ew
be
the
steady-state
rate of inflation
consistent
with
the
initial
increase
in
money growth.
That
rate
may
be
interpreted
as
the
level of
inflation
that the Fed
is
willing
to tolerate
under
the new
expan-
Do We
Really
Know that
Oil Caused
the
Great
Stagflation?
?
145
sionary regime.
The Fed
responds
to
periods
of inflation
in excess of
,new
by decelerating
monetary growth by
some small fraction
y
of last
pe-
riod's excess
inflation rate:
A2mt
=
-y
Ap,_
I(Apt_1
>
fnw)
+
At,,
(Ic)
where
I(-)
denotes
the indicator
function,
and
Et
represents
the
increase
in
the
money
growth
rate
associated
with the Fed's more
expansionary
policy
after
the
collapse
of
the
Bretton Woods
system.
Note
that,
holding
constant other demand shifters
and
given
the
sluggishness
of
inflation,
this
money growth
rule
may
be translated into a more
conventional
interest-rate rule
by
inverting
an
IS curve
and
observing
that
high
real
balances
imply
low real interest rates.
In
addition,
by
way
of
compari-
son,
we
will
explore
a
much
simpler
model
in which
money supply
growth
follows
a
sequence
of
exogenous policy
shocks
Et
and
in
which
there
is no
policy
feedback:
A2mt
=
AEt. (lc')
The
model is
parametrized
as follows.
We
postulate
that
in
steady
state
output
grows
at
3%
per
annum.
Moreover,
prices
grow
at a
steady
rate of 3%
per
annum
prior
to the
monetary expansion.
We
follow
Kim-
ball
(1995)
in
setting
3
=
0.06. The
single
most
important parameter
in
the
model is
A,
which
determines the fraction of
agents
"awake." We
choose
A
to
give
our
model the
best
possible
chance to
match the
timing
of
business-cycle
peaks
and
troughs
in
the U.S. inflation and
output-gap
data
for 1971-1975.
The
resulting
value of
A
=
0.08
implies
that after
two
years
slightly
less
than
half of
economic
agents
will
have
adopted
the
new
pricing
rule.
This rate of
transition
may
appear
slow,
but-as we
will
discuss
below-is consistent with
evidence from other
sources as
well.5
Finally,
for
the model with
policy
feedback,
we
choose
y
=
0.05 for
illustrative
purposes.
This value
means
that, if,
for
example,
the inflation
rate last
quarter
is
2%,
the Fed will
decelerate
monetary growth
by
0.1
percentage point
(one-tenth
of
the initial
monetary expansion).
Our
choice of
y
ensures
that
the inflation
rate
returns to the initial
steady-
5.
In
our
model
it
takes about
two
years
for half
of the
agents
to
adopt
the
new
pricing
rule.
This
rate of
adaptation
may appear
very
slow,
but it
is not unlike
those found in
many
other
economic
contexts. For
example,
data
from
the literature on
the
entry
of lower-
priced
generics
into
the
market for
branded
drugs
show that
after two
years
only
about
half
of
the
consumers have
switched
to the
lower-priced generic
drug
(see
Griliches and
Cockburn, 1994;
Berndt,
Cockburn,
and
Griliches,
1996).
If
it
takes so
long
for
agents
to
adapt
in
such
a
simple problem,
it
does
not
appear implausible
that it
would
take
at
least
as
long
in
our
context.
146
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
state rate
in
the
long
run.
This choice is consistent with the
interpreta-
tion
that the Fed-rather than
discovering
a solution to
the
dynamic
inconsistency
problem-found
its
way
back to low inflation
using
a
mechanical
rule
(see
Sargent,
1998).
Given this choice
of
parameters,
consider
a
one-time shock
to
E,
in
period
5,
representing
a
4-percentage-point-per-annum
increase
in
money growth, beginning
in
steady
state.
Figure
2a
shows
that
a
mone-
tary expansion
produces
the
essential features discussed above.
The
model
economy displays stagflation, sluggish
inflation,
and a
hump-
shaped response
of
output
to a
monetary expansion.
Most
importantly,
the
output gap
rises
with
the inflation rate
initially,
with
output peak-
ing
about two
years
after the
shock,
whereas inflation
peaks only
after
three
years
(close
to
the 13
quarters reported by
Nelson,
1998).
Between
these
two
peaks
output
and inflation move
in
opposite
directions,
re-
sulting
in
stagflation.
We now address
the extent to which
this
stylized monetary
model
can
explain
the
business-cycle
peaks
and
troughs
over the 1971-1975
period.
Consider
the
following
thought experiment:
Since
we know
that
a
strong
monetary expansion
took
place starting
in
the
early
1970s,
we-somewhat
arbitrarily-propose
to date the
monetary expansion
in
the
model so
that
period
5
in
Figure
2a
corresponds
to
1971.1. This
thought experiment
allows
us
tentatively
to
compare
the behavior
of
output
and inflation
in
the model
in
response
to a
monetary
expansion
with the actual
U.S.
data.
Given
this
interpretation,
the
monetary
model
predicts
a
peak
in
GDP
in
1972.4-1973.1,
followed
by
a
peak
in
deflator
inflation
in 1974.2
(shortly
after the
OPEC oil
price
increase)
and
a
trough
in
GDP
in 1975.2. Note
that,
although
the
NBER
dates
the
end
of the
expansion
in late
1973,
Hodrick
and Prescott
(HP)
detrended
GDP
peaks
in
1973.1,
at
the same
time as
the
gap peaks
in
our model.
Thus,
the
timing
of the
cycle
that would
have
been
induced
by
the
monetary
expansion
in
1971.1
(after
allowing
for the
Fed's reaction
to
the
changes
in inflation set
in
motion
by
this
initial
expansion)
is re-
markably
close
to the
timing
of
the actual business
cycle.
Note that
this
coincidence
of
the
timing
of
the
business-cycle
peaks
and
troughs
does
not
occur
by
construction,
but arises
endogenously
given
our
choice
of
parameters.
Continuing
with
the
same
analogy,
we now
focus
on the
magnitude
of
the
output
and
price
movements
induced
by
the
monetary
expansion.
Of
particular
interest
is
the
ability
of the
model
to
match
the
phase
averages
for 1971.1-1973.3
and for
1973.4-1975.1.
We find that
the
aver-
age per
annum
inflation
rates
for
1971.1-1973.3
and
1973.4-1975.1
in
the
model
are
fairly
close
to
the U.S.
data.
The model
predicts
average
inflation rates
of
5.1%
and
10.4%
per
annum,
respectively,
compared
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil
Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
147
Figure
2 IMPLICATIONS OF A PURELY MONETARY
MODEL OF
STAGFLATION:
(a)
WITH POLICY
FEEDBACK;
(b)
WITHOUT
POLICY
FEEDBACK
0.08
0.06-
,,"
',\
0.04-
0.02-
0.00--
\
-0.02-
-0.04
-
-0.06
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
(a)
0.08
0.06-
,,
x\
'"\
0.04-
0.02-
"
/
,
/zi
'
0.00
-----
-0.02-
-0.04
5 10 15
20 25 30
35
40
(b)
Notes: Solid
curves:
quarterly
inflation
rate.
Dashed curves:
output gap.
Models described in
text.
Responses
to
a
permanent
1-percentage-point
increase
in
money
growth
in
period
5.
148
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
with
4.9%
and
9.6%
in
the
data.
Thus,
both
the model and
the
data
show
a
substantial
increase
in
inflation
during
the
recession.
Similarly,
for
GDP
growth
the model fit
is not
far
off. The
model
predicts
4.8%
growth
per
annum for
1971.1-1973.3
compared
with 5.2% in
the
data,
and
-3.0% for
1973.4-1975.1
compared
with -1.8% in the data.
We
conclude
that the
quantitative
implications
of
this model are not
far
off
from
the U.S.
data,
especially
considering
that we
completely
ab-
stracted
from other
macroeconomic determinants. Also note
that the
Fed
inflation
target
in
our model
economy
becomes
binding
in
early
1973,
consistent
with the
empirical
evidence of
a
monetary
tightening
in
early
1973
in
response
to actual and
incipient
inflation
(see
Section
4).
This
example
illustrates
that
go-stop monetary
policy
alone could
have
generated
a
large
recession
in
1974-1975,
even
in
the
absence
of
supply
shocks.
A
question
of
particular
interest is how essential
the
endogenous pol-
icy
response
of the
Fed
is
for the
generation
of
stagflation.
Some authors
have
argued
that the
1974
recession
may
be
understood
as
a
conse-
quence
of
the Fed's
policy response
to
inflationary expectations
(e.g.,
Bohi,
1989; Barnanke,
Gertler,
and
Watson,
1997).
Figure
2b shows that
policy
reaction
is an
important,
but
by
no
means
essential,
element of
the
genesis
of
stagflation.
In
fact,
a
qualitatively
similar
stagflationary
episode
would
have
occurred
under the
alternative
policy
rule
(lc')
with-
out
any
policy
feedback. The
main
effect of
adding policy
feedback
(y
>
0)
is
to increase
the
amplitude
of
output
fluctuations
and
to
dampen
variations
in
inflation.
In
the model
without
policy
feedback,
holding
fixed
the
remaining
parameters,
the
timing
of the
cycle
induced
by
the
monetary
regime
change
is
roughly
similar
to
that
in
Figure
2a.
Figure
2b shows
a
peak
in
GDP
in
1972.4-1973.1,
followed
by
a
peak
in inflation
in
1974.3
and
a
trough
in
GDP
in
1975.2.
The model
without
policy
feedback
predicts
average
annual
inflation rates
of 5.1%
and 12.0% for
1971.1-1973.3
and
1973.4-1975.1,
respectively,
compared
with
4.9% and 9.6%
in the
U.S.
data.
Average
output growth
per
annum over
these same
subperiods
is
4.9%
and
-2.0%,
respectively,
in the
model,
compared
with 5.2%
and
-1.8%
in the data.
The
policy
shift
associated
with
the
monetary
tightening
under Paul
Volcker
in
late
1980
provides
a
second
example
of the
basic mechanism
underlying
our
stylized
model.
Using
the
same
parametrization
as
for
Figure
2b,
our model
predicts
a
sharp
recession
in
late
1982,
followed
by
an
output
boom
in
1985
and
an
output
trough
in
early
1987. This
pattern
closely
mirrors
the movements
of HP-filtered
actual
output.
At the
same
time,
inflation
in
the model falls
sharply,
reaching
its
trough
in
1984,
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation?
*
149
followed
by
a
peak
in
1986. Actual inflation in the GDP
deflator
followed
a
qualitatively
similar,
but
delayed pattern.
It
reached
its
trough
in
1986,
followed
by
a
peak
in
mid-1988.
Thus,
the
response
of
actual inflation
in
this
episode
is even more
sluggish
than
that
in
the model.
4
Supportfor
the
Monetary
Explanation
of
Stagflation
In
this
section,
we
will
present
four
additional
pieces
of evidence
in
support
of
the
monetary
explanation
of
stagflation.
First,
we
will
exam-
ine several indicators
of
monetary
policy
stance to show
that
monetary
policy
in
the
United
States,
in
particular,
exhibited
a
go-and-stop pattern
in the
1970s.
Second,
we
will
show
that
episodes
of
"stagflation"
were
associated
with
swings
in
world-wide
liquidity
which dwarf
monetary
fluctuations elsewhere
in
our
sample.
Third,
we
will
show
that
there
were
dramatic and
across-the-board increases
in
the
prices
of
industrial
commodities
in
the
early
1970s
that
preceded
the OPEC
oil
price
in-
creases.
These
price
increases
do
not
appear
to be
related to
commodity-
specific supply
shocks,
but are
consistent
with
an
economic
boom
fueled
by monetary
expansion. Finally,
we
will
document
that
in
early
1973
a
broad
range
of
business-cycle
indicators started to
predict
a
recession,
nine
months before the
first OPEC
oil
crisis,
but
immediately
after
the
Fed
began
to
tighten
monetary policy.
4.1
EVIDENCE OF
GO-AND-STOP MONETARY
POLICY
IN THE
UNITED STATES
Our
evidence is based on two
measures of the total
stance of
monetary
policy
for this
period-one
based
on the behavior
of the Federal
Funds
rate,
the
other
based on
narrative evidence
(see
Bernanke
and
Mihov,
1998;
Boschen and
Mills,
1995).
The
Bernanke-Mihov index of
the over-
all
monetary
policy
stance shows
a
strongly
expansionary
stance
from
mid-1970
to the
end
of 1972
(see
Figure
3).
Interestingly,
the
Boschen-
Mills
index,
which is
based on
narrative
evidence,
is
mostly
neutral
during
this
period
with
the
exception
of
1970-1971.
The reason
is
that
the
Boschen-Mills
index is based
on
policy
pronouncements
as
opposed
to
policy
actions.
Quite
simply,
the Fed's
pronouncements
in
this
period
were
uninformative
at
best and
probably
misleading.
Both
the
Boschen-Mills index and
the
Bernanke-Mihov
index
show
a
sharp
tightening
of
monetary
policy
in
early
1973.
The
Boschen-Mills
indicator,
on
a
scale from
+2
(very
expansionary)
to
-2
(very
tight),
moves
from neutral at
the
end of 1972
to
-1
for
the first
three
months of
1973. It
then
spends
the
next 6
months at
-2,
followed
by
two
months at
-1,
ending
the
year
in
neutral.
Further,
the
Bernanke-Mihov
index
shows a
sharp
and
prolonged
contraction
in
monetary
policy
by
early
1973
150
*
BARSKY
& KILIAN
Figure
3
INDICATOR OF OVERALL
MONETARY POLICY
STANCE,
JANUARY
1966
TO
DECEMBER 1988
0.
1968
1970 1972
1974 1976 1978
Source:
Courtesy
of B. Bernanke and
I.
Mihov.
(see
Figure
3).6
As noted
by
Boschen and Mills
(1995),
this contraction
was
an
explicit
response
to
rising
inflation. It
occurred
long
before the distur-
bances
in
the oil market
in
late 1973 and
provides
an
alternative
explana-
tion
of
the recession
in
early
1974.7 The
contractionary
response
of the
Fed
in 1973 to
the
inflationary pressures
set
in
motion
by
earlier Fed
policy
is
a
key
element
of
our
monetary explanation
of
stagflation.8
Note
that the
observed increase
in
inflation
in
1973 is understated
as a result of
price
controls,
and
the observed
increase
in
1974 is overstated
due
to
the
lifting
of the
price
controls
(see
Blinder,
1979).
6. The
downturn in the
Bernanke-Mihov index in
1973 reflects a
sharp
rise
in
the Federal
Funds rate.
Interestingly,
as
Figure
5d
shows,
although
the real interest
rate
rose,
it
remained
negative throughout
1974.
Thus,
the
contractionary
effect of the
monetary
tightening
must have worked
partly through
other channels such as
the
effect of
high
nominal
interest rates on
housing
starts in
the
presence
of
disintermediation
due
to
interest-rate
ceilings.
7.
This
interpretation
is
consistent
with
Bernanke,
Gertler,
and
Watson's
(1997)
conclusion
that
the Fed in 1973 was
responding
to the
inflationary
signal
in
non-oil
commodity
prices,
not to the oil
price
increase as is
commonly
believed.
8.
There
is
no Romer date for
1973,
despite
the clear evidence of a
shift
in
policy
toward a
contractionary
stance.
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation?
?
151
As the
U.S.
economy
slid
into recession
in
1974,
the Fed
again
re-
versed course to
ward off
an
even
deeper
recession.
Indicators show
a
renewed
monetary expansion
that lasted
into
the late 1970s. The
Ber-
nanke-Mihov index indicates
that
monetary policy
was
strongly
expan-
sionary
from late 1974
into 1977
(see
Figure
3).
This
expansion
was
not
initially
reflected
in
high
inflation,
in line with our earlier discussion
of
sluggish
inflation.
Boschen and Mills record
a
similar,
if
somewhat
briefer,
expansion.
Around
1978,
the
monetary
stance turned
slightly
contractionary, becoming strongly
contractionary
in late 1979 and
early
1980 under Paul
Volcker,
as inflation continues
to worsen. Once
again,
the
monetary policy
stance
provides
an alternative
explanation
for the
genesis
of
stagflation.
4.2
WORLDWIDE CHANGES
IN
LIQUIDITY
The
changes
in
monetary policy
indicators
in the 1970s
in
the
United
States,
and indeed
in
many
other OECD
countries,
were
accompanied
by unusually large swings
in
global liquidity.
One indicator of
global
liquidity
is world
money growth.
We focus on world
(rather
than
simply
U.S.)
monetary growth,
both because
the
prices
of
oil
and
non-oil com-
modities are
substantially
determined
in
world
markets,
and
because-
despite
its
origins
in
the U.S.-the
monetary expansion
in
the
early
1970s was
amplified
by
the
workings
of the international
monetary sys-
tem,
as
foreign
central banks
attempted
to stabilize
exchange
rates
in
the
1968-1973
period.
The
counterpart
of the
foreign-exchange
intervention
in
support
of the dollar was the
paid
creation of domestic credit
in
all of
the
large
economies
(see
McKinnon,
1982;
Bruno and
Sachs, 1985;
Genberg
and
Swoboda,
1993).
Figure
4a and b
show
a
suitably updated
data set for
GNP-weighted
world
money growth
and
inflation,
as defined
by
McKinnon
(1982).
There is evidence
of
a
sharp
increase
in
money growth
in
1971-1972 and
in
1977-1978
preceding
the two
primary stagflationary episodes
in
Table
1.
The increase
in
world
money
growth
is followed
by
a substantial
rise
in
world
price
inflation
in
1973-1974 and in
1979-1980
(see
Figure
4b).
The
data also
show
a
third
major
increase
in
world
money-supply
growth
in
1985-1986.
This does
not
pose
a
problem
for
the
monetary
explanation
of
stagflation,
because
1985-1986 is
fundamentally
different
from
1973-1974 and
1979-1980.
The coincidence of
substantial
money
growth
and low
world
inflation
constitutes
a
partial
rebuilding
of real
balances
following
the restoration
of the
commitment to
low
inflation.9
9.
This is
precisely
the standard
interpretation
of the
patterns
of
inflation and
money
growth
that
have
been
documented for the
period
following
the
monetary
reform that
ended the
German
hyperinflation
(see
Barro, 1987,
p.
206,
Table
8.1).
152
-
BARSKY
& KILIAN
Figure
4
MEASURES OF WORLD
LIQUIDITY
(a)
World
Money
Growth: Ten
Industrial
Countries
(b)
World Price Inflation: Ten Industrial Countries
15
20
15
...I
10
l
U)
0
-5
1960
1965
197
1975
1980
1985
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 19
(c)
Growth
of
World
Real Balances:
Ten
Industrial Countries
15
10
5
20
-10
-15-
1960
1965 1970
1975
1980
1985
Source:
Inflation
and
money
are
GNP-weighted
growth
rates
per
annum
as
defined
by
McKinnon
(1982,
pp.
322),
based
on
IFS
data
for
1960.1-1989.4.
We
now
turn
to
the
United
States,
where the
monetary expansions
of
the
1970s
originated.
