BEFORE
THE
DEPARTMENT
OF
TRANSPORTATION
WASHINGTON,
D.C.
Joint
Application
of
)
AIR
CANADA
)
THE
AUSTRIAN
GROUP
)
BRITISH
MIDLAND
AIRWAYS
LTD
)
CONTINENTAL
AIRLINES,
INC.
)
DEUTSCHE
LUFTHANSA
AG
)
Docket
OST-2008-0234
POLSKIE
LINIE
LOTNIECZE
LOT
S.A.
)
SCANDINAVIAN
AIRLINES
SYSTEM
)
SWISS
INTERNATIONAL
AIR
LINES
LTD.
)
TAP
AIR
PORTUGAL
)
UNITED
AIR
LINES,
INC.
)
)
to
Amend
Order
2007-2-16
under
49
U.S.C.
§§
)
41308
and
41309
so
as
to
Approve
and
Confer
)
Antitrust
Immunity
)
PUBLIC
VERSION
COMMENTS
OF
THE
DEPARTMENT
OF
JUSTICE
ON
THE
SHOW
CAUSE
ORDER
Christine
A.
Varney
Communications
with
respect
to
this
document
Assistant
Attorney
General
should
be
addressed
to:
Antitrust
Division
Donna
N.
Kooperstein
Chief
Molly
S.
Boast
William
H.
Stallings
Carl
Shapiro
Assistant
Chief
Deputy Assistant
Attorneys
General
Jill
A.
Ptacek
Michael
D.
Billiel
Oliver
M.
Richard
Tracey
D.
Chambers
Assistant
Chief
Robert
D.
Young
William
H.
Gillespie
Attorneys
Economist
Transportation,
Energy,
and
Economic
Analysis
Group
Agriculture
Section
U.S.
Department
of
Justice
450
Fifth
Street,
N.W.
Washington,
DC
20530
Telephone:
202/307-6607;
Facsimile:
202/307-2784
June
26,
2009
E-mail:
jill.
ptacek@u
sdo
j
.gov
TABLE
OF
CONTENTS
I.
Summary
of
Comments
.........................................................................................................
1
II.
Background
..........................................................................................................................
.3
A.
The
Star
Alliance
and
its
immunized
components
..............................................
.3
B.
Continental
s
request
to
join
Star
and
receive
antitrust
immunity
.....................
.
5
C.
The
Show
Cause
Order
..........................................................................................
.8
III.
The
Statutory
Scheme
Disfavors
Immunity
and
Places
a
Significant
Burden
on
the
Applicants
to
Justify
Their
Request
....................................................................................
10
A.
Antitrust
enforcement
plays
a
central
role
in
the
deregulated
airline
industry
..
11
B.
Applicants
must
show
that
immunity
is
required
by
the
public
interest
.............
12
IV.
DOT
Should
Deny
the
Broad
Application
for
Immunity
................................................
13
V.
Immunizing
an
Alliance
that
Includes
Continental
and
the
Other
Star
ATI
Members
Risks
Significant
Competitive
Harm
in
Certain
Markets
................................................
16
A.
Analyzing
the
competitive
effects
of
the
Joint
Application
agreements
.............
16
B.
Competition
on
non-transatlantic
routes
...............................................................
18
C.
Competition
on
transatlantic
routes
.......................................................................
20
1
.
Nonstop
service
is
a
separate
product
market
..........................................
21
2.
Nonstop
overlap
on
specific
transatlantic
routes
......................................
23
3.
The
loss
of
a
nonstop
competitor
is
likely
to
result
in
significant
fare
increases
.......................................................................................................
24
4.
Nonstop
entry
is
unlikely
............................................................................
25
D.
Competition
on
transborder
routes
.......................................................................
26
E.
Competition
on
domestic
routes
...........................................................................
28
VI.
The
Applicants
Make
No
Showing
Why
Immunity
Is
Required
to
Achieve
the
Claimed
Public
Benefits
Arising
from
the
Joint
Application
Agreements
....................................
29
A.
The
Applicants
assertion
that
they
will
not
move
forward
without
immunity
is
not
convincing
.........................................................................................................
31
B.
The
Applicants
exaggerate
their
claim
that
significant
litigation
risks
exist
absent
immunity
.......................................................................................................
33
C.
The
Applicants
inflate
the
importance
of
inter-alliance
competition
.................
34
D.
Immunity
will
not
advance
open
skies
.................................................................
35
E.
The
Applicants
overemphasize
the
likelihood
that
immunity
for
the
proposed
alliance
will
substantially
reduce
double
marginalization
....................................
35
VII.
Any
Grant
of
Antitrust
Immunity
Should
Include
Restrictions
to
Limit
Potential
Anticompetitive
Effects
.......................................................................................................
37
A.
Carve
out
nonstop
overlap
routes
.........................................................................
37
B.
Deny
global
immunity
............................................................................................
41
VIII.
Conclusion
............................................................................................................................
43
Appendix
A:
China/Beijing
...........................................................
................................................
45
Appendix
A:
China/Hong
Kong
..................................................
................................................
46
Appendix
B:
Empirical
Addendum
............................................
................................................
47
COMMENTS
OF
THE
DEPARTMENT
OF
JUSTICE
ON
THE
SHOW
CAUSE
ORDER
The
United
States
Department
of
Justice
(
DOJ
)
hereby
submits
its
comments
to
the
Department
of
Transportation
’s
(
DOT
)
Show
Cause
Order
(
Order
)
in
the
matter
of
the
Joint
Application
of
Air
Canada,
the
Austrian
Group
(
Austrian
),
British
Midland
Airways
Ltd
(
BMI
),
Continental
Airlines,
Inc.
(
Continental”
),
Deutsche
Lufthansa
AG
(
Lufthansa
),
Polskie
Linie
Lotniecze
Lot
S.A.
(
LOT
),
Scandinavian
Airlines
System
(
SAS
),
Swiss
International
Air
Lines
Ltd
(
Swiss”
),
TAP
Air
Portugal
(
TAP
)
and
United
Air
Lines,
Inc.
(
“United
)
(collectively,
the
“Joint
Applicants
or
Applicants
)
to
Amend
Order
2007-2-16
under
49
U.S.C.
§§
41308
and
41309
so
as
to
Approve
and
Confer
Antitrust
Immunity
(the
“Joint
Application
or
J.A.
).
I.
Summary
of
Comments
Antitrust
enforcement
has
played
a
vital
role
in
bringing
increased
competition
and
consumer
benefits
to
the
deregulated
airline
industry.
Accordingly,
any
exemptions
from
the
antitrust
laws
should
be
strongly
disfavored.
To
overcome
the
presumption
against
antitrust
immunity,
applicants
must
demonstrate
that
their
collaboration
will
generate
significant
public
benefits
that
outweigh
any
harm
to
competition,
that
they
cannot
achieve
those
benefits
without
immunity,
and
that
they
have
narrowly
tailored
the
requested
immunity
to
achieve
the
benefits
claimed.
For
many
past
applications,
the
principal
public
interest
benefit
furthered
by
DOT
s
grant
of
immunity
has
been
the
negotiation
of
open
skies
agreements
with
the
home
country
of
the
U.S.
carriers
alliance
partners.
In
the
present
matter,