Figure
5
shows
that
U.S.
liquidity
followed a
pat-
tern
similar
to
that
of other
industrial countries.
Figure
5a
shows
two
large
spikes
in
money growth
in
1971-1972
and in
1975-1977
that
pre-
ceded
two
episodes
of
unusually
high
inflation
in
the
GDP
deflator
in
1974 and
in
1980
(see
Figure
5b)
and
that
coincided
with
two
episodes
of
significantly
negative
growth
in
real
money
balances
in
1973-1974
and
1978-1980
(see
Figure
5c).
Figure
5c
also
shows
evidence
of
a
rebuilding
of
real
balances
(and
possibly
of the
financial
deregulation)
after
1980.
Additional
evidence
of
excess
liquidity
in
the
1970s is
provided
by
the
behavior of
the U.S.
real
interest
rate.
Figure
5d shows
that 1972-1976
and
1976-1980
were
periods
of
abnormally
low
real interest
rates,
followed
by
unusually high
real interest
rates
in
1981-1986.
This
pattern
is
consistent
with the
view that
the excess
money
growth
in
the
early
and
mid-1970s
depressed
ex
ante
real interest
rates
via a
liquidity
effect
and
further
depressed
ex
post
interest
rates
by
causing
unanticipated
inflation.
The
evidence
in
Figure
5d
also is consistent
with
the
view
that the Fed
in
the
1970s followed
an interest-rate
rule
that was
more tolerant
of
inflation
than would
have been
consistent
with a
Taylor
rule
as estimated
over
the
Do We
Really
Know
that Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
153
Figure
5 MEASURES
OF
U.S.
LIQUIDITY
(a)
U.S.
Money
Growth
(b)
U.S.
Deflator Inflation
10
03
ao
cL
8
6
4
2
1
a)
0
a)
0-
OE
n
. .
1960 1965
1970
(c)
Growth
of U.S.
Real
Balances
.. ..
10
5
0
-5
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985
1975 1980
1985
(d)
U.S. Real Interest Rate
I I I I
-
5-
0
^vH
^
.A.
i
1960 1965 1970
1975 1980 1985
Source:
(a)
Based on
DRI
series FM2.
(b)
Based on DRI series GDPD.
(c)
Based on DRI
series
FM2 and
PRXHS.
(d)
Based on DRI series FYGM3 and PRXHS.
Volcker-Greenspan period
(see
Clarida, Gall,
and
Gertler,
2000).
Finally,
the
timing
in
Figure
5d contradicts the view that oil
shocks were
responsi-
ble
for the low ex
post
real interest rates. Real
interest rates were
negative
during
1973,
after the evidence of
excess
money growth,
but
well before
the two
major
oil
price
increases.
In
fact,
the 1973-1974 and
1979-1980 oil
price
increases were followed
by
a
rise
in
ex
post
real interest
rates.
4.3
MOVEMENTS IN
OTHER
INDUSTRIAL COMMODITY
PRICES
An
important
additional
piece
of evidence that
has received
insufficient
attention in
recent
research is
the
sharp
and
across-the-board
increase
in
industrial
commodity prices
that
preceded
the
increase
in
oil
prices
in
1973-1974
(see
Figure
6).
These
increases occurred
as
early
as
1972,
well
before
the
October
War,
and
are too
broad-based
to
reflect
supply
shocks
in
individual
markets.
They
are,
however,
consistent
with
a
picture
of
increased
demand
driven
by
the
sharp
increase
in
global
liquidity
docu-
mented in
Figure
3.
There is
significant
evidence that
poor
harvests
caused food
prices
to
soar
in
the
early
1970s
(see
Blinder,
1979).
Our data
set
deliberately
rc
a)
03
03
c)
0-
,
I
LA
-
154
*
BARSKY
&
KILIAN
Figure
6
NOMINAL PRICE INDEXES
FOR CRUDE OIL AND FOR
INDUSTRIAL
COMMODITIES, JANUARY
1948 TO
JULY
2000
-
1
-
I I I
I
I
I
I
I
I
I
1950
1955
1960 1965 1970
1975
1980
1985
1990 1995
2000
Source: All
data are
logged
and de-meaned.
The
commodity
price
index
excludes oil
and
food. The index
shown is an index
for industrial
commodity
prices
(DRI
code:
PSCMAT).
Virtually
identical
plots
are
obtained
using
an
index for sensitive materials
(DRI
code:
PSM99Q).
The oil
price
series is defined as
in
Figure
1.
excludes
food-related commodities.
Instead,
we focus on
industrial
raw
materials.
Commodities such as
lumber,
scrap
metal,
and
pulp
and
pa-
per,
for
which
there
is no
evidence
of
supply
shocks,
recorded
rapid
price
increases in the
early
1970s
(see
National
Commission on
Supplies
and
Shortages,
1976).
For
example,
the
price
of
scrap
metal
nearly
dou-
bled
between October
1972
and
October
1973,
and
continued to rise until
early
1974,
to
nearly
four times its initial level. The
price
of lumber
almost
doubled between
1971 and
1974,
as
did
the
price
of wood
pulp.
These
commodity price
data
paint
a
picture
of
rapidly rising
demand for
all
commodities
in
the
early
1970s.
It
is
interesting
to
note
that a
similar
increase
did
not
occur
in
oil
prices
until
late 1973.
Similarly,
the
1979 increase
in
oil
prices
was
preceded by
a
boom
in
other
commodity prices,
consistent with
the evidence of mone-
tary
expansion, although
the
commodity price
increase is of lesser
magni-
tude.
In
fact,
a
striking empirical regularity
of the data in
Figure
6 is that
Do We
Really
Know that Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
155
increases
in
other
industrial
commodity prices
tended to
precede
in-
creases
in
oil
prices
over the 1972-1985 OPEC
period
(and
similarly
for
decreases).
This fact is
evident for
example
in
1972,
1978, 1980,
1983,
and
1984.
A
natural
question
is
how
the
monetary
explanation
of
stagflation
proposed
here
can be reconciled
with
the
delayed response
of oil
prices
relative
to
other
industrial commodities.
The
explanation
appears
to
be
that,
unlike other
commodity
transactions,
most
crude-oil
purchases
until the
early
1980s did
not
take
place
in
spot
markets,
but at
long-term
contractual
prices.
The
sluggish
adjustment
of these contractual
prices
in
response
to demand conditions
in
commodity
markets
tended
to
delay
the
response
of
the
oil
price
relative to
the
price
of more
freely
traded
commodities,
until
the
spot
market
largely
replaced
traditional oil
con-
tracts
in
the
early
1980s.
4.4
BUSINESS-CYCLE
INDICATORS
Finally,
the
monetary
explanation
is consistent
with
evidence
of an
im-
pending
recession
long
before
the first oil
price
shock in October
1973-
January
1974,
but
shortly
after the
monetary tightening
of
early
1973.
Both
the
expected
conditions
component
of
the index of consumer confidence
and the
index
of
leading
indicators
peaked
in
January
1973,
when mone-
tary
policy
switched to
a
contractionary
stance
in
response
to
rising
infla-
tion. Consumer durables started
falling
relative to trend
in
early
1973,
as
would be
expected
in
response
to
a
monetary tightening.
Similar
declines
can be observed
in
the numbers of
housing
starts and
motor-vehicle
pur-
chases.
Figure
7
suggests
that
both consumers
and
economic forecasters
were
expecting
a recession
many
months before
the
October
1973 war and
the
subsequent
oil
embargo,
and that this
expectation
was not driven
by
concerns over OPEC. The
decline
in
the
index of
leading
indicators contin-
ued
throughout
1974.
Although
we cannot tell to
what
extent
the
fall
in
the index of
leading
economic indicators after
September
1973
can be
attributed to oil as
opposed
to
money,
a full
two-thirds of the fall in
consumer
confidence
in
1973-1974
was
completed
prior
to the
oil
date.
5.
What
Explains
the Initial
Monetary
Expansion
of
the 1970s?
The
U.S.
economy
moved from an
extended
period
of
low
and
stable
inflation at the
beginning
of
the
1960s
to
one
of
high
and
variable
infla-
tion
by
the
end
of
the
decade.
The
underlying
cause of the
shift towards
higher
inflation
was the
gradual
reduction in the
United
States's commit-
ment to the twin
goals
of low and
stable
inflation
and
the
avoidance
of
"excessive"
balance-of-payments
deficits.
In
the late
1960s,
the central
156
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
Figure
7
BUSINESS-CYCLE INDICATORS WITH OPEC
I
OIL DATES:
(a)
EXPECTED
CONDITIONS
COMPONENT OF
CONSUMER
CONFIDENCE;
(b)
REAL
DURABLES
CONSUMPTION
(PERCENT
DEVIATION FROM
HP-TREND); (c)
INDEX OF
LEADING
ECONOMIC INDICATORS
(a)
1975 1975.5 1976
(b)
Do We
Really
Know that Oil Caused the
Great
Stagflation?
?
157
Figure
7
CONTINUED
8 6
I
i
I i I 1
I
84
-
82-
-
80-
78-
76
74-
72-
1971.5
1972
1972.5 1973 1973.5 1974 1974.5 1975 1975.5 1976
(c)
Sources:
(a)
Survey
of
Consumers,
University
of
Michigan;
(b), (c)
based on DRI data.
bank's commitment to
these traditional
goals
was
increasingly
diluted
by
the
additional
goal
of
maintaining
high employment.10
The dilution of
the commitment
to
controlling
inflation and
balance-of-payments
defi-
cits was behind both the
weakening
(and
ultimately
the
destruction)
of
the Bretton
Woods
system
and
the initiation of
expectations
of
high
and
persistent
inflation in
the
late
1960s. The rise in
inflationary expectations
in turn
triggered
an
inflation
trap by raising
the
cost
of
subsequent
disinflations
(also
see Christiano and
Gust,
2000).11
These
inflationary
pressures
were reinforced
by
two serious errors of economic
analysis
on
10.
This
change
in
focus
can
be traced
ultimately
to the Great
Depression
and
the
percep-
tion that
tight
monetary policy
had been
responsible
for
excessively
high unemploy-
ment
during
the Great
Depression.
The
rise
in
social
and
political
commitment to
full
employment
was
furthered
by
an
intellectual belief
in
the more or less
permanent
exploitability
of the
Phillips
curve
(see
Samuelson
and
Solow,
1960).
The refusal to rein
in social
spending
or to allow a
sharp
rise in
interest
rates,
as the Vietnam
war
ex-
panded
in
the late
1960s,
reflected the
change
in
priorities.
11. What
makes the
expectations-trap hypothesis plausible
is evidence that
by
1971 the Fed
indeed
perceived
a shift in the
public's expectations
of inflation. As Christiano
and
Gust
(2000)
note,
Arthur
Burns
was
concerned
about
expectations
of inflation as
early
as December 1970.
By
1971,
he
perceived
a shift in
inflationary expectation
due to the
steady
rise
of
consumer-price
inflation since
1965,
well before the
commodity supply
shocks,
the
oil
shocks,
and the
monetary expansion
of the
early
1970s
(see
Burns,
1978,
pp.
118,
126).
158
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
the
part
of the
Federal
Reserve:
first,
a
miscalculation of full
employment
in
the wake of the
productivity
slowdown and of structural
changes
in
the
labor
market
(see
Orphanides,
2000;
Orphanides
et
al.,
1999);12
and,
second,
an
increased
tendency
to attribute
inflation to
"special
factors"
rather than the
underlying monetary
environment.13
A
third
element
was the
exploitation
of
the
newly
unconstrained
policy
environment in
the service of electoral
politics.14
A
number
of
authors
(see
McKinnon, 1982;
DeLong,
1997;
Mundell,
2000)
have
suggested
that the
collapse
of the
gold exchange
standard
associated
with
Bretton
Woods
played
a
key
causal
role
in
the
creation of
the
inflationary monetary
environment of the
1970s.15
Although
it is
widely accepted
that
the eventual
collapse
of the Bretton
Woods
system
was
inevitable due to fundamental
structural flaws
(see
the
papers
in
Bordo
and
Eichengreen,
1993),
the
timing
of its demise was influenced
by
the same factors
that also
launched the
initial
wave
of
inflation
in
the
mid-1960s to
1970.
The
collapse
was
triggered
by
an
excess
supply
of
U.S. dollars
resulting
both from the
expansion
of the U.S.
monetary
base
and
a
reduction
of the demand for dollars abroad driven
by
the
expecta-
12.
Orphanides
(2000)
documents
that
the measurements of real
output
available to the
Fed
following
both the 1970 and
1974
recessions were
substantially
lower
than
the
output
data
now available.
At
the same
time,
official estimates
of
potential
real
output
were
in
retrospect
far
too
optimistic, resulting
in
excessively high
estimates
of the
output gap,
defined
as the shortfall of actual
output
relative to
potential.
Drawing
on
evidence from
simulated
real-time
Taylor
rules and on the Fed minutes
and
the recollec-
tions of the
policymakers
involved,
Orphanides
concludes
that
the increase
in
the
natural rate
of
unemployment
and the
productivity
slowdown
in
the
late
1960s and
1970s were
two
major
factors
in
explaining
the
inflationary
outcomes
of
the
period.
13.
For
example,
Hetzel
(1998)
makes
the
case
that then chairman Arthur Burns adhered
to
a
special-factors
theory
of inflation
which attributed
increases
in
inflation
to a
variety
of
special
circumstances
ranging
from unions and
large corporations
to
government
defi-
cits and
finally
food
and
oil
price
increases.
Hetzel
argues
that Bums
systematically
discounted
any
direct effects from increases
in the
money
supply
on inflation
and did
not
appear
to
be
overly
concerned
about the extent of the
monetary expansion
in the
early
1970s.
For a similar
view
see Christiano
and Gust
(2000).
14.
For
example,
DeLong
(1997)
stresses
that the inflation of the
early
1970s
was fueled in
addition
by
Arthur
Bums's efforts
to
facilitate
Nixon's
reelection
through expansionary
monetary policy.
Christiano
and Gust's
(2000)
narrative
evidence that
Burns was
not
intimidated
by
Nixon
does not contradict this
interpretation,
because
Burns's conserva-
tive economic
views were
closer to Nixon's than
to
those
of his
Democratic
opponent.
15.
The
temporal
coincidence
is
indeed
an
impressive
one. The
breakdown
of
the
Bretton
Woods
system
was foreshadowed
by
the introduction
in 1968 of
a
two-tiered
system
of
convertibility
with
significantly higher
prices
for
private
than for
official
transactions,
in
response
to the
declining private-sector
confidence
in
the
dollar
peg.
It became
official when
President Nixon
announced
the
"closing
of
the
gold
window"-ending
the
convertibility
of dollars into
gold
in
August
1971.
The relaxation of the convertibil-
ity
constraint coincided
with a dramatic
increase
in
U.S.
monetary growth
(see
Figure
3a)
and
a
period
of
expansionary monetary policy
between mid-1970
and late
1972,
as
indicated
by
the Bernanke-Mihov
index.
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil
Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
159
tion of
an
incipient
depreciation
of the dollar
(see
McKinnon,
1982;
Bruno
and
Sachs, 1985;
Genberg
and
Swoboda,
1993).
In
this
sense,
the
breakdown
of the Bretton Woods
system
was
endogenous.
At
the
same
time,
awareness
of
the loss
of
prestige
that
would
accom-
pany
suspension
of
convertibility
continued
until the
end
to serve as a
partial
commitment device
that
contributed
significant
restraint
against
higher
inflation
(see
Bordo
and
Kydland,
1996).
By completely
removing
this
constraint,
the
1971
closing
of the
gold
window
permitted
a
second
round of
monetary expansion starting
from
an
already high
base.
In
this
sense,
the
breakdown
of the Bretton Woods
system
may
also be
consid-
ered one of the causes of
the
monetary expansion.
As stressed
by
Kydland
and
Prescott
(1977)
and Barro
and
Gordon
(1983),
the
incentive
of the central bank to stimulate
employment
in
the short
run tends
to
produce
an
excessively high
rate of inflation
in
the
absence
of
a
suitable
commitment mechanism. Not
until the
development
of new
commit-
ment
devices
in
the form of a
lexicographic
intellectual
commitment
to
price stability
and
the cult of the conservative central banker at the
beginning
of the 1980s
(see
Rogoff,
1985)
was the
prevailing
inflation
reduced to
the levels of the
early
1960s. The
reason
that the
1970s are
different from the
preceding
and the
following
decade
thus
is the
ab-
sence
of
effective constraints on
monetary policy.
As the
global
monetary
system
underwent dramatic
changes
in
the
early
1970s,
both
central
bankers
and
private
agents slowly
had to
adapt
to the new rules of
the
game.
The
monetary
expansion
was
not immedi-
ately
understood
by
market
participants
and
required
a
process
of learn-
ing
that
is reflected
in
the
sluggish
adjustment
of
inflation
in
the model
of Section 3.
Furthermore,
the
Fed
itself
was
operating
in a
new mone-
tary
environment without
the traditional
constraints
and
needed to learn
about
the
consequences
of its own
actions. There was
a
widespread
sense
that
"the rules of
economics are
not
working
in
quite
the
way they
used
to"
(see
Burns,
1978,
p.
118).
This
element of
trial
and
error is
important
in
understanding
the
go-and-stop
nature of
monetary policy
in
this
period
and
helps
to
explain why
the
generally
inflationary
stance
of
monetary
policy
was
punctuated
by
occasional
sharp
contractions.
It
also
helps
to answer the
question why
the
Fed did
not learn
from its
mistakes after the first
episode
of
go-and-stop
monetary
policy
ended
in
1974.
The data
for
U.S.
monetary
growth
in
Figure
5a
show
a
renewed
expansion
that
coincided with
a
period
from
late
1974
until
1977,
in
which
policy
indicators
signal
a
second
"go" phase
for
monetary
policy.
Part of
the
explanation
may
be
that,
at
the
time,
the
Fed
attributed at
least
part
of the
observed
stagflation
to oil
supply
shocks and
other
special
factors.
More
importantly,
the Fed
lacked
a
political
mandate
for
160
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
serious reform. The lack of
commitment to
maintaining
low inflation
could
only
be overcome
by
the
experience
of
double-digit
inflation
in
the
late
1970s.16
6.
How
Convincing
is the
Aggregate-Supply-Shock
Explanation of
Stagflation?
The view that the historical
pattern
of
stagflation
can be accounted for
by
the effects of
money
does
not
preclude
the
possibility
that oil shocks
played
a
major
role
in
generating
the
stagflation
either
directly
or
indi-
rectly
by inducing
a
policy response.
In
this
section,
we will
demonstrate
that the
supply-shock explanation
of
stagflation
is
less
convincing
than
commonly thought.
6.1 IS
THE
TEXTBOOK
ANALYSIS OF AGGREGATE SUPPLY
SHOCKS
CONVINCING?
GROSS
VS.
VALUE-ADDED CONCEPTS
OF OUTPUT AND PRICE
The
textbook view is
that oil
price
shocks
are
of
necessity inflationary.
The
only
question
is
the
magnitude
of the
inflationary
effect. As we
will
show,
however,
this
claim
is
unambiguously
true
only
for the
price
of
gross
output,
not for
the
price
of
value
added.
The
following
coun-
terexample
demonstrates
that
oil
price
shocks
may
in
fact
have a defla-
tionary
effect
on the
price
of value
added,
even as
they
raise the
price
of
gross
output.
Suppose
gross output
Q
is
given
by
the
production
function
Y
=
Q[V(K,
L,
x),
O],
where
x
denotes
a
technology
disturbance,
O
denotes the
quan-
tity
of
a
foreign
commodity import
("oil"),
and
V(K,
L,
x)
is domestic
value
added. As
is
standard,
we assume
separability
between
O
and the other
factors
in
order
to ensure
the existence
of a value-added
production
func-
tion. As
is
immediately
clear,
a
decline
in
O,
under
separability,
is not
a
shock
to the
production
function for value
added-the
ability
to
produce
domestic
output
is
unchanged.
It follows
that oil
shocks
cannot
play
the
role of
a
technology
shock
in a
standard
real-business-cycle
model
(i.e.,
they
do not alter
value
added,
holding
constant
capital
and
labor
input),
although
they
do
lower the
quantity
of
gross output.
Following
Rotemberg
and
Woodford
(1996),
we consider
an
economy
in
which
symmetric
firms
produce
final
output
using
the
gross
output
production
function
Yt
=
Q(Vt(Lt),Ot),
(2)
16.
Sargent
(1998)
provides
a
detailed account
of
competing
explanations
of the transition
back to
a low-inflation
regime.
Do
We
Really
Know that
Oil
Caused the
Great
Stagflation?
*
161
where
Ot
is
the
quantity
of
foreign
oil
used
in
production,
Q
is
homoge-
neous of
degree
one
in
its
arguments,
and
Vt
is
a
function of labor
hours
and
capital.
The
capital
stock
is assumed to
be
fixed,
ensuring
concavity
of
Vt. Let
gross
output
be the
numeraire.
Vt,
the
value added
associated
with
capital
and
labor,
should
be
thought
of
as real
GDP.
Nominal
GDP
is
given by
PtYt
-
P?
Ot,
where
P?
is the
price
of
imported
oil.
Further
postulate
that
the demand
for
money
balances is
proportional
to nominal
gross
output:
M
=
kPY,
(3)
where
Pt
is the
price
of
gross
output.
Thus,
nominal
gross
output
is
determined
by
the
money
stock alone.
Now
suppose
that
labor
is
supplied
inelastically.
Further
suppose
that
all
markets
are
perfectly
competitive.
Logarithmically
differentiating
(2)
and
(3)
with
respect
to
P?,
we obtain
AY=-
E
vAPo,
(4)
1
-
so
so
APt
=
1
APO
(5)
1
-
So
where
A
denotes
percent
changes,
so
is the
cost
share
of oil
in
gross
output,
and
o,
v
is
the
elasticity
of
substitution
between
value
added and
oil.
This
means that an
increase
in
the
price
of
imported
oil will
tend
to
lower
the
quantity
of
gross
output
and
raise the
price
of
gross
output.
Next
consider
the
deflator
for
value
added,
defined as
the
ratio
of
nominal
to real
value
added:
PV
=
PY-POt
t
PtYt(l-So)
t
(6)
Vt(Lt)
Vt(Lt)
Again
consider an
increase
in
the
price
of
imported
oil.
Clearly,
under
our
assumptions
the
denominator of
(6)
does
not
vary
with
the
price
of
oil.
The
numerator, however,
will
fall,
since
by
(3)
nominal
gross
output
is
determined
solely by
the
money
stock,
and
the
cost
share
of
imported
oil in
gross
output
is
expected
to
rise
in
response
to an
oil
price
increase
(see
Gordon,
1984;
Rotemberg
and
Woodford,
1996).
Thus,
the oil
price
shock
lowers
the
price
of
value
added,
even
as it
raises
the
price
of
gross
output.
162
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
This
stylized
example
illustrates
that
the
aggregate-supply-shock
analysis
of oil
price
changes
is
questionable.
Whereas
aggregate-supply
shocks
in
the textbook
model are
stagflationary
for
value
added,
oil
price
increases
may
actually
be
deflationary.
In
this
sense,
in
our
example
they
are
closer
in
spirit
to
aggregate
demand
shocks than
to
aggregate supply
shocks.17 How
realistic is this
counterexample?
Clearly,
to
overturn our
benchmark result
would
require
a
sufficiently
sharp
fall in
real
value
added
in
response
to
an
oil
price
shock,
without a
commensurate
drop
in
the
money
stock. We now
discuss
several
mechanisms
by
which oil
price
shocks
may
in
principle generate
a fall in
the
quantity
of
value
added.
Since oil
shocks
are
not
productivity
shocks,
the
key
to
establishing
that oil
price
shocks affect value
added
then must be
showing
that
labor
and
capital inputs
change
in
response
to an oil
price
shock.18 One
model
that
establishes
such
a
link is the
sectoral-shifts
model
of
Hamilton
(1988).
A
related channel has
been
discussed
by
Bernanke
(1983),
who
shows
in
a
partial-equilibrium
model that oil
price
shocks
will
tend to
lower
value
added,
because firms
will
postpone
investment
as
they
at-
tempt
to
find
out
whether the
increase
in
the
price
of
oil is
transitory
or
permanent.
Even
if
we
accept
the view that
an
oil
price
shock
lowers real value
added, however,
there is no
presumption
that
this shock
will
be
stagfla-
tionary.
First,
consider the case of
a
fixed
money
supply.
It
is not
enough
to show that value added falls
in
response
to an oil
price
shock.
For
the
price
of value added
actually
to rise when the
money supply
is
fixed,
value added must fall
by
more than
the
numerator
in
(6).
More
generally,
the
money supply
will
not be fixed.
In
that
case,
the direction of the
change
in
the
price
deflator also
depends
on
the Fed's
reaction
to the
fall
in
value added. The
optimal
Fed behavior would be
to contract
the
money supply
in
response
to the fall
in
value added
(see
King
and
Goodfriend,
1997).
We have
already
shown
that indeed the Fed was
conducting contractionary monetary policy
at
the
time of the oil
price
17. An
additional
factor that reinforces
the
aggregate-demand-shock interpretation
is
the
transfer
of
purchasing
power
from the United States
to
OPEC
(see
Bruno
and
Sachs,
1985).
18.
Under
imperfect
competition,
as
noted
Rotemberg
and Woodford
(1996),
an
oil
price
shock does result
in
a rise
in
the
supply
price
for
all
levels of
value added. This increase
occurs
because
firms
apply
the
markup
to
all
cost
components, including
imported
oil,
not
just
to
capital
and
labor. The
magnitude
of this
effect,
however,
is
likely
to be small
for reasonable
markup
ratios,
unless we allow
in
addition
for substantial
changes
in
the
markup
over time.
The latter
possibility
is discussed
by Rotemberg
and Woodford
(1996),
who show
that
a
model
involving implicit
collusion between
oligopolists
in
the
goods
market can
yield output responses
to
an
oil
price
shock
that are
quantitatively
important.
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil Caused
the
Great
Stagflation?
*
163
shocks. Whether this
monetary
contraction
would have been
enough
to
stabilize the
price
level,
as value
added
fell,
is an
empirical question.
Either
way, monetary policy plays
a
key
role
in
determining
the effect
of
oil
price
shocks
on inflation.
This discussion
shows
that
the
implications
of
an
oil
price
shock
are
unambiguous
only
for
the
price
of
gross output
measures
such as
the
consumer
price
index
(CPI).
Although
one could construct other
exam-
ples,
in
which
oil
price
shocks are
inflationary
for the
price
of
value
added
(measured
by
the GDP
deflator),
there
is no
presumption
that in
general they
are.
The direction and
strength
of
the
effect of oil
price
shocks
on
the GDP
deflator
is
an
empirical question.
6.2
DO OIL
PRICE
SHOCKS
MOVE
THE
GDP
DEFLATOR?
The
preceding
discussion
stressed
the
important
distinction between
infla-
tion
in
prices
of
gross
output
(such
as the
CPI)
and of
value
added
(such
as
the GDP
deflator).
In
this
section,
we
provide
some
empirical
evidence
about the
timing
and
relative
magnitude
of the
changes
in
the
GDP defla-
tor
and
the CPI
inflation rates
during
major
oil
price changes
that sheds
light
on
the relative
contributions of oil and
money
to the
inflation
in
the
GDP
deflator observed
in
the
1970s.
Figure
8
shows the annualized infla-
tion rates
for
gross
output prices
(as
measured
by
the
CPI)
and
the
price
of
value
added
(as
measured
by
the GDP
deflator)
for
the
United States
in
the
period
1960.1-2000.2.19 We
use the
PRXHS
index
of
consumer
prices,
which
excludes
housing
and
shelter.
Despite
the
obvious
differences
in
the content and
construction of
these two
indices,
there
is
strong
comovement
in
the
long
run.
For our
purposes,
it
will be
of
interest to
focus on
five
major
episodes:
the two
major
oil
prices
increases of 1973-
1974 and
1979-1980,
the
major drop
in
oil
prices
in
early
1986,
the invasion
of Kuwait
in
1990-1991,
and
the recent oil
price
volatility
since
1997.
Our
first
observation is that
Figure
8
shows an
unusual
discrepancy
between
the
deflator and CPI
inflation
rates
during
each
of the five
episodes
of
interest.
CPI
inflation rose
sharply
relative to deflator infla-
tion
between 1972
and 1974
and
again
in
1979 and
early
1980.
This result
is not
surprising,
as
these
periods
were
characterized
by major
fluctua-
tions
in
world
commodity
markets.
To
the
extent that
prices
of
imported
19. Our
theoretical
counterexample
maintained
the
implicit
assumption
that
no oil is
pro-
duced
domestically.
This is not
an
issue for
most OECD
countries
in
the
1970s
with
the
exception
of
the
United States.
There
are reasons to doubt
the
quantitative
importance
of this
channel,
however,
even for
the United
States,
given
the small
share of
domestic
oil
in
U.S.
GDP.
It
may
be shown
that the
inflation rate
for
the non-oil
component
of
U.S. GDP will
be
lower than
the
inflation rate
for the total
GDP
deflator,
but that the
overall
results are
qualitatively
similar under
realistic
assumptions.
164
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
Figure
8
QUARTERLY
U.S.
INFLATION RATES FOR
1960.1-2000.2
18-
..
-CPI1
-
Deflator
14-
12-
10-
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
1965
1970I
I I I
8
195
2000
1970 1975
1980 1985
1990 1995
2000
Source: All data are
growth
rates
per
annum. All data
are taken from
the
DRI
database. We use
PRXHS
(consumer
prices excluding
shelter)
as the
CPI
measure,
and GDPD as the
implicit
GDP deflator.
oil and other
imported
commodities
enter the CPI but not
the
deflator,
our
earlier discussion
suggests
that we
should
expect
to
see
a
wedge
between
inflation
in the
CPI and
in
the
deflator.
Moreover,
it
is
well
known that
especially
price-sensitive
items such as
food
(whether
im-
ported
or
not)
have
higher weights
in
the
CPI than in
the
deflator,
adding
to
the
discrepancy. Similarly,
the
1986 and
1990-1991
episodes
are characterized
by
a
differential
response
of CPI
and
deflator inflation
rates.
The
same
differential
response
occurs
after
1997,
as
oil
prices
first
plummet
and
then
experience
a
dramatic reversal in
1999
and
2000.
Our second
observation is that
during
the 1970s
increases
in
CPI
infla-
tion
rates
tended
to
precede
increases
in the
inflation rate of
the
deflator.
Although
CPI
inflation reached
double-digit
rates
in
early
1974,
the bulk
of the
inflation
in
the deflator
only
occurred from
mid-1974 to
1975.
Similarly,
although
CPI
inflation
rates
rose
sharply
in
1979-1980,
the
bulk of
the increase in the
inflation
in
the deflator
occurred
only
in
mid-
16
-
Do We
Really
Know that Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation?
*
165
1980-1981.20
One
possible explanation
for
this
difference
in
timing
is
that
value added fell for
the
reasons described
by
Hamilton
(1988),
and
mone-
tary
policy
did not contract
enough
to
prevent
an
increase
in
the
price
level.
An
alternative
explanation
is
that
the
delayed
inflation
was
caused
by
the
earlier
monetary
expansion.
The latter
explanation
seems
more
plausible,
given
that
of
the five oil
episodes
in
our
sample period only
the
1973-1974 and 1979-1980
episodes
are
associated
with
large changes
in
the deflator inflation
rate-but
none
of
the other
major
oil
price
changes.
Of
particular
interest
is the
1986 fall in the oil
price following
the
collapse
of
OPEC. The fact that
the
sharp
deflation
in the CPI
in
1986
was
accompanied by only
a
minor reduction
in
deflator
inflation casts
doubt
on the view that
oil
was
responsible
for
deflator inflation
in
earlier
peri-
ods.
Similarly,
during
1990-1991 deflator inflation
changed
little
by
his-
torical
standards.
Further evidence
against
the
oil-supply-shock
view of
stagflation
is
provided
by
the events of 1997-2000.
During
this
period
oil
prices
first fell
sharply
to
an
all-time low and then
rose
sharply
to
heights
not seen since
1979-1980. As
expected,
these oil
prices
swings
are
re-
flected in
considerable
swings
in
CPI inflation rates
in
Figure
8,
but
they
have
little,
if
any,
effect
on deflator inflation.
Figure
8
illustrates that the
high
correlation of oil
price
shocks
and
subsequent
increases
in
deflator inflation
that
we observe
in
the 1970s
breaks down
in
other
periods.
We
interpret
this
evidence as
supportive
of the view that
this
relationship
is
largely
coincidental. The
monetary
explanation
of
stagflation provides
a
coherent account of
why
the 1970s
were
different,
and of what
generated
the
observed
dramatic
increases
in
deflator
inflation.
Thus,
the evidence
in
Figure
8
provides
further
support
for
the
monetary explanation
of
the
stagflation
of the
1970s.
7.
The
Relationship of
Oil Prices and
the
Macroeconomy: Theory
In
Section
6,
we
showed
that,
although
an oil
supply
shock
may
well
cause
a
recession,
its
effect on the GDP
deflator
(as
opposed
to
the
CPI)
is
ambiguous
in
theory
and
appears
to be
small in
practice.
Neverthe-
less,
casual
observers
continue to
be
impressed
with
the
coincidence
of
sharp
oil
price
increases
in
the
1970s and
the
worsening
of
stagflation.
In
20.
The
unusually
long delay
in
the
response
of
inflation to
money
can be
explained
by
the
presence
of
wage
and
price
controls
throughout
1973 and in
early
1974. These
controls
effectively
suppressed
inflation
rates. The
lifting
of
price
controls in
April
1974
coin-
cided with a
sharp
increase in
deflator
(as
well as
CPI)
inflation
(see
Blinder,
1979).
The
fact
that
the
increase
in
deflator inflation
rates in
1980-1981
was
smaller
(if
more
sustained)
than in
1974-1975 also is
consistent with
this
interpretation.
166
*
BARSKY
&
KILIAN
fact,
some observers seem
puzzled by
the
absence
of a
close
link
be-
tween oil
prices
and
stagflation
at
other times
(for
example,
The Econo-
mist,
1999).
In
this
section,
we will
argue
that the
almost simultaneous occurrence
of
sharp
increases
in
oil
prices
and
worsening stagflation
in
the 1970s was
indeed
no
coincidence.
Unlike
conventional accounts
based
on
exoge-
nous
oil
supply
shocks, however,
we
stress
that
oil
prices
were
respond-
ing
in
substantial measure to
conditions
in
the oil
market,
which
in
turn
were
greatly
affected
by
macroeconomic
conditions
(and
ultimately by
the
monetary
stance).
Put
differently,
we
reject
the
common notion
of a
sim-
ple
one-way
causal
link from
oil
prices
to the
macroeconomy
and
allow
for
the
possibility
that oil
prices
(like
other
commodity
prices
traded
in inter-
national
markets)
tend to
respond
to
macroeconomic forces.
The view that
oil
prices
contain
an
important endogenous
component
is not
as radical
as
it
may
seem.
In
fact,
the
observed
behavior of oil
and
non-oil
commodity prices
coheres
well with
economic
theory
about re-
source
prices
(see
Heal
and
Chichilnisky,
1991).
Commodity
prices
rise
in
response
to
high output
and
low real
interest
rates. Our
emphasis
on
the
endogenous response
of oil
prices
to
global
(and
in
particular
U.S.)
macroeconomic
conditions does not
rule out that
political
events
played
a
role
in the
timing
of
the
observed oil
price
increases,
but it
suggests
that
politically
motivated
increases
in the oil
price
would have been
far
less
likely
in
the absence of
a conducive economic environment
created
by monetary policy.
The
starting
point
for
our
analysis
is the classic resource
extraction
model of
Hotelling
(1931).
Applying
this model to
oil,
marginal
revenue
(MR)
net of
marginal
cost
of extraction
(MCE)
must rise
at the
rate
of
interest,
so
that
well
owners are on
the
margin
indifferent
between
extracting
oil
today
and
extracting
oil tomorrow.
Further,
the transver-
sality
condition
says
that,
in
the
limit,
no oil should
be
wasted. Combin-
ing
these
two
conditions,
for the
special
case
of zero
marginal
extraction
cost,
we
have
Dtil
(pil
ert,
Yt)
soil
(7)
t=0 _
+
where
poil
=
initial relative
price
of
oil,
Soil
=
fixed stock
of
oil,
r
=
real
interest
rate,
Yt
=
aggregate
output
in
period
t,
and
DQil
=
demand for
oil
in
period
t. Under
perfect competition,
equation
(7)
implies
that the
price
of oil
rises
at the rate of interest
until the
fixed stock
of oil is exhausted.
For
the more
general
case
of
positive
marginal
extraction costs
the first-
Do We
Really
Know
that Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
167
order condition
for
profit
maximization
is that MR
- MCE must
rise
at
rate
r:
MR-
MCE
=r.
(8)
MR
-
MCE
Note
that
the
required
rise over time
in MR -
MCE
may
be
accom-
plished by
a fall in
MCE as
new
capacity
is
developed,
even without
a
rise
in
the oil
price
(see
Holland,
1998).
Indeed,
this feature of the
model
allows for the oil
price
to fall
over
time.
This
simple
model
implies
several channels
through
which
monetary
policy
affects oil
prices.
First,
a one-time
permanent drop
in r
raises
the
initial
price,
and
implies
slower
price
growth
thereafter.
Second,
a
rise
in
aggregate
real income
shifts out the flow demand for oil.
Since the oil is
consumed
more
rapidly,
the
price
of oil must
rise to clear the
market.
The
magnitude
of these
effects
depends
on the
size
and duration
of the
effects of
monetary
policy
on
r
and
y.
Money
is not
normally
thought
to
permanently
change
r
or
y.
Thus,
the
magnitude
of
price
adjustment
in
response
to
monetary policy
in
this model
may
not be
large.
Much
stronger
effects on
the
price
of oil
may
occur once
capacity
is
modeled
explicitly.
If
marginal
costs are
increasing
in
the extraction
rate
(which-in
the
limit-may
be
interpreted
as
a
capacity
constraint),
a
shift
in
demand
for
oil
in
this model
may generate
sharp
increases
in
the
price
of oil
as well
as
overshooting
of the oil
price.21
In
the
limit,
if
installed
capacity
is
instantaneously
fixed,
the
price
of oil at a
moment
in
time is
determined
entirely
by
demand.
A
rise
in
real
GDP,
or
a
decrease
in
the
real
interest
rate,
shifts the
demand
curve for oil
to the
right,
sharply raising
the
market
price
of
the
given
stock of oil.
However,
this
price
increase
carries
the seeds
of its
own
destruction.
If
we
began
in
steady
state,
the
shadow
price
of
capacity
will
now
exceed its
replacement
cost at
current
levels of
capacity.
If
the
price
remains
high
for extended
periods,
investment
in
drilling
and
distribution
capacity
takes
place,
and in
the
long
run
the
price
of
oil
will
fall.
In
addition to
the
direct
effects of real
income and
real
interest rates
on
the demand
for
oil,
there
is also an
additional
effect
that
links
the stabil-
21.
Mabro
(1998,
p.
16)
notes
that
".. .
exhaustibility
as an
ultimate
outcome
in
a
universal
context
is not
very
relevant
[for
the oil
price]
because
the time
horizon
involved,
even
today,
is far
too
long
to have a
noticeable
impact.
What
matters is the
relationship
of
current
productive
capacity
to current
demand
and of
planned
investments
in
capacity
to
future demand.
It is
not
the
geo-physical
scarcity
of
oil that
poses problems
.
. .
but
the
capacity
issued at
any given point
in
time."
168
*
BARSKY
& KILIAN
ity
of
oil cartels to
macroeconomic forces.
Standard
theoretical models of
cartels such as
Rotemberg
and
Saloner
(1986)
and
Green
and
Porter
(1984)
predict
that cartel
stability
will
be
strengthened by
low real inter-
est
rates. Producers trade off the
immediate
gains
from
abandoning
the
cartel
against
the
present
value of
the cartel
rents
forgone.
This
logic
suggests
that
the
unusually
low real
interest rates
in
the
1970s,
all
else
equal,
should have
been
conducive to
the
formation
of
cartels,
and the
high
real interest rates
of
the 1980s
should
have
been detrimental.
More-
over,
Green and Porter show
that if
producers,
rather than
observing
the
cartel's
output, only
observe
a
noisy
measure of the
market-clearing
price,
cartel
activity
will
be
procyclical.
The
assumption
of
imperfectly
observable
output
is
particularly appealing
for crude-oil
producers.
The
actual
production
level of
crude
oil
can
only
be estimated
in
many
cases,
and
reliable
output
statistics become available
only
with a
long
lag.
Thus,
we would
expect strong
economic
expansions,
all
else
equal,
to
strengthen
oil cartels and
major
recessions
to
weaken
them.
8. The
Relationship of
Oil
Prices
and
the
Macroeconomy:
Evidence
The
view
that oil
prices
are
endogenous
with
respect
to
U.S.
macroeconomic variables
such
as
real interest rates
and real GDP has
considerable
empirical
support.
The two most
prominent
increases
in
the
price
of oil
in 1973-1974
and
1979-1980
were
both
preceded
by
periods
of economic
expansion
(see
Table
1)
and
unusually
low
real
interest
rates
(see
Figure
5d).
Similarly,
the
most
recent oil
price
increase
coincided
with
a
strong
economic
expansion.
In
contrast,
the
fall in
oil
prices
after 1982 coincided
with
a
severe
global
recession and
unusually
high
real interest
rates. This section
analyzes
in detail the historical
evidence for
a link between oil
prices
and the
macroeconomy.
8.1 WHY
DID THE
1973-1974
OIL PRICE INCREASE
OCCUR
WHEN
IT DID?
An
intriguing
question
is
why
the
two
major
and
sustained
oil
price
increases
of the
1970s occurred
when
they
did. The dominant
view
in
the
literature
appears
to
be
that
the
timing
was
primarily
determined
by
exogenous
political
events
in the Middle
East,
which
are
thought
to have
triggered
supply
cuts,
thereby raising
oil
prices
(see
Hamilton,
1999).
However,
as
we
will
argue,
sustained
oil
price
increases
are
only
possi-
ble under
conditions
of excess
demand
in
the oil
market.
Such condi-
tions
are
unlikely
to occur
in the absence
of favorable
macroeconomic
conditions,
notably
economic
expansion
and low
real interest
rates.
Do We
Really
Know
that
Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
?
169
Thus
the
apparent
success of OPEC oil
producers
in
raising prices
in
the
1970s
(and
their
failure
to
raise
prices
for
sustained
periods
at
other
times)
is no historical
accident. The
timing
of
the
oil
price
increases
in
the
1970s
coincided
with
periods
of
unusually strong
demand for
oil,
driven
in
substantial
part
by
global
macroeconomic conditions.
Until the
late
1960s,
the
excess
capacity
of
the U.S. oil
industry
allowed
the U.S. to
play
the
special
role
of the
supplier
of
last resort
to
Europe
and
Japan,
in
the event that
oil
supplies
were
threatened. The fact
that
the U.S. assumed
this role was an
inadvertent
consequence
of
the
regula-
tory policies
of the
Texas Railroad
Commission
regime,
under which
rationing
of
production
led to
excess
capacity
(see
Hamilton,
1985).
The
ability
of the United
States to flood
the market with
surplus
oil served
as
a
deterrent
against any
attempt
to
raise
international oil
prices,
and
ultimately
thwarted the
effects of the
1956
and
1967 oil
embargoes.
What
then
were the
changes
in
the world
oil market
that
made the
successful
1973 oil
price
hike
possible?
The
main
difference
between
the
early
1970s
and
earlier
periods
was
that,
on
top
of
the
long-term
trend
toward
in-
creased
energy
consumption,
there
was
a
dramatic
surge
in
worldwide
demand for oil that
was
fueled
by
monetary
expansion.
In
March
1971,
U.S. oil
production
for
the
first time
in
history
reached
100% of
capacity
(see
Yergin,
1992,
p.
567).22
The
rising
demand
for oil
was
at
first met with an
increase
in
oil
output
in
the
Middle East that
kept
the
price
of
oil low and
falling
in
real
terms
(see
Figure
9).
Oil
imports
as
a
share of
U.S. oil
consumption
rose from
19%
in
1967 to
36%
in
1973
(see
Darmstadter and
Landsberg,
1976,
p.
31).
Mabro
(1998,
p.
11)
notes
that
OPEC's
average
daily
production
increased from
23.4
million
barrels
per
day
in
1970
to 30.99
million barrels
per
day
in
1973. All
OPEC
members but
Kuwait,
Libya,
and
Venezuela
increased
production
in
this
period.
As
a
result,
excess
capacity
was
shrinking
quickly
in
the
Middle
East.
Seymour
(1980,
p.
100)
documents
that
the oil
market
had
been
tight-
ening
since
1972 in
spite
of the
rapid
increases
in
oil
output.
In
late
1972,
all
of
the
main
market
indicators-tanker
freight
rates,
refined-
product
prices,
and
spot
crude
prices-started
rising
and
continued
their
climb
throughout
1973.
While
the
recoverable
reserves
in
the Mid-
dle
East
were
of
course
huge,
available
production
capacity
was
lagging
consumption.
By
September-October
of
1973,
immediately
before
the
22.
The
normal
market
response
to this
shortage
would
have been
rising
oil
prices.
How-
ever,
U.S.
price
controls
on
oil,
imposed
in
1971 as
part
of
an
overall
anti-inflation
program,
were
discouraging
domestic oil
production
while
stimulating
consumption,
and
left little
incentive for
exploration
or
conservation.
Moreover,
growing
environmen-
tal
concerns
held back
U.S. oil
production,
even
as new
large
oil
reserves
were
being
discovered in
Alaska
(see
McKie,
1976,
p.
73).
170
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
Figure
9 REAL
PRICE INDICES FOR
CRUDE OIL
AND
FOR
INDUSTRIAL
COMMODITIES,
JANUARY
1948 TO
JULY
2000
1950
1955 1960 1965
1970 1975 1980
1985 1990
1995 2000
Source: See
Figure
6 for
a
description
of the data.
The
price
data
have been deflated
using
the
CPI index
excluding
shelter
(PRXHS).
oil
embargo,
both Saudi Arabia
and Iran had
just
about
reached their
maximum
sustainable
output.
The
capacity shortage
was
not limited to
Saudi Arabia
and Iran. Had
oil
prices
not risen in
late
1973,
there
would have
been
virtually
no
spare productive
capacity
available
any-
where in
the world
on the basis
of the then
projected
forecasts of oil
consumption
for the
winters of
1973-1974 and
1974-1975
(see
Seymour,
1980,
p.
100).23
23.
Our
reading
of the evidence coincides with
contemporary
accounts. For
example,
in
November
1968,
only
one
year
after the
successful defeat of the
1967 oil
embargo,
State
Department
officials announced at
an OECD
meeting
that soon
the U.S. would not
be
able
to
provide
extra
supply
to the world in
the event of an
embargo
(see
Yergin,
1992,
p.
568).
In
November
1970,
a U.S.
diplomat
in the Middle East
filed
a
report
stating
that
"the
extent
of
dependence by
western industrial
countries
upon
[foreign]
oil as a
source of
energy
has
been
exposed,
and
the
practicality
of
controlling
supply
as a
means of
exerting
pressure
for
raising
the
price
of
oil has been
dramatically
demon-
strated"
(Yergin,
1992,
p.
587).
Do
We
Really
Know
that Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
171
8.2 IF THE
1973 OIL
PRICE INCREASE
WAS CAUSED
BY
DEMAND
SHIFTS,
WHY DID
OIL OUTPUT
FALL?
The normal market
reaction to the
increased demand for
oil in
the
early
1970s
should have
been
an
increase
in
both
price
and
quantity
of oil.
As
we have
noted,
the
data
instead
show
a
steady
decline of
the
price
of
oil
in
real
terms
in
the
early
1970s,
followed
by
a
sharp
rise
in
the
price
of
oil
in
late 1973 and
a
drop
in
oil
output.
This
puzzling
observation reflected
the
gradual
resolution of a
disequilibrium
that
arose from the
peculiar
institutional
structure of
the OPEC
oil
market at
that
time.
Throughout
the
1960s,
oil
delivery
contracts were
long-term
agree-
ments
between OPEC
producers
and oil
companies.
Oil
producers
agreed
to
supply
oil at
a
price
that was
fixed
in
nominal terms for
several
years
in
advance.
Contracts were
periodically
renegotiated
to
take account
of
changes
in
economic
conditions. As the
macroeconomic
environment
became
increasingly
unstable
in
the
early
1970s,
the
renegotiations
failed
to
keep
pace
with
the
rapidly
changing
macroeconomic
conditions.
The
stickiness of the
nominal
oil
price
contributed to the
observed
fall
of
the
real
price
of
oil,
as
inflation
outpaced
expectations.
OPEC
producers
be-
came
increasingly
reluctant
to
supply
additional
quantities
of
oil
at
prices
well
below the
market-clearing
level.
By
late
1973 this
regime
came
to
an
abrupt
end,
when
OPEC
reneged
on its
contractual
agreements
with
the oil
companies
and
unilaterally
decreed
a
much
higher price
of
oil.
As
the
price
of oil
rose
sharply,
the
quantity
of
oil
fell,
lending
credence to the view that a
contemporaneous
shift
in
the
supply
of oil had
taken
place.
It
is
common to
attribute the
fall in
oil
output
and the
rise
in
the
price
of oil
to
the 1973 war
and
the
subsequent
oil
embargo
(see
Hamilton,
1999).
As
we will
show,
this
interpretation
is
by
no
means
obvious,
because
excess demand in
the oil
market
would
have
induced an
unprecedented
increase
in
oil
prices
at
the
end of
1973,
even
in
perfectly competitive
markets.
For
expository
purposes
consider
a
two-period
model of
the oil
market
dynamics
in
the
early
1970s
(see
Figure
10).
In
period
1,
starting
from
the
equilibrium
point
A,
a
shift
in
demand
for oil
as
a
result
of
expansionary
monetary
policy
raises
the shadow
price
for oil.
The new
market-clearing
price
at
point
B,
however,
is
never
realized,
because the
price
of
oil is
effectively
held
back
by
long-term
contractual
agreements
(see
Penrose,
1976).24
Instead,
we
move from A
to
C,
corresponding
to an
increase
in
24.
The
essential
point
here is that
the
price
of oil in
the
early
1970s
remained
substantially
below
market-clearing
level in
the
presence
of
excess
demand. The
assumption
of a
fixed
price
is
an
oversimplification
designed
to allow
us to
abstract
from
the
effects of
inflation.
The
price
of oil
actually
fell in
real
terms
in
the
early
1970s,
despite
efforts
by
OPEC
to
offset
these
losses
(see
Figures
6 and
9).
172
*
BARSKY
& KILIAN
Figure
10
A
TWO-PERIOD
DISEQUILIBRIUM
ANALYSIS OF
THE
OIL
MARKET
t'?
D'
S
P"
D'\ /
O O
Period
I
Period
2
Notes:
In
period
1,
starting
from the
equilibrium point
A,
a shift
in
demand for oil as
a
result of
expansionary
monetary
policy
raises the shadow
price
for oil. Given the fixed contractual
price
of
oil,
production
increases
and we move to C.
In
period
2,
OPEC
reneges
on the contractual
price,
and raises
the
oil
price
to the
market-clearing
level
D while
reducing
the
quantity supplied.
the
quantity
of
oil
supplied
at the old
price.
In
period
2,
OPEC
reneges
on
the contractual
price,
and
raises the
oil
price
to the market
clearing
level
(D=B)
while
reducing
the
quantity supplied.
The
price
and
quan-
tity
movements
in
period
2
have the
appearance
of
an
oil
supply
shock,
yet
the
supply
curve
never
shifts;
we
are
witnessing
the correction
of
a
disequilibrium
resulting
from the earlier demand
shift.
Our
stylized
model of
the 1973-1974 oil market
dynamics
is consistent
both
with the absence of
significant
increases
in
the real
price
of
oil and
the observed
increase
in
oil
production
in
the
early
1970s.
It
also
is
consistent
with
the
fall
in
the
quantity
of
oil
produced
and the
sharp
increase
in
the
OPEC oil
price
in
1973-1974.
The 1973-1974
episode
illustrates
the
point
that fundamental identification
problems
need to be
addressed before
we
can
assess the effect of
exogenous
political
events
in
the
Middle East on
the
price
of oil.
As we have
shown,
the observed
price
and
quantity
movements
in
1973-1974 are consistent
both with
supply
interruptions
and
with the restoration
of
equilibrium
after
the
removal
of
price
ceilings.
Our
model also
is consistent
with
the
views
of
oil economists
such as
Mabro
(1998,
p.
10)
that
"a
major political
crisis
will not cause
a
price
shock
when
capacity
cushions
exist
in
other
coun-
Do
We
Really
Know that Oil
Caused
the
Great
Stagflation?
*
173
tries,
while
excess demand would
cause
prices
to flare even
in
the ab-
sence
of
any political
crisis."
The
fact that the cumulative rise
in the
oil
price
did not exceed the
cumulative increase
in
other
industrial
commodity prices suggests
that
the actual oil
price
in
January
1974 was
probably
not far from the
market-
clearing
level. As we
will
argue
later,
OPEC market
power played
a
more
important
role
in
determining
the
price
of oil
only
after
January
1974,
when OPEC
attempted
to stabilize
the
price
of
oil at
its
peak
level,
even
as
the U.S.
economy
slid into recession
and
other
commodity prices
fell
sharply.
An
alternative
interpretation
of
the oil
price
increase
of 1973-1974 has
been
proposed by
Hamilton
(1999).
Hamilton stresses the role of
oil
supply interruptions
that are
exogenous
to
the
state
of
the
U.S. macro-
economy.
He discusses several such
supply interruptions
that
in
his
view
were
caused
by "military
conflicts"
and
"wars"
[including
(1)
the
October 1973
war,
(2)
the Iranian
revolution
of late
1978;
(3)
the outbreak
of
the
Iran-Iraq
war in
September
1980,
and
(4)
the Gulf war of
1990-
1991].
There is
some
doubt, however,
about the
extent to which
these
events were
truly exogenous.
Hamilton
is
not
explicit
about the nature
of the
causal
link
from
military
conflict
to
exogenous production
cut-
backs.
In
some
cases,
for
example
in
discussing
the
Gulf war
(p.
28)
or
the
Iraq-Iran
war
(in
his
Appendix
B),
he
clearly
has
in
mind
the
physi-
cal destruction
of
oil
facilities
and
the war-induced
disruption
of oil
shipping.25
In
contrast,
the
production
cutbacks
in
late 1973
clearly
were
not
caused
directly
by military
conflict.26
In
fact,
most of the
production
cutbacks
occurred
only
after
the war
(which
lasted from
October
6
to
October
23,
1973)
as
part
of
an
oil
embargo
by
Arab
oil
producers.
In
his
Appendix
B,
Hamilton
postulates
a
causal
link
from
the
October
war
to this oil
embargo.
This
link
is
questionable.
Unlike
the
war
itself,
the oil
embargo
is not an
exogenous
political
event.
There
is
considerable
evidence
that
oil
producers
carefully
considered the
economic
feasibility
of the oil
embargo.27
In
fact,
the oil
embargo
was
contemplated
as
early
25.
Hamilton
(1999,
p.
28)
refers to "a
number of
historical
episodes
in
which
military
conflicts
produce
dramatic and
unambiguous
effects on the
petroleum production
from
particular
fields" such
as the
Iraqi
invasion of Kuwait in
July
1990.
26.
During
this war
only Syrian
and
Iraqi
oil
facilities
sustained battle
damage.
Neither
country
was
a
major
oil
producer,
and
the
loss
of
oil
output
was small.
The
bulk
of the
reduction
in
oil
output
that did
occur
in
late 1973
can be attributed
to
countries that
were not
directly
involved in
the
war,
but
chose to
restrict
output,
notably
Saudi Arabia
and
Kuwait
(see
U.S.
Energy
Information
Administration,
1994,
p.
307).
27. An
early example
is
King
Faisal
of Saudi
Arabia's
rejection
in
1972 of
the use of
the oil
weapon
on
economic
grounds
(see
Terzian, 1985,
p.
164).
That
decision
was reversed in
late
1973,
when more
than
a
third of
U.S. oil
consumption
was
accounted
for
by
174
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
as
July
1973,
well
before
the
October war
(see
Arad
and
Smernoff, 1975,
p.
124),
and
United States
officials were
aware of that threat.28
Although
some countries
announced
a
first
stage
of
production
cuts as
early
as
October
18
(in
the
last
week of the
war),
the
embargo
was
tightened
only
after
hostilities
had
ended on
October
23. Not
surprisingly,
the
oil em-
bargo
was lifted without its
original
political
goals being
achieved,
as
soon as oil
prices
had reached a
sufficiently high
level. Concern for
the
Arab cause lasted
only
as
long
as
it
was
economically expedient.
Moreover,
contrary
to
popular
perception
(see
the
quotation
from the
Economist
in
Section
1),
the oil
embargo
was
not associated with
a
quadru-
pling
of oil
prices.
In
actuality,
the
price
increase
that
coincided
with the
embargo
was
only
half as
large.
The
other
half
of
the oil
price
increase
occurred well before the
embargo.
In
1971,
the
basic
structure of
the
con-
tractual
agreements
between oil
companies
and
OPEC countries had
been
renegotiated
at
conferences
in
Teheran and
Tripoli.
These
agree-
ments were
long-term
in nature.
Neither the
oil
companies
nor the
OPEC
governments
anticipated
the
subsequent
successive dollar deval-
uations
in
1971
and
1973,
the
rapid
rise
in
U.S.
inflation,
and the
extraor-
dinary surge
in
the
demand for oil
in
1972 and 1973.
In
response
to these
events,
OPEC countries
and
oil
companies
repeatedly
renegotiated
the
conditions
of their contracts.
Posted
prices
of
light
Arabian
crude
gradu-
ally
rose
from
$2.29
in
June
1971
to
$2.90
in
February
1973.
In
June
1973,
pressure
mounted to abandon the
framework
of
Teheran
and
Tripoli
and
for
governments
to set
posted prices unilaterally. By
September
1973,
all the
OPEC countries were
prepared formally
to re-
quest
a
revision of
the
price agreements,
as
the
gap
between market
prices
and
posted prices
widened.
Negotiations opened
on
October
8,
two
days
after
the outbreak
of the
October 1973
war. OPEC
proposed
to
raise
the
price
of
oil to
$5.12.
The
oil
companies
stalled for time. On
October
16, 1973,
OPEC
renounced
the Teheran
and
Tripoli
agreements
and
unilaterally adopted
the
proposal
they
had earlier
put
before
the
companies.
As Penrose
(1976,
p.
50)
notes,
"the October
1973 increases
imports.
Similarly, during
the
1971
Teheran
negotiations
between
the
major
oil
compa-
nies,
the Gulf states threatened
to
implement
an
oil
embargo,
but
never
implemented
it.
Again, during
Israel's invasion
of
Lebanon
in
1982-which coincided
with
high
oil
prices,
a
global
recession,
and
high
real interest rates-an
oil
embargo
was considered
by
the
Organization
of
Arab
Petroleum
Exporting
Countries,
but
rejected
as
inconsis-
tent
with the
economic
interests
of the
organization
(see
Yergin,
1992,
pp.
582, 719;
Skeet,
1988,
p.
187).
28. Arad
and
Smernoff
(1975,
p.
190)
note
that
in
July
1973 the Committee
on
Emergency
Preparedness
of the National
Petroleum Council issued
a
report
that concluded
that an
interruption
of
petroleum imports
into
the
U.S.
was
likely
as
early
as
January
1974,
based on data
on the
dependence
of the U.S.
on
oil
imports.
Do
We
Really
Know that
Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
*
175
in
posted
prices
were
not related
to the
war,
but to the
fact that
the
assumptions underlying
the
Teheran
agreement
had
proved
unjustified.
The
exporting
countries therefore felt
that
the
.
.
.
prices agreed upon
in
Teheran
required
adjustment
to the new market and
monetary
condi-
tions. These conditions
were
not,
in their
view,
of their own
making,
since
they
had
not
cut
back
supplies
...
."
In
fact,
the
quantity
of
oil
supplied by
OPEC
had
gradually
increased
from 29.9 million
barrels
per
day
in
January
1973 to 32.7 million
barrels
per
day
in
September
1973.
Thus,
as we showed
earlier,
not
only
are there
strong
reasons to doubt
that
the second
doubling
of oil
prices
on
January
1,
1974,
was caused
by
exogenous
oil
supply
cuts,
but
there
is
overwhelming
evidence that
the
initial
doubling
of the
oil
price
to
$5.12/barrel
was due
to increased
demand for oil.
8.3 WHY DID THE
1979-1980
OIL PRICE INCREASE
OCCUR
WHEN
IT DID?
We now
turn to
the second
major
oil
price
increase
of
the
1970s,
which
took
place
in
1978-1980. As in
the
early
1970s,
there is
clear
evidence of
an
output
boom,
unusually
low
real
interest
rates,
and
rising
inflation
prior
to 1980.
The
rapid
growth
was
fueled
by
the
renewed
world-wide
monetary expansion
documented
in
Section
4.
Although
this
expansion
was
reflected
in a
sustained
increase
in
industrial
commodity
prices
in
1976-1979,
the increase in
other
commodity
prices
was
dwarfed
by
the
increase
in
oil
prices
that
started
in
late
1978
(see
Figure
6).
Since the
surge
in
oil
prices
not
only
far
exceeded inflation
adjustments,
but
also
was
not
supported
by
a
corresponding
tightening
in
other
commodity
markets,
it
must
have reflected
additional
developments
specific
to the
oil
market.
Judging
by
the
increase
in
other
industrial
commodity
prices
in
1978-1979,
at
best
one-third of
the actual oil
price
increase
appears
to be
consistent
with the
monetary
model.
In
that
respect,
the
second oil
crisis
appears
fundamentally
different from
the first
oil
crisis
of
1973-1974.29
The
inability
of
the
monetary
model
to
explain
more than
one-third
of
the
oil
price
increase
in
1979-1980 does not
imply
that
the
other
two-
thirds of
the
increase was
due
to
oil
production
cutbacks
caused
by
the
Iranian
revolution in
late 1978
and
the
outbreak
of the
Iran-Iraq
war in
September
1980,
as
suggested
by
Hamilton
(1999).
First,
taking
into
29.
Also
note
that,
unlike in
1973-1974
when
oil
prices
doubled in
a
single day,
the oil
price
increase in
1979-1980 was
much
more
gradual.
One
reason is
that-unlike in
the
early
1970s-OPEC oil
prices
had not
been held
back
by
what
was
effectively
a
price
ceiling.
Thus,
the
observed oil
price dynamics
cannot be
explained
by
a
disequilibrium
adjust-
ment
of the
kind
described in
Figure
7.
176
*
BARSKY & KILIAN
account the
offsetting production
increases
by
other oil
producers
such
as
Saudi
Arabia,
the
production
shortfall
in
early
1979
was not
nearly
as
dramatic
as
suggested by
Hamilton
(1999).
Global
production
in
Octo-
ber, November,
and December 1978
exceeded the
September
1978 level.
Only
in
January
and
February
of
1979,
at
the
height
of turmoil
in
Iran,
did
global
oil
production
fall
significantly
below its
September
1978
level,
by
4%
and
3%,
respectively
(see
U.S.
Energy
Information Administra-
tion, 1994,
p.
312).30
Moreover,
total
annual OPEC oil
production
in
1979
was 4%
higher
than
in
1978
(see
Skeet, 1988,
p.
244).
Second,
the
timing
of the
oil
price
increase
suggests
that
physical
production
shortfalls
narrowly
defined are not the cause of the
oil
price
surge.
The bulk
of the
oil
price
increases occurred
well after
the
Iranian
revolution was over
and well before the outbreak
of
the
Iran-Iraq
war.
Specifically,
during
the
Iranian
revolution,
between October
1978
and
April
1979,
the
average price
of U.S.
oil
imports
rose
by only
about
$3/
barrel
(see
DRI
database).
In
February
1979,
Iran
announced
the
resump-
tion
of
exports,
and
by
April
1979,
global
oil
production
matched
the
September
1978 level. The
main
surge
in
oil
prices
began only
in
May
1979,
at a time when
global
oil
production
exceeded
its
September
1978
level
(see
U.S.
Energy
Information
Administration,
1994,
p.
312).
Be-
tween
May
and October
1979
alone,
oil
prices
rose
from
$19
to
$25
per
barrel.
Oil
prices
continued to climb
to almost
$34
by April
1980,
when
the
armies
of
Iran and
Iraq
were first
put
on
alert
(see
Terzian,
1985,
p.
279).
The
war broke
out
in
September
1980.
In
December
1980,
oil
was
still
under
$36.
It
finally
rose to
a
peak
of
$39
in
February
1981.
One
explanation
of the
additional oil
price
rise
that occurred
between
mid-1979
and mid-1980
that
has been
proposed
in
the
literature
is
a
temporary
surge
in
precautionary
demand
in
response
to increased
un-
certainty
about
future
oil
supplies
and
expectations
of
strong
future
demand
(see
Adelman,
1993,
p.
428).
The
uncertainty-based explanation
of
higher
oil
prices,
however,
does not
seem
plausible
in
the
absence
of
taut demand
conditions
in
the oil
market,
which
in
turn
were
driven
in
no
small measure
by
a
booming
world
economy
and low
real
interest
rates.
The
fact
that
a
large
number
of
military
conflicts
and incidents
in
the
Gulf
region
in
subsequent
years
did not
lead
to
sustained
increases
in oil
prices
suggests
that
increased
Middle
East
uncertainty
appears
to
have little or
no
effect
on oil
prices
in the
absence of
favorable
macro-
30.
Hamilton notes
that
Iranian cutbacks
in
January
and
February
1979 amounted
to
almost
9%
of
the
average
monthly global
oil
production
for
1978.
Using
the same data
source,
after
allowing
for
production
increases
elsewhere,
global
oil
production
in
January
and
February
1979
actually
matched or
exceeded
slightly
the
average
1978 level
(see
U.S.
Energy
Information
Administration,
1994,
p.
312).
Do
We
Really
Know that Oil Caused the Great
Stagflation?
*
177
economic
conditions.31
It
is no
coincidence
that oil
prices
(as
well as
non-
oil
commodity prices) peaked
shortly
after Paul
Volcker launched a
sharp
monetary
contraction
resulting
in
a
global
recession
and
high
real
inter-
est
rates.
Weakening
demand
played
a crucial role
in
undermining
Saudi
Ara-
bia's efforts to shore
up
the oil
price
between 1982
and 1985
by reducing
oil
supply.
The fact that other
OPEC members
undercut the official
OPEC
price
in 1982-1985
appears
consistent
with the view
that,
in
the
absence
of
effective
monitoring
and
punishment,
cash-starved
oil-producing
countries
(such
as
Iraq
and
Iran)
had an incentive to
undercut the cartel
price
in
order
to
increase
current revenue.
At the same
time,
competition
from
other oil
producers
increased.
By
the
early
1980s,
a
large
number of
new oil
suppliers
such as
Egypt,
Angola, Malaysia,
China,
Norway,
and
the United
Kingdom
had entered
the market
in
response
to the unusu-
ally
high
oil
prices
of
the
1970s,
while
existing
producers
including
the
United States
(Alaska),
Mexico,
and
the USSR
had invested
in
new
capac-
ity
and
expanded
oil
production. By
1982,
less than
half
of
world
oil
was
supplied
by
OPEC,
compared
with two-thirds
in
1977
(see
Skeet, 1988,
p.
201).
The
resulting
downward
pressure
on oil
prices
is
consistent
with
the
predictions
of
the
Hotelling
model with
capacity
constraints.
We do not
attempt
to address
in
this
paper
the
reasons
for the
long
delay
in
the decline
of
oil
prices-both
in
the
mid-1970s
and
in
the
early
1980s-after
the initial
monetary expansion
was
reversed.
Although
the
sharp
oil
price
increases
in
the
1970s
came on
the
heels
of shifts in
the
demand
for
oil
that-in
our
view-were
directly
or
indirectly
fueled
by
monetary expansion,
OPEC seems to have been
adept
at
restraining
official
price cutting
even
in
the
presence
of
significant
excess
capacity.
Figure
8 shows that
other industrial
commodity
prices dropped
sharply
in
response
to
recessions
and
higher
real
interest
rates,
as
theory
would
suggest.
Oil
prices,
however,
remained at a
much
higher
level
than
31.
Examples
include the Israeli attack on an
Iraqi
nuclear
reactor
in
June
1981;
a
state
of
near-war
between
Israel
and
Syria
from
April
to
July
1981
(see
Skeet,
1988,
p.
181);
the
invasion of
Lebanon
by
Israel in
June
1982;
the Iranian Ramadan
offensive
against Iraq
in
July
1982
(see
Yergin,
1992,
p.
764);
Iran's
threat
in
July
1983
to
blockade the
Straits
of
Hormuz
(see
Terzian, 1985,
p.
323);
suicide attacks on the U.S. and
French
headquar-
ters in
Lebanon
in
October 1983
(see
Skeet
1988,
p.
197);
the
tanker
war
in
the Gulf
in
February-April
1984,
during
which at least
eleven tankers and the
major
Iranian oil
terminal
were hit
(see
Terzian,
1985,
p.
327;
Yergin,
1992,
p.
743);
the
Iranian
capture
of
the Fao
Peninsula in the
southeastern corner
of
Iraq
in
February
1986,
followed
by
Iranian
artillery
and
missile attacks on
Kuwait's oil
ports
and Iranian
naval
attacks on
Kuwaiti
shipping;
the Kuwaiti
request
for U.S. naval
patrols
in
the Gulf in
March 1987
to
protect
its
oil
tankers
(see
Yergin,
1992,
p.
765);
the
Iraqi
missile attack on the
U.S.S.
Stark
during
the tanker war in
May
1987,
resulting
in
the
deaths of 36
sailors;
and
the
downing
of an Iranian
airliner
by
U.S. forces in
the Gulf in
July
1988
following
skir-
mishes
with
Iranian
patrols
(see
Yergin,
1992,
p.
766).
178
*
BARSKY &
KILIAN
other
commodity
prices
during
1974-1978 and
again during
1981-1985.
This
differential
response after
the
onset of the
1974-1975
and
1981-1982
recessions
is
suggestive
of the use
of OPEC market
power
to
prop up
oil
prices.
As
Nordhaus
(1980,
p.
367)
notes,
in
periods
of
excess
demand,
there
is
little OPEC
can do
(or
would
want to
do)
to
impede
oil
price
increases. Once
official OPEC
prices
have
risen, however,
they
tend
to
be
sticky,
even when
there
is a
glut
in
the
oil market.
Indeed,
empirical
and
anecdotal
evidence lends
support
to the view that
OPEC was
most
influential not in 1973-1974 or in
1979
during
the time
of
the most
rapid
oil
price
increases-as
popular opinion
would
suggest-but
in
prevent-
ing
oil
prices
from
falling
as
rapidly
as
they
should
have
when oil de-
mand
subsided
(also
see
Mabro,
1998,
pp.
10-11).
9. Lessons
from
the Most Recent
Oil Price
Surge
The
tripling
of oil
prices
after 1998
provides
us with
yet
another
opportu-
nity
to
test
the
implications
of
our
explanation
of
stagflation.
Historically,
as
we
have shown
in
Section
6,
oil
price
increases
by
themselves have
caused
excess CPI inflation
(relative
to inflation in
the GDP
deflator)
for
short
periods,
rather
than
extended
periods
of inflation. The current
episode
is no
exception.
U.S.
data after
1998 show
a
spike
in CPI infla-
tion relative
to
deflator
inflation
rates
(see
Figure
8).
In
contrast,
there
has been little movement
in
the
inflation
rate
of
the deflator.
This
finding
is not
surprising,
because
there
has not been
a
major monetary expan-
sion
of the kind that
was
characteristic of the 1970s. Also
noteworthy
is
the fact
that,
despite
higher
oil
prices,
there is no evidence
yet
of
a
major
contraction,
which
seems to belie the notion that oil
price
increases
inevitably
cause
recessions.
Although
real
interest rates have
not been
unusually
low,
cumulative
growth
rates
for the United States have been
extraordinarily high-high
enough
to offset
the
less
than stellar
growth
performance
of
Europe
and
Japan.
That increase
in
output,
however,
appears
to
be different
from
the
rapid output growth
in the
1970s
that was
largely
fueled
by
mone-
tary
expansion.
The
very
strong
real
growth
in
the
past
several
years,
especially
in
the
U.S.,
has
been
reflective
of an
increase
of
potential
output
rather
than "demand"
generated
(see
Basu,
Fernald,
and Sha-
piro,
2000).
Our
analysis
suggests
that this
strong growth
in
output
was
instrumental
in
supporting
the increase
in oil
prices
in 1999-2000.
If the
United
States
had
been
in
a
recession
during
1999-2000
and U.S.
de-
mand for oil
had been
low,
it
would
have been
hard for OPEC
to
enforce
high
oil
prices
over
extended
periods.
The
ability
of a cartel like OPEC
to sustain
prices
above the
competitive
level
depends
on
a
conducive
macroeconomic environment.
If there is
a
significant
contraction
of
Do We
Really
Know that
Oil Caused
the Great
Stagflation?
?
179
the
economy,
historical
experience
suggests
that OPEC
will have
an
uphill
battle
maintaining
the current level
of oil
prices.
Both oil
and
other
commodity prices
fell
sharply
after
the Asian
crisis,
yet
only
oil
prices
have
strongly
rebounded.
This
discrepancy
is
sugges-
tive of
a
larger
role for OPEC after 1998
than in
earlier
episodes.
One
interpretation
we can rule out for
sure is
that
OPEC
has been
reacting
to
exogenous political
events in the
Middle East.
Certainly,
the latest
major
oil
price
increase was not
preceded
by physical production
cutbacks
"induced
by
war"
along
the
lines of
Hamilton
(1999).
In
fact,
oil
prices
rose
during
the
period
of
peace
making
between Israel
and
the Palestin-
ians,
but Arab
leaders refused to use the "oil
weapon"
when
the recent
confrontations
erupted
(see
Washington
Post,
2000).
This is
not
surpris-
ing, given
the
already
high
level of oil
prices,
and
certainly
is consistent
with
our
view
that
in
previous
episodes political
factors
were allowed to
play
a
role
in
setting
oil
prices only
to
the extent
that
they
did not
conflict
with
economic
objectives
and constraints.
What
then
enabled
OPEC to consolidate its
power
after its
influence
had
declined ever
since the late 1980s?
There are two
reasons. One
is
that
other
oil
producers
(such
as
Norway
and
Mexico)
that
are not
part
of
OPEC
effectively joined
forces with
OPEC,
raising
the
organization's
effective market
share,
which
had
declined
dramatically
in
the
1980s
(see
New York
Times,
2001).
The
consolidation of OPEC
is consistent with
theoretical
models of
cartels,
such as
Green
and
Porter
(1984),
that
lead
us to
expect
that
cartels
will
flourish
in
periods
of
strong
economic
growth.
Second,
there is
evidence that oil
producers
across
the
world,
with
the
possible
exception
of Saudi
Arabia,
were once
again
operating
close to
capacity,
and that
few
additional oil
supplies
were
likely
to be
forthcoming
in
the
short run.
This
scarcity
was
arguably
driven in
impor-
tant
part by
strong
demand for
crude oil.
The rise
in
oil
prices
coincided
with a
shortage
of
oil
tankers,
and
freight
rates for
crude oil
shipments
have
increased
sharply,
suggesting high
demand
for oil.
Thus,
the
prob-
lem
appears
to have
been
one of
insufficient
inventories
in
the face
of
rapidly
rising
demand for
oil,
rather than a
global
supply
cut.
This
view is
further
supported
by
the
sharp
drop
of
crude-oil
prices
in
late
December
2000 from
a
peak
of
more than
$37
per
barrel to
below
$27
upon
news
reports
of
an
impending
U.S.
recession,
despite
low
invento-
ries,
Middle East
turmoil,
one
of
the
coldest
winters
in
recent
memory,
and
the
high
likelihood that
most of
Iraq's
oil
exports
would
remain off
global
markets.
Predictably,
OPEC
will
attempt
to
stem
the
expected
decline
in
oil
prices by
announcing production
cutbacks,
as
it
did
after
each
of the
major
oil
price
increases
in
the
1970s when
demand
for oil
began
to
slacken
(see
New
York
Times,
2001).
How
long
OPEC will
be
able
to
sustain
high
real
oil
prices
will
depend
on
the
depth
of
the
economic
180
*
BARSKY
&
KILIAN
downturn as
well as the extent to
which new
non-OPEC oil
supplies
will
be
forthcoming
in
response
to
higher
oil
prices.
10.
Concluding
Remarks
The
origins
of
stagflation
and the
possibility
of its
recurrence
continue to be
an
important
concern
among
policymakers
and in
the
popular
press.
Our
analysis suggests
that in
substantial
part
the
Great
Stagflation
of
the 1970s
could have been
avoided,
had
the Fed not
permitted
major
monetary
ex-
pansions
in the
early
1970s.
We
demonstrated that the
stagflation
ob-
served
in
the 1970s is
unlikely
to
have
been caused
by
supply
disturbances
such
as
oil shocks.
This
point
is
important,
because
to
the
extent
that
stag-
flation is
due to
exogenous supply
shocks,
any
attempt
to
lower
inflation
would worsen
the
recession.
In
contrast,
if
we
are
right
that
stagflation
is
first
and foremost
a
monetary phenomenon,
then
stagflation
does
not
present
an
inevitable
"policy
dilemma." We conclude
that
oil
price
in-
creases
by
themselves are
unlikely
to
reignite
stagflation,
as
long
as the
Federal Reserve
refrains
from
excessively
expansionary
monetary poli-
cies.
Moreover,
a
sustained
increase
in
the
real
price
of oil
is
unlikely
in
the
absence of
a conducive
macroeconomic environment
in
OECD countries.
REFERENCES
Abel, A.,
and
B.
Bernanke.
(1998).
Macroeconomics,
3rd
ed.
Reading,
MA:
Addison-Wesley.
Adelman,
M. A.
(1993).
The Economics
of
Petroleum
Supply. Cambridge,
MA:
The
MIT
Press.
Arad,
U.
B.,
and B.
J.
Smernoff.
(1975).
American
Security
and
the
International
Energy
Situation.
New York:
Hudson Institute.
Barro,
R.
J. (1987).
Macroeconomics,
2nd
ed.
New York:
Wiley.
,
and D.
Gordon.
(1983).
A
positive
theory
of
monetary
policy
in a natural
rate model.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
91:589-610.
Basu,
S.,
J.
Fernald,
and M. D.
Shapiro.
(2000).
Productivity growth
in
the
1990s:
Technology,
utilization
or
adjustment?
Department
of
Economics,
University
of
Michigan.
Mimeo.
Bernanke,
B.
S.
(1983).
Irreversibility,
uncertainty,
and
cyclical
investment.
Quar-
terly
Journal
of
Economics
98:85-106.
,
and
M. Gertler
(1995).
Inside the
black box:
The credit
channel of
mone-
tary policy
transmission.
Journal
of
Economic
Perspectives
9:27-48.
,
,
and
M.
W.
Watson.
(1997).
Systematic
monetary policy
and
the
effects
of oil
price
shocks
(with
discussion).
Brookings
Papers
on Economic
Activ-
ity
1:91-148.
,
and
I.
Mihov.
(1998).
Measuring
Monetary Policy.
Quarterly
Journal
of
Economics
113(3):869-902.
Berndt,
E.-R.,
I.
M.
Cockburn,
and
Z.
Griliches.
(1996).
Pharmaceutical
innova-
tions
and
market
dynamics:
Tracing
effects on
price
indexes
for
antidepressant
drugs. Brookings
Papers
on
Economic
Activity:
Microeconomics
133-188.
Do
We
Really
Know that
Oil
Caused the Great
Stagflation?
*
181
Blinder,
A.
(1979).
Economic
Policy
and
the Great
Stagflation.
New
York: Academic
Press.
Bohi,
D.
R.
(1989).
Energy
Price Shocks and Macroeconomic
Performance.
Washing-
ton: Resources
for the
Future.
Bordo,
M.
D.,
and
B.
Eichengreen.
(1993).
A
Retrospective
on
the
Bretton Woods
System:
Lessons
for
International
Monetary Reform.
NBER
project report. Chicago:
University
of
Chicago
Press.
,
and
F
E.
Kydland.
(1996).
The
gold
standard as
a
commitment
mecha-
nism. In
Modern
Perspectives
on the Gold
Standard,
T.
Bayoumi,
B.
Eichengreen,
and M. P.
Taylor
(eds.).
Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press,
pp.
55-100.
Boschen,
J.
F,
and L.
O.
Mills.
(1995).
The relation between narrative and
money
market
indicators of
monetary policy.
Economic
Inquiry
33(1):24-44.
Bruno,
M.,
and
J.
Sachs.
(1985).
Economics
of
Worldwide
Stagflation.
Cambridge,
MA:
Harvard
University
Press.
Burns,
A. F
(1978).
Reflections
of
an
Economic
Policy
Maker.
Speeches,
and
Congres-
sional
Statements:
1969-1978.
Washington:
American
Enterprise
Institute
for
Public
Policy
Research.
Cagan,
P
(1979).
Persistent
Inflation:
Historical and
Policy Essays.
New York: Colum-
bia
University
Press.
Calvo,
G.
(1983).
Staggered prices
in
a
utility-maximizing setting.
Journal
of
Mone-
tary
Economics
12(3):383-398.
Christiano,
L.
J.,
M.
Eichenbaum,
and
C.
L.
Evans.
(1996).
The effects
of mone-
tary policy
shocks: Some evidence
from the flow of funds. Review
of
Economics
and
Statistics
78:16-34.
,
and
C. Gust.
(2000).
The
expectations
trap
hypothesis.
International
Finance
Discussion
Paper
No. 676.
Board of
Governors of the Federal
Reserve.
Clarida,
R.,
J.
Gall,
and
M.
Gertler.
(2000).
Monetary
policy
rules and
macro-
economic
stability:
Evidence and some
theory. Quarterly
Journal
of
Economics
115:147-180.
Darmstadter,
J.,
and H. H.
Landsberg.
(1976).
The
economic
background.
In The
Oil
Crisis,
R.
Vernon
(ed.).
New York:
Norton.
De
Long,
B.
J.
(1997).
America's
peacetime
inflation:
The 1970s. In
Reducing
Inflation:
Motivation
and
Strategy,
C.
Romer and D.
Romer
(eds.).
Chicago:
University
of
Chicago
Press.
Economist.
(1999).
"Oil's
Pleasant
Surprise."
November
27,
p.
16.
Fisher,
I.
(1906).
The
Rate
of
Interest. New
York:
MacMillan.
Friedman,
M.
(1975).
Perspectives
on
Inflation.
Newsweek,
June
24,
p.
73.
Genberg,
H.,
and
A.
K.
Swoboda.
(1993).
The
provision
of
liquidity
in
the
Bretton Woods
system.
In
A
Retrospective
on
the Bretton
Woods
System:
Lessonsfor
International
Monetary
Reform,
M. D.
Bordo and
B.
Eichengreen
(eds.).
NBER
project
report.
Chicago:
University
of
Chicago
Press,
pp.
269-315.
Gordon,
R.
J.
(1984).
Supply
shocks and
monetary
policy
revisited. American
Economic
Review,
74:38-43.
Green,
E.
J.,
and R. H.
Porter.
(1984).
Noncooperative
collusion
under
imperfect
price
information.
Econometrica,
52(1):87-100.
Griliches,
Z.,
and
I.
Cockburn.
(1994).
Generics and
new
goods
in
pharmaceuti-
cal
price
indexes. American
Economic
Review,
84(5):1213-1232.
Hamilton,
J.
D.
(1983).
Oil and
the
macroeconomy
since World War
II.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
91:228-248.
.
(1985).
Historical
causes of
postwar
oil shocks and
recessions. The
Energy
Journal
6:97-115.
182
*
BARSKY
&
KILIAN
.
(1988).
A
neoclassical
model
of
unemployment
and
the
business
cycle.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
96:593-617.
.
(1999).
What is an
Oil
Shock?
Cambridge,
MA:
National
Bureau of
Eco-
nomic
Research.
NBER
Working
Paper
7755.
Hetzel,
R. L.
(1998).
Arthur
Burns
and
inflation.
Federal
Reserve Bank
of
Richmond
Economic
Quarterly
84:21-44.
Heal, G.,
and
G.
Chichilnisky.
(1991).
Oil and the
International
Economy.
Oxford:
Clarendon
Press.
Holland,
S.
(1998).
Existence of
competitive
equilibrium
in
the
Hotelling
model
with
capacity
constraints.
Department
of
Economics,
University
of
Michigan.
Mimeo.
Hotelling,
H.
(1931).
The
economics of
exhaustible
resources.
In
Microeconomics:
Theoretical and
Applied,
Vol.
1. R.
E.
Kuenne
(ed.).
Aldershot:
Elgar,
1991,
pp.
356-394.
Houthakker,
H.
(1987).
The
ups
and
downs
of oil.
In
Deficits,
Taxes,
and
Economic
Adjustments,
P.
Cagan
(ed.).
Washington:
American
Enterprise
Institute.
International
Monetary
Fund.
International
Financial
Statistics,
various
issues.
Kimball,
M.
S.
(1995).
The
quantitative
analytics
of the
basic
neomonetarist
model.
Journal
of Money,
Credit,
and
Banking
27(4),
Part
2:
1241-1277.
King,
R.,
and M.
Goodfriend.
(1997).
The new
neoclassical
synthesis
and
the
role
of
monetary policy.
In
NBER
Macroeconomics
Annual,
No.
12. B.
S.
Bernanke
and
J.-J.
Rotemberg
(eds.).
Cambridge,
MA: MIT
Press.
Kydland,
E
E.,
and E.
C.
Prescott.
(1977).
Rules rather than
discretion: The
inconsistency
of
optimal plans.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
85:473-492.
Leeper,
E. M.
(1997).
Narrative and VAR
approaches
to
monetary policy:
Com-
mon identification
problems.
Journal
of Monetary
Economics
40(3):641-657.
Lucas,
R.
E.
(1972).
Expectations
and
the
neutrality
of
money.
Journal
of
Economic
Theory
4:103-124.
.
(1973).
Some international
evidence on
output-inflation
tradeoffs. Ameri-
can
Economic Review
63:326-334.
Mabro,
R.
(1998).
OPEC behavior
1960-1998:
A
review of the
literature. The
Journal
of
Energy
Literature 4:3-27.
McKie,
J.
W.
(1976).
The
United
States.
In The
Oil
Crisis,
R.
Vernon
(ed.).
New
York: Norton.
McKinnon,
R.
I.
(1982).
Currency
substitution and
instability
in
the world
dollar
standard. American Economic
Review
72(3):320-333.
Mundell,
R. A.
(2000).
A
reconsideration
of
the
twentieth
century.
American
Economic Review
90(3):327-340.
National Commission on
Supplies
and
Shortages.
(1976).
The
Commodity
Short-
ages of
1973-1974.
Case Studies.
Washington:
U.S. Government
Printing
Office.
Nelson,
E.
(1998).
Sluggish
inflation and
optimizing
models of the
business
cycle.
Journal
of Monetary
Economics
42:303-322.
New York Times.
(2001).
For
OPEC,
cuts
in
production
are a
delicate
balancing
act.
January
11,
p.
1.
Nordhaus,
W.
D.
(1980).
Oil
and
economic
performance
in
industrial
countries.
Brookings Papers
on Economic
Activity
2:341-388.
Orphanides,
A.
(2000).
Activist
stabilization
policy
and inflation:
The
Taylor
rule
in
the 1970s. Board
of
Governors
of the
Federal Reserve. Discussion
Paper.
,
R. D.
Porter,
D.
Reifschneider,
R.
Tetlow,
and
E
Finan.
(1999).
Errors
in
Comment
183
the measurement
of
the
output gap
and
the
design
of
monetary policy.
Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Discussion
Paper.
Penrose,
E.
(1976).
The
development
of crisis.
In The Oil
Crisis,
R.
Vernon
(ed.).
New York:
Norton.
Roberts,
S.
(1984).
Who Makes
the
Oil Price?
An
Analysis of
Oil
Price Movements
1978-1982.
Oxford: Oxford Institute for
Energy
Studies.
Rogoff,
K.
(1985).
The
optimal degree
of
commitment
to
an
intermediate mone-
tary target.
Quarterly Journal
of
Economics
100:1169-1190.
Rotemberg,
J.
(1982).
Sticky
prices
in
the United States.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
90(6):1187-1211.
.
(1996).
Prices,
output,
and
hours:
An
empirical analysis
based on
a
sticky
price
model.
Journal
of Monetary
Economics
37(3):505-533.
,
and G.
Saloner.
(1986).
A
supergame-theoretic
model of business
cycles
and
price
wars
during
booms. American Economic Review 76:390-407.
,
and M.
Woodford.
(1996).
Imperfect competition
and
the
effects
of
en-
ergy price
increases
on
economic
activity.
Journal
of
Money,
Credit,
and
Banking
28(4),
Part
1:
550-577.
Samuelson,
P. A.
(1974).
Worldwide
stagflation.
In
Collected
Scientific
Papers,
Vol.
4. H.
Nagatani
and K.
Crowley
(eds.).
Cambridge,
MA:
The
M.I.T.
Press,
1977.
,
and
R. M.
Solow.
(1960).
Analytical aspects
of
anti-inflation
policy.
American
Economic Review
40(2):177-194.
Sargent,
T.
J. (1998).
The
Conquest
of
American
Inflation.
Hoover Institution.
Seymour,
I.
(1980).
OPEC: Instrument
of Change.
London:
Macmillan.
Skeet,
I.
(1988).
OPEC:
Twenty-Five
Years
of
Prices and Politics.
Cambridge:
Cam-
bridge University
Press.
Taylor,
J. (1979).
Staggered
wage
setting
in a
macro model. American Economic
Review
69(2):108-113.
Terzian.
P.
(1985).
OPEC: The Inside
Story.
London: Zed Books.
United
States
Energy
Information
Administration.
(1994).
Historical
Monthly
En-
ergy
Review: 1973-1992.
U.S. Government
Printing
Office.
Washington
Post.
(2000).
Arab
leaders meet for summit.
October
21.
Yergin,
D.
(1992).
The Prize. The
Epic
Quest
for
Oil,
Money,
and Power.
New York:
Simon and
Schuster.
Comment
OLIVIER
BLANCHARD
Massachusetts
Institute
of
Technology
1.
Introduction
Revisionist
history
is
always
fun.
But it is
not
always
convincing.
I
have
enjoyed
thinking
about the
thesis
developed
by Barsky
and
Kilian. But I
am
not
convinced.
Comment
183
the measurement
of
the
output gap
and
the
design
of
monetary policy.
Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve. Discussion
Paper.
Penrose,
E.
(1976).
The
development
of crisis.
In The Oil
Crisis,
R.
Vernon
(ed.).
New York:
Norton.
Roberts,
S.
(1984).
Who Makes
the
Oil Price?
An
Analysis of
Oil
Price Movements
1978-1982.
Oxford: Oxford Institute for
Energy
Studies.
Rogoff,
K.
(1985).
The
optimal degree
of
commitment
to
an
intermediate mone-
tary target.
Quarterly Journal
of
Economics
100:1169-1190.
Rotemberg,
J.
(1982).
Sticky
prices
in
the United States.
Journal
of
Political
Economy
90(6):1187-1211.
.
(1996).
Prices,
output,
and
hours:
An
empirical analysis
based on
a
sticky
price
model.
Journal
of Monetary
Economics
37(3):505-533.
,
and G.
Saloner.
(1986).
A
supergame-theoretic
model of business
cycles
and
price
wars
during
booms. American Economic Review 76:390-407.
,
and M.
Woodford.
(1996).
Imperfect competition
and
the
effects
of
en-
ergy price
increases
on
economic
activity.
Journal
of
Money,
Credit,
and
Banking
28(4),
Part
1:
550-577.
Samuelson,
P. A.
(1974).
Worldwide
stagflation.
In
Collected
Scientific
Papers,
Vol.
4. H.
Nagatani
and K.
Crowley
(eds.).
Cambridge,
MA:
The
M.I.T.
Press,
1977.
,
and
R. M.
Solow.
(1960).
Analytical aspects
of
anti-inflation
policy.
American
Economic Review
40(2):177-194.
Sargent,
T.
J. (1998).
The
Conquest
of
American
Inflation.
Hoover Institution.
Seymour,
I.
(1980).
OPEC: Instrument
of Change.
London:
Macmillan.
Skeet,
I.
(1988).
OPEC:
Twenty-Five
Years
of
Prices and Politics.
Cambridge:
Cam-
bridge University
Press.
Taylor,
J. (1979).
Staggered
wage
setting
in a
macro model. American Economic
Review
69(2):108-113.
Terzian.
P.
(1985).
OPEC: The Inside
Story.
London: Zed Books.
United
States
Energy
Information
Administration.
(1994).
Historical
Monthly
En-
ergy
Review: 1973-1992.
U.S. Government
Printing
Office.
Washington
Post.
(2000).
Arab
leaders meet for summit.
October
21.
Yergin,
D.
(1992).
The Prize. The
Epic
Quest
for
Oil,
Money,
and Power.
New York:
Simon and
Schuster.
Comment
OLIVIER
BLANCHARD
Massachusetts
Institute
of
Technology
1.
Introduction
Revisionist
history
is
always
fun.
But it is
not
always
convincing.
I
have
enjoyed
thinking
about the
thesis
developed
by Barsky
and
Kilian. But I
am
not
convinced.
184
*
BLANCHARD
2.
The Noncontroversial Part: The
Role
of Money
in the
Early
1970s
Not
all
of the
paper
is
revisionist; indeed,
some of
it
is less so than it
sounds: There
is,
I
believe,
wide
agreement
that
money played
a
major
part
in what
happened
in
the
early
to mid-1970s. Most
observers
would
in
particular
agree
to
the
following propositions
(much
of
what follows
can,
for
example,
be found
in
the book
by
Michael
Bruno and
Jeffrey
Sachs
on
the
Economics
of Stagflation,
published
in
1985):
Expansionary monetary
policy
was an
important factor
in
stimulating growth
and
reducing
unemployment
in
the United States
after
the 1970 recession.
By
1973,
the
unemployment
rate
was
4.9%, downfrom
6.0% in
1971.
U.S.
inflation
came down until
1972,
and then
started
increasing
in
1973,
suggesting
that the
unemployment
rate was then close
to
the
natural
rate. It is
therefore likely
that,
had the
output
expansion
continued at the same rate
after
1973,
inflation
would have
further
increased,
even absent
any
changes
in the
relative
price of
oil.
Expansionary monetary
policy
in the
United
States,
and the
attempts byforeign
central
banks to maintain the value
of
the
dollar,
led to
large
induced
monetary
expansions
abroad.
Growth
in the
other
major
OECD
countries-countries,
which
in contrast to the United
States,
had
not had a recession in 1970-
continued
to be
high. Unemployment
continued to
be
very
low.
Inflation
in
the
EEC
steadily
increased,
nearly doubling
between 1970 and 1973.
There
again,
a slowdown
in
activity
was
clearly
needed,
and would have
come,
even
absent
the
increase in the
price
of
oil.
This world
monetary
expansion
was associated
with low nominal interest
rates,
and
even lower real
interest rates.
This,
combined with
strong
world
demand,
was more than
enough
to
trigger
an increase
in the
price
of
commodities and
raw
materials some time
before
the
increase
in
the
price
of
oil.
In
short,
even
absent the
increase
in
the
price
of
oil,
1974 and 1975
would
have seen either
increasing
inflation
and/or
a
slowdown
in
growth.
Most
likely, given
the attitude
of central
banks from
1973
on,
the
outcome
would have
involved
monetary tightening
and
a
slowdown
in
growth.
3.
Controversial
Point
1:
One Can
Explain
Stagflation
within
a
Model
with
Only
Monetary
Shocks
Let
me
start
with what looks
like
a
semantic
issue,
but is in fact more.
Comment.
185
Barsky
and Kilian
define
"stagflation"
as the
coincidence
of
"low or
negative
output growth"
and
"high
inflation"
(i.e.,
Au
>
0,
7r
high). They
argue-
rightly-that
this is
easy
to
generate
in a model with nominal
rigidities.
In
effect,
we know that
inflation
builds
up
slowly after
a
monetary expansion.
At
some
point,
high
inflation
leads to a decrease in real
money,
which in
turn
leads
to a
decrease in
output
growth;
at that
point
there
is indeed
high inflation
and
low,
possibly
negative, output growth.
A
more conventional
definition of "stagflation"
however is the
coincidence
of
high unemployment
and
increasing
inflation
(i.e.,
u
high,
and AT
r
>
0.
Why
does this semantic
discussion matter?
Because
(1)
what
was ob-
served
in
the 1970s was
indeed
a
combination of
high
unemployment
and
increasing
inflation,
i.e.
stagflation
according
to the
second
defini-
tion;
(2)
this combination is
very
hard to
generate
in
response
to
only
changes
in
money growth.
Let
me
develop
both
points.
On the
empirical
evidence: The
average unemployment
rate from
1973
to
1975
was
6.4%,
substantially higher
than
what
the natural
rate of
unemployment
had been until
then.
And,
over
the same
period,
the
increase
in
inflation
was around
5
percentage points.
The
period
was
one
of
high unemployment
and
increasing
inflation.
On
the
theoretical
proposition:
Go
back
to a
conventional
Phillips-
curve
relation:
-Tt
-
-t
=
-a(u -
l).
Inflation minus
expected
inflation
is
a
decreasing
function of
the dis-
tance between
the actual
unemployment
rate and
the
natural
unemploy-
ment
rate.
In
the
absence
of
supply
shocks,
a
is
a
constant.
Stagflation
(according
to the
second
definition,
and
the
1973-1975
facts)
implies
the
coincidence of
increasing
inflation,
viz.
7Tt
-
lt_
>
0,
and of
unemployment
above
the natural
rate,
viz.
ut
-
u
>
0,
so
that,
by
implication,
'Tt
-
t
<
0.
These
two
conditions
can
be
rewritten
as
t
-
7t_t-
>
ITt-
7t-
1>
0.
186
*
BLANCHARD
In
words,
the
expected
increase
in
inflation must
exceed
the actual
in-
crease
in
inflation,
and this at
a
time at which inflation is
increasing.
It is
difficult
to think of
expectation
formation mechanisms
which
will natu-
rally
deliver this result.
The
learning
model
presented by
Barsky
and
Kilian does not.
In
general,
learning
does
not seem
promising
here:
It
seems more
likely
to
lead to the
opposite inequality,
with the
expected
increase
in inflation
lagging
behind the
actual increase.
So,
how
can one
generate stagflation? By
having
an
increase
in the
natural rate
a, or,
equivalently
for our
purposes,
a
positive
disturbance
to
the
Phillips-curve
relation.
A natural
candidate
is
an
increase
in the
price
of
oil,
which
generates
an increase
in
a, or,
equivalently
for our
purposes,
a
positive
disturbance
in the
Phillips-curve
relation.
Thus,
the
traditional
focus
on
supply
shocks
to
explain
the
1970s.
This
argument
however
suggests
one
way
out
for
proponents
of the
monetary-policy
explanation.
Barsky
and Kilian do not
push
it
explicitly,
but
clearly
they
could,
as it is
in
the
spirit
of their
paper.
If
expansionary
monetary policy
leads to
an
increase
in
the relative
price
of
oil,
then
one
indeed
can
in
principle
generate stagflation
just
from
monetary
shocks.
This leads
to the second
major
issue,
the
degree
to which one
can
think
of the
large
increases
in the
price
of oil
in the 1970s
as
endogenous
and
triggered
by
monetary policy.
4.
Controversial
Point
2:
The Increase
in the Price
of
Oil
in
the
1970s
Was
an
Endogenous
Response
to a
Money-Driven
World
Boom
Here,
theory
is on
the side
of
Barsky
and Kilian.
Oil is
a natural resource.
Current
or
anticipated
increases
in demand or
decreases
in the real
interest
rate
should
both
lead to
an
increase
in the
current
price.
And,
indeed,
the
early
1970s were
a
period
of
high
demand
and low
real
rates.
The
problem
is
empirical.
I
am
no
expert
on
the oil
market.
But
from
my
reading
of the
literature,
I
have the
strong
feeling
that most
experts
agree:
The
two
increases
in
the
price
of oil
were
not
the
natural,
if
delayed,
response
to
demand
and interest
rates,
but
were
mostly
the
result
of successful
cartelization.
Agreement
among
experts
is
surely
no
proof.
But the
hypothesis
of
endogenous
increase
in
the
price
of
oil runs
into
a number of
obvious
problems
(my-very
limited-knowledge
on these
issues
is
largely
based
on
M.
A.
Adelman's
writings,
in
particular
Adelman,
1993):
The
degree
to which
the
price of
a
good
depends
on the
interest
rate
depends
on
the
degree
to which
it
is
a
fixed
rather than
a renewable resource.
And
here,
the
Comment 187
evidence seems
to be that
oil behaves more like
the second than the
first.
The
amount
of
so-called
"proven
resources"
has
consistently
increased over
time,
despite
the
steady
extraction
of
oil
from
the
ground.
The
degree
to which the
price
depends
on
current
and
anticipated
demand
de-
pends
on the
slope
of
the
marginal-cost
curve,
relating
the cost
of
extraction to
theflow
of
extraction.
Evidence
suggests
that,
in the
1970s,
the
marginal-cost
curve was rather
flat:
that there
were a
large
number
offields
from
which oil
could be extracted
at close to the same cost
per
barrel-a
costfar
below
the
price
which
prevailed
from
1974 on.
The
increase in
prices
in the mid-1970s was
associated
with a decrease
in
production-not
what
you
would
expect
to
see
in
response
to
a
shift
in de-
mand. The issue
is taken
up by Barsky
and
Kilian,
who
provide
a
creative,
if
not
totally
convincing,
answer.
But there
is
another
empirical
problem
along
the same lines: The increase
in
prices
in
the mid-1970s
was associated
with
a
decrease
in
productionfor
the low-cost OPEC
countries,
and an increase in the
production
for
the
high-cost
non-OPEC
countries.
This is hard to
explain
without
giving
some
central role to
OPEC
in
the
story.
With the world recession
of
the
mid-1970s,
the
high-demand
conditions,
which
might
have
justified
the
high
price
of
oil
earlier,
largely
vanished.
And later on
in the
decade,
tighter monetary policy
led to much
higher
real rates. Yet
the
price
of
oil remained
high.
The
paper-and
the literature-invoke
"ratchet
effects"
(in
the
form of higher
excise
taxes,
imposed by
the
oil-producing
countries
on oil
companies);
but this
begs
the
question: Why
not invoke the
same mechanisms
for
the initial increase
in the
price of
oil?
5.
Controversial
Point 3:
The
Recession
of
the Mid-1970s
Was Due
to
a Contraction
in
Money
Here,
the
problem
is
again empirical
and
obvious. The
way
monetary
contraction is
supposed
to work is
through high
interest
rates. Nominal
interest rates increased
substantially
in 1974
and 1975. This is shown
in
Figure
1,
which
plots
short-, medium-,
and
long-term
interest
rates from
the
mid-1960s to the
early
1990s.
But
inflation increased
by
more, and,
based on forecasts of inflation at the
time,
so did
expected
inflation.
This
is shown
in
Figure
2,
which
plots
short-,
medium-,
and
long-term
real
interest
rates,
using
inflation
forecasts of the
time,
for the
same
period.
Real interest
rates were lowest
in 1974 and
1975; indeed,
in
both
years,
the short real
rate
was
negative,
the
longer
real
rates
very
close to zero.
(The
numbers are taken from
Blanchard, 1993;
the
construction of the
real rates
is
described
in
that
paper.)
Can the
monetary-contraction
story
survive
Figure
2?
Yes,
if
there is a
role for the nominal
interest
rate,
for a
given
real interest
rate.
And,
Figure
1
NOMINAL
INTEREST
RATES, SHORT, MEDIUM,
AND LONG: UNITED
STATES,
l
1966 TO 1992
15.0
-
SHORT NOMINAL
-
MEDIUM_NOMINAL
LONG
NOMINAL
Z
U
12.5
10.0
7.5\
5.0
2.5
66 68 70
72
'
74 76 78 80
'
8'2
84
86
8
8
90
92
t
I
I
I I
I I
I I
I I
I
I
I
I I
I I
Figure
2 REAL
INTEREST
RATES, SHORT,
MEDIUM,
AND LONG:
UNITED
STATES,
1966
TO
1992
10.0
SHORT_REAL
MEDIUM_REAL
LONG
REAL
7.5
5.0
2.5
^
0.0
-2.5
6 7-2.5
74I
i
7 78I I 8
8 I
I
I
-
6
'
68
70
72 74 76
78
80 82 84 86
88
90
92
C-)
00
00
\C
Q)
2
v^~~V
\^~I
190
*
BLANCHARD
based on
the
research
on the
interaction between
inflation,
taxation,
and
intermediation,
we can think of
a
number
of channels
through
which
nominal
rather than real rates
might
matter.
One
may
however
doubt
that the rather modest increase
in
nominal
rates could have been
enough
to
offset the effects
of low
real rates
and
generate
a
recession of
the size
observed
in
the mid-1970s.
The burden of
proof
is
on
the authors
on
this
one.
6. Controversial
Point 4: An Increase
in
the Price
of
Oil
Should
Have
No
Effect
on the
GDP
Deflator;
Yet
the
GDP
Deflator
Increased
Substantially
in the
Mid-1970s
The
argument
that
the
price
of
oil
should
not
affect
the
price
of
value
added-the
GDP
deflator-is
perfectly
valid as far
as it
goes,
that
is,
in
partial
equilibrium.
The
general-equilibrium
closure
offered
by
Barsky
and
Kilian,
with
fixed nominal
money
and fixed
employment,
is
not
convincing.
Once one uses
a more standard
macroeconomic
closure,
the
evidence
on
inflation
appears
quite
consistent
with
theory.
Let
me use
the standard
toy
model here.
Assume
that consumers
consume
a bundle
composed
of
a
produced
good
and
energy.
The
pro-
duced
good
is
produced
using
labor. Denote
by
Pv
the
(log) price
of
the
produced
good
(the
GDP
deflator),
by
x
the
(log)
relative
price
of
energy,
and
by
p
the
(log)
consumption
price
index
(the
CPI).
Then assume
p
=(1
-
0)
p
+
(p
+x),
pv=
,
w
=
ap
+
(1
-
a)p(-l)
+
ay,
y
=
m
-
p,
m
=bp,
b1l.
The
first
equation
states that
the
consumption price
index
is
a
weighted
average
of the
price
of
the
produced
good
and
the
price
of
energy,
with
0 as
the
share
of
energy
in
consumption.
The second
states
that
the
price
of
the
produced
good
is
equal
to the
nominal
wage
(the
constant
terms are
unimportant
here,
so
I
set
them
equal
to
zero).
The
third
equation
states
that the
consumption
wage depends
on
the
output
gap
y.
It
introduces
nominal
wage
rigidity
in the form
of a
depen-
dence
of
the
wage
on both
the current
and the
lagged
consumer
price
index.
The
fourth
equation
is
a reduced-form
aggregate
demand
equa-
tion
giving
the
demand
for
the
produced
good
as
a
function
of
real
money
balances.
The
last
equation
is
a
money
rule.
Comment 191
Solving
the model
is
straightforward.
For
simplicity,
let me
just
look
here
at the
limit
case
where
b
=
1,
so there
is full accommodation
by
the
central
bank,
and
y
remains constant
(the
difference with
Barsky
and
Kilian is that
constancy
of
output
is the
result of
monetary
accommoda-
tion,
so the nominal
money
stock
is
not
constant
but
endogenous).
In
this
case,
inflation is
given
by
Ox
Ap
=
(1
-
0) (1- a)
Apv
=
Aw
=
a
Ap
+
(1
-
a)
Ap
(-1).
Then:
An
increase
in
the
relative
price of energy
leads
to
positive
inflation,
measured
using
either the
CPI
or the GDP
deflator.
Even
if
the
share
of energy
in
consumption
is
small,
the
effect of
the relative
price
increase
on
inflation
can be
large.
(For
example, if
0
=
0.05 and
a =
0.5,
then
a 50%
increase
in the relative
price
of energy
leads to
an
increase in
inflation
of
5%.)
Inflation
measured
using
the GDP
deflator lags
inflation
measured
using
the
CPI.
This
is
very
much what
was observed
in
the mid-1970s. The mecha-
nism behind the increase
in
inflation is
straightforward.
Given
the
wage,
the
increase
in
the
price
of
oil
increases the CPI.
But
the
implied
decrease
in
consumption wages
leads
workers to ask
for
an
increase
in
nominal
wages,
which leads
in turn
to
an
increase
in
the GDP deflator. Under the
convenient
assumption
of
full
accommodation made
here,
inflation
goes
on
forever. Under the more realistic
assumption
of
partial
accommoda-
tion,
lower
output eventually puts
an
end
to
these
price
and
wage
in-
creases,
and
inflation
eventually
stops.
But
the
results
that
inflation lasts
for some
time,
it
can
be
quite large
relative
to the
shock,
and CPI infla-
tion
leads inflation
using
the
GDP
deflator
all remain.
7.
Conclusions
I
have
argued
that
money
cannot
be the
main
culprit
for
what
happened
in the
mid-1970s.
It
cannot
explain
stagflation.
The
behavior of
interest
rates does
not
fit.
And
most of the
movements
in
the
price
of
oil had
little to do with
monetary
policy.
192
*
BLINDER
Does this mean that
there are no
mysteries
left? The
answer
is
an
emphatic
no.
There is
plenty
we do not
understand about
what
hap-
pened
in
the
1970s,
and
more
generally
about the
price
of oil
and
eco-
nomic
activity.
The list of
puzzles
is well
known,
from
the
surprising
finding
by
Hamilton that
most U.S.
postwar
recessions have been
pre-
ceded
by
an
increase
in
the
price
of oil
(a
finding
which
may
turn
to
be
true once
more
in the
near
future),
to the
apparent asymmetry
between
the
effects
of
increases
and
decreases
in
the
price
of
oil,
to the
sheer size
of the two
recessions of the 1970s.
I
thank the two
authors
for
putting
the
issues
back on
the research
agenda.
REFERENCES
Adelman,
M.
(1993).
The Economics
of
Petroleum
Supply.
Cambridge,
MA: The MIT
Press.
Blanchard,
0.
(1993).
The
equity
premium.
Brookings
Papers
on Economic
Activity
2:75-138.
Comment
ALAN S. BLINDER
Princeton
University
This is
a
fascinating
paper,
one which is well
worth
reading.
It
more
than
repays
the time
you spend digesting
it. It
was
also,
obviously,
meant
to
be
a
provocative
paper,
and
I
was,
appropriately,
provoked.
In
my
book
Economic
Policy
and the
Great
Stagflation
(Blinder, 1979),
which
I
dusted off
to
prepare
this
comment,
I
considered the
monetary
(dare
I
say
"monetarist"?)
explanation
of the
episode
and
concluded
as follows:
"If
I
were forced
to
summarize
the
influence
of the
Fed
on
the Great
Stagflation,
I
guess
I would
stress
how
little
difference
it
made rather
than how
much."
Barsky
and
Kilian
reach
a
rather
different conclusion.
Why?
Was
I
so
wrong
in
1979?
Frankly,
I find
very
few errors of commission
in the
paper.
So
the
hunt
must be for errors
of omission.
The
paper
reads
a
bit
like a
selective
legal
brief
prepared
by
a
pair
of
clever
trial
lawyers.
So
I'll
try
to
add
a
few
arguments
for the defense
(of
the
conventional
wisdom)
and
point
out
that
some
of
the conclusions
that
they portray
as
contrary
to
that wis-
dom are
actually quite
well
known.
Leaving
out
many
interesting
details,
their
argument
comes
in
five
parts,
and I'll
take
each
up
in turn.
192
*
BLINDER
Does this mean that
there are no
mysteries
left? The
answer
is
an
emphatic
no.
There is
plenty
we do not
understand about
what
hap-
pened
in
the
1970s,
and
more
generally
about the
price
of oil
and
eco-
nomic
activity.
The list of
puzzles
is well
known,
from
the
surprising
finding
by
Hamilton that
most U.S.
postwar
recessions have been
pre-
ceded
by
an
increase
in
the
price
of oil
(a
finding
which
may
turn
to
be
true once
more
in the
near
future),
to the
apparent asymmetry
between
the
effects
of
increases
and
decreases
in
the
price
of
oil,
to the
sheer size
of the two
recessions of the 1970s.
I
thank the two
authors
for
putting
the
issues
back on
the research
agenda.
REFERENCES
Adelman,
M.
(1993).
The Economics
of
Petroleum
Supply.
Cambridge,
MA: The MIT
Press.
Blanchard,
0.
(1993).
The
equity
premium.
Brookings
Papers
on Economic
Activity
2:75-138.
Comment
ALAN S. BLINDER
Princeton
University
This is
a
fascinating
paper,
one which is well
worth
reading.
It
more
than
repays
the time
you spend digesting
it. It
was
also,
obviously,
meant
to
be
a
provocative
paper,
and
I
was,
appropriately,
provoked.
In
my
book
Economic
Policy
and the
Great
Stagflation
(Blinder, 1979),
which
I
dusted off
to
prepare
this
comment,
I
considered the
monetary
(dare
I
say
"monetarist"?)
explanation
of the
episode
and
concluded
as follows:
"If
I
were forced
to
summarize
the
influence
of the
Fed
on
the Great
Stagflation,
I
guess
I would
stress
how
little
difference
it
made rather
than how
much."
Barsky
and
Kilian
reach
a
rather
different conclusion.
Why?
Was
I
so
wrong
in
1979?
Frankly,
I find
very
few errors of commission
in the
paper.
So
the
hunt
must be for errors
of omission.
The
paper
reads
a
bit
like a
selective
legal
brief
prepared
by
a
pair
of
clever
trial
lawyers.
So
I'll
try
to
add
a
few
arguments
for the defense
(of
the
conventional
wisdom)
and
point
out
that
some
of
the conclusions
that
they portray
as
contrary
to
that wis-
dom are
actually quite
well
known.
Leaving
out
many
interesting
details,
their
argument
comes
in
five
parts,
and I'll
take
each
up
in turn.
Comment 193
1.
A
PURELY
MONETARIST
MODEL
OF
GO-STOP POLICY
GIVES
A
GOOD
EXPLA-
NATION
OF THE
STAGFLATIONARY
EVENTS OF
THE 1970s.
The authors
indeed demonstrate
that
they
can calibrate a
relatively
simple
model of
go-stop monetary policy
that matches the
cyclical
facts
without ever
mentioning
oil
prices.
Or
can
they?
When I
read,
in the last
paragraph
of Section
3,
of a
predicted
"output
trough
in
early
1987"
that
"closely
mirrors" the
facts,
I
wondered
what facts those were.
I never
noticed
a
1987
trough,
and neither did the
NBER
dating
committee.
Incidentally,
the model doesn't even need
the
"stop"
part
of
"go-stop"
to
generate
stagflation.
As we
have
all
known
for
years,
the
"go" part
alone is
enough.
In
a
textbook
aggregate-demand-aggregate-supply
dia-
gram,
if a
burst of
demand
growth
(it
need
not be
generated
by
money)
leads the
economy
to overshoot
its
potential
output,
the
adjustment
back
to
equilibrium
will entail
bothfalling
output
and
rising
prices.
Or,
moving
up
a
derivative
to the
Phillips-curve
diagram,
overshooting
the natural
rate
will
lead to
an
adjustment period
in
which
both
unemployment
and
inflation are
rising
at the same time.
Many
of
us have
demonstrated this
well-known conclusion
to
our
Economics
101 students-without
using
difference
equations.1
2. THERE
IS ABUNDANT EVIDENCE
IN
FAVOR OF
THE
MONETARY EXPLANATION.
It
is one
thing
to claim
that a
certain
type
of
model
can
explain
a
phenomenon;
it is
quite
another to claim
that
the
proffered explanation
is
empirically
relevant. So
Barsky
and
Kilian
marshal
a
variety
of
empiri-
cal
support
for
their
monetary explanation
of
stagflation.
But
I
am
not
entirely
convinced.
For
example, they
show
that
several bursts of
money growth
occurred
at
approximately
the
right
times to set off
go-stop
(or
just go-adjust)
cycles.
But
they
never mention the
(often
simultaneous and
offsetting)
shifts
of
velocity-the
very things
that
eventually
led
almost
all
econo-
mists and
policymakers
to abandon monetarism.
One
example
comes
in
1970 and
1971,
when
sharp
declines
in
velocity
seemed to validate
Ar-
thur Burns's
perspicacious
(or
was
it
lucky?)
prediction
that
falling
veloc-
ity
would
obviate most of the
dangers
of
rapid money
growth.
A
second
example
is the
apparent
downward shift
of the
conventional
money
demand
equation
in
1974-1976,
which
Steve Goldfeld
dubbed
"The
Case of the
Missing
Money."2
1.
See,
for
example,
W.
J.
Baumol
and A.
S. Blinder
(1999),
Economics:
Principles
and
Policy,
8th
ed.,
Harcourt,
pp.
590-591.
2.
S.
M.
Goldfeld
(1976),
The
Case of the
Missing Money, Brookings Papers
on
Economic
Activity
3:683-730.
194
*
BLINDER
I
do not
wish
to
dispute
the claim that a
go-stop
cycle
occurred
in
the
United States
in
1972-1973.
It did. But
it
seems
a
grave
omission to
forget
the
role of fiscal
policy.
This was
the infamous
period
in which
President
Nixon
opened
the federal coffers to
assist
his
1972
reelection
campaign,
and then
shut
them
abruptly
in
1973. Years
ago,
Goldfeld
and
I
constructed econometric-model-based measures
of fiscal
policy
which
show
a titanic
runup
in
fiscal stimulus
from
1969 to
a
peak
in 1971
and
then an
abrupt plunge
to
fiscal restraint
in
1973.3
Yes,
it was
an
aggregate-demand
story;
but
money growth
was
not
the
only
actor.
3. THE
BURST
OF WORLD
MONEY
GROWTH WAS LARGELY DUE TO
THE BREAK-
DOWN OF THE
BRETTON
WOODS
CONSTRAINTS ON
MONEY CREATION.
I
have no
quarrel
with
highlighting
the end of the Bretton
Woods
system
as an
explanation
for the
high money growth
rates
that
followed,
not
only
in
the
United
States
but
in
other countries.
But
think
about the
timing
for a
minute. The old
system
of
fixed
exchange
rates died not
all at
once,
but rather
in
stages
between
August
1971 and
early
1973. That
seems
a bit
early
to
account
for
rapid money
growth
in 1971 and
1972,
followed
by stagflation
starting
in
late 1973.
The Nixon reelection
campaign-to
which
his
friend
Arthur Burns contributed from
the
Fed-is
a more
convincing explanation
(or
at least
a
partner
in
crime)
for
the
United
States.
4. THE SUPPLY-SHOCK
THEORY OF
STAGFLATION
GIVES
NO REASON
TO THINK
THAT INFLATION MEASURED
BY THE
GDP
DEFLATOR
SHOULD RISE.
Barksy
and
Kilian do shoot
at
least
one hole
in the
supply-shock
theory:
It
gives
no
reason
to
think
the GDP deflator-as
opposed
to
some
index
of consumer
prices-should
rise more
rapidly
after
an
oil
shock.
Empirically,
of
course,
it
did.
This
is
a
legitimate
criticism of
the
conventional
wisdom-which
does
not,
of
course,
apply
to
analyses
that
focus
on
consumer-price
inflation.4
Their
point
is
really
much
simpler
than the
way
they
make it
in
the
paper.
Just
remember
that Y=C+I+G+X-IM
(another
thing
we teach
our
Economics
101
students),
and
you
will notice
that
IM
enters
with
a
minus
sign.
In
the
simple,
limiting
case
that
all
imported
oil is consumed
and
no real
quantities
are affected
by
an
oil
shock,
nominal
C and nominal
IM
would rise
by
identical
amounts,
leaving
nominal
GDP
and
all
real
magnitudes
unchanged.
Thus the
GDP deflator
would
be
unchanged.
3.
A.
S.
Blinder
and S.
M.
Goldfeld
(1976),
New
measures of
fiscal
and
monetary policy,
1958-1973,
American Economic
Review
66(December):780-796.
4.
This caused
me to
check
my
own
past
work.
Fortunately,
it
was all about
consumer-price
inflation.
Discussion
*
195
This,
of
course,
is a
rather
unrealistic account of the
way
our
economy
reacts
to an oil shock.
But it
does
point
out
that
we need a more
compli-
cated
theory-involving,
say,
markups
and
wage-price
interactions-to
explain why
an
oil shock boosts
the GDP deflator.
Having
said
that,
if
we
resist
the conclusion that
oil
shocks
are
inherently
stagflationary,
we
have
quite
a
few
coincidences
to
explain-as
is
clear,
e.g.,
from
the
work of
Jim
Hamilton
(cited
in
the
paper)
or
Carruth,
Hooker,
and Oswald
(1998).5
5.
THE
FACT
THAT
OIL PRICES ROSE
FIRST AND STAGFLATION
FOLLOWED LATER
IS
LARGELY
EXPLAINED BY
REVERSE CAUSATION:
IT WAS
MONETARY-INDUCED
BOOMS
THAT
PUSHED
OIL PRICES UP.
Thus do
Barsky
and
Kilian
elide
the aforementioned coincidences.
If I
may paraphrase Shakespeare,
methinks the
gentlemen
doth
protest
too
much on this
point.
The
simple
conventional
wisdom holds
that movements
in
the
price
of
oil
(which
are
purely
exogenous)
drive the
economy-or,
in a
variant,
that
oil
prices
drive
monetary policy,
which in turn
drives
the
economy.6
The
Barsky-Kilian
model,
by
contrast,
holds
that
monetary policy
drives the
economy,
which
in
turn
drives the
(now
purely
endogenous) price
of oil.
In
fact,
reasonable
people
do
not have to choose
either
of
these two
extremes.
Two-way
causation is
fine-and,
indeed,
I
think
that's where
Barsky
and Kilian
actually
come out
in
the end.
On the "oil
prices
are
endogenous"
side,
there is
surely
truth to the notion that
strong
world-
wide
macroeconomic conditions made
it
easier
for the
OPEC
cartel
to
work.
[But
didn't
Rotemberg
and
Saloner
(1986)
argue
that
cartels
break
up
in
booms?7]
But on
the "oil
prices
are
exogenous"
side,
I
think it is a
mistake to
argue
that
money growth
caused
the
Yom
Kippur
War
or the
fall of
the Shah.
Indeed,
don't
events like those
give
econometricians
their best
shot
at
cutting
the Gordian knot of
simultaneity?
Discussion
Robert
Barsky explained
that
the main aim
of the
paper
was
to cast
doubt on
the received
wisdom
that
stagflation
in
the
1970s
was
a
result
of an
aggregate
supply
shift
alone.
In
response
to
Olivier
Blanchard's
5. A.
Carruth,
M.
Hooker,
and A.
Oswald
(1998),
Input
prices
and
unemployment
equilib-
ria:
Theory
and
evidence
for
the United
States,
Review
of
Economics and
Statistics
LXXX,
pp.
621-628.
6.
See
Bernanke, Gertler,
and
Watson
(1997).
7.
I realize
that
other theorists
have
argued
that
strong
market conditions
help
cartels
hold
together.
That's
one of the nice
features of
economic
theory.
Discussion
*
195
This,
of
course,
is a
rather
unrealistic account of the
way
our
economy
reacts
to an oil shock.
But it
does
point
out
that
we need a more
compli-
cated
theory-involving,
say,
markups
and
wage-price
interactions-to
explain why
an
oil shock boosts
the GDP deflator.
Having
said
that,
if
we
resist
the conclusion that
oil
shocks
are
inherently
stagflationary,
we
have
quite
a
few
coincidences
to
explain-as
is
clear,
e.g.,
from
the
work of
Jim
Hamilton
(cited
in
the
paper)
or
Carruth,
Hooker,
and Oswald
(1998).5
5.
THE
FACT
THAT
OIL PRICES ROSE
FIRST AND STAGFLATION
FOLLOWED LATER
IS
LARGELY
EXPLAINED BY
REVERSE CAUSATION:
IT WAS
MONETARY-INDUCED
BOOMS
THAT
PUSHED
OIL PRICES UP.
Thus do
Barsky
and
Kilian
elide
the aforementioned coincidences.
If I
may paraphrase Shakespeare,
methinks the
gentlemen
doth
protest
too
much on this
point.
The
simple
conventional
wisdom holds
that movements
in
the
price
of
oil
(which
are
purely
exogenous)
drive the
economy-or,
in a
variant,
that
oil
prices
drive
monetary policy,
which in turn
drives
the
economy.6
The
Barsky-Kilian
model,
by
contrast,
holds
that
monetary policy
drives the
economy,
which
in
turn
drives the
(now
purely
endogenous) price
of oil.
In
fact,
reasonable
people
do
not have to choose
either
of
these two
extremes.
Two-way
causation is
fine-and,
indeed,
I
think
that's where
Barsky
and Kilian
actually
come out
in
the end.
On the "oil
prices
are
endogenous"
side,
there is
surely
truth to the notion that
strong
world-
wide
macroeconomic conditions made
it
easier
for the
OPEC
cartel
to
work.
[But
didn't
Rotemberg
and
Saloner
(1986)
argue
that
cartels
break
up
in
booms?7]
But on
the "oil
prices
are
exogenous"
side,
I
think it is a
mistake to
argue
that
money growth
caused
the
Yom
Kippur
War
or the
fall of
the Shah.
Indeed,
don't
events like those
give
econometricians
their best
shot
at
cutting
the Gordian knot of
simultaneity?
Discussion
Robert
Barsky explained
that
the main aim
of the
paper
was
to cast
doubt on
the received
wisdom
that
stagflation
in
the
1970s
was
a
result
of an
aggregate
supply
shift
alone.
In
response
to
Olivier
Blanchard's
5. A.
Carruth,
M.
Hooker,
and A.
Oswald
(1998),
Input
prices
and
unemployment
equilib-
ria:
Theory
and
evidence
for
the United
States,
Review
of
Economics and
Statistics
LXXX,
pp.
621-628.
6.
See
Bernanke, Gertler,
and
Watson
(1997).
7.
I realize
that
other theorists
have
argued
that
strong
market conditions
help
cartels
hold
together.
That's
one of the nice
features of
economic
theory.
196
*
DISCUSSION
discussion,
he
raised the
possibility
that,
with
sufficiently responsive
expectations
on
the
part
of the "awake"
firms,
the model
in
the
paper
might generate expected
inflation
greater
than
lagged
inflation.
On car-
tels,
he said
that the
links between interest
rates,
output,
and
cartel
power
could
go
in
both directions.
In
particular,
when
interest rates
are
low and
output
is
high,
the incentives to cheat
might
be less.
Barsky
responded
to
Alan Blinder's
discussion
by
saying
that
monetary
over-
shooting
could lead
to a
stagflation
in
the
model.
This result
depended
on
the amount
of
"sleepiness"
in
firms
and
the
endogeneity
of
monetary
policy.
He stressed
the
similarity
between their
paper
and
Bernanke,
Gertler,
and Watson
(1997),
the
main
difference
being
that their
paper
argued
that the
Fed
was
responding
to
commodity
price
inflation
alone,
rather than to
inflation
in
both
commodity
and oil
prices
as
in
BGW.
Barsky agreed
with Blinder that
Arthur
Burns
might
have loosened
money
supply
to
help
Nixon's
re-election,
but
he
noted that
commodity
price
inflation
gave
Burns the excuse
he
needed.
Mark Gertler
suggested
that,
because of
the
regulation
of
depository
institutions
in the
1970s,
increases
in nominal interest rates
could
have
had an
effect
on economic
activity
even without
increases
in real rates.
For evidence
on this
point,
he
suggested
that
the
authors
look
at
what
happened
to
housing
in 1973.
He
agreed
with Blanchard
that more than
a
purely
monetary story
was
necessary
to
explain
the combination
of low
growth
and
high
inflation
of
the
early
1970s. Gertler
noted
the
potential
role
of the
productivity
slowdown
in 1972 and the
resulting
decline
in
growth;
it
could
be
argued
that
the
Fed,
failing
to
understand
what was
happening,
eased
policy,
leading
to
high
inflation. He
put
forward
the
possibility
that the
opposite
has
happened
in
recent
years,
during
which
productivity
has
surged
and inflation
has
been
low.
Michael
Klein remarked
that
the
exchange-rate
channel
was one
way
that
a
monetary expansion
might
have fed
into
a
rise
in the dollar
price
of
oil. Charles
Engel
followed
up
on this comment
by
saying
that,
until
1990,
a dollar
depreciation
was related to
an increase
in
the
price
of
oil,
and vice
versa.
A
possible
explanation
is that
oil was
priced
in
dollars.
When the dollar
fell,
the oil
price
fell
in
Europe
and
Japan,
increasing
world demand
and the
world
price
of
oil.
This
could
be consistent
with
a
money-based
account
if
money growth
caused
the
depreciation.
The
problem
is
that
empirical
studies have
not found
a
close
connection
between
monetary policy
and
exchange-rate
changes
in the short
run.
David
Romer
agreed
with
the
general
point
made
by
the authors
that
something
more than
an oil
price
shock
was
necessary
to
explain
the
1970s.
He was
worried
by
the fact
that,
though
an
oil-price-shock
story
works
well for
the
1970s,
oil
prices
are
rarely
invoked
to
explain
the
Discussion 197
events of
the
past
20
years.
Blinder
responded
that an
oil-price
story
would work for
the 1990 recession.
Barsky
and Romer
disagreed,
saying
there
was
no
stagflation
in
1990.
Greg
Mankiw
suggested
that a benefi-
cial
oil
shock
helps
to
explain
the
economy's
behavior
in
1986. Olivier
Blanchard said
that no
doubling
of the
price
of oil had
happened
outside
the 1970s. He maintained
that the one
thing
that would
be
fatal
to
the oil
story
would be a
doubling
of the
price
of oil
with no
subsequent
reces-
sion. Blinder remarked
that 1997-1998
was characterized
by
a fall in
oil
prices,
a
boom,
and low inflation.
Ben
Bernanke noted that
in the VAR
literature
that tries to look
at
the
effect of
oil
prices
on the real
economy,
it is
hard
to
find a reliable
statistical
link
between
indicators of oil
price
shocks and
subsequent
output
movements.
But
there
would be some
inflationary
effect
that
leads to
a
policy response.
Tom
Sargent
took
up
the
point, saying
that in
a model with
vintages
of
capital,
it is
difficult
to find
large
real
effects
of
oil
prices.
David Laibson
pointed
out that
in
an
[S,s]
model
of
capital
formation,
the effects of oil
prices
would be nonlinear.
Dramatic
price
shocks
in
either
direction could
depress output through scrapping
of
capital.
This
nonlin-
earity
could
explain
why
the
increases
in
oil
prices
of the 1970s
depressed
activity,
while
falling prices
in
the
1980s had
ambiguous
effects.
Mankiw
remarked
that the issue
of
modeling
sleepy
firms was an
important
one,
as the
dynamics
of the
model are
sensitive
to how
sleepi-
ness is
modeled.
He
said
that while economists have
a
good
idea of how
to
model
awake
firms,
they
did
not
yet
have
good
models of
sleepiness.
In
response
to the
general
discussion,
Lutz Kilian reiterated the
key
point
that the
prices
of other commodities rose before the
price
of oil rose
in 1973. Oil
prices
were different
in
that
they
remained
high
while other
commodity prices
fell.
He
suggested
that the success of the cartel could
explain
why
oil
prices
remained
high.
Kilian
questioned
the
link
be-
tween events such as the Yom
Kippur
War
and the
fall
of the
Shah
of
Iran
on
the
one
hand,
and oil
prices
rises
on the
other,
on the
grounds
that
the
timing
was not
right.
He
emphasized
that
embargoes
could be en-
dogenous. Barsky
agreed, noting
that
disruptions
in
the Middle
East
don't
always
raise the
price
of
oil.
Rather,
embargoes
are
imposed
when
it is
profitable
for oil
producers
to do so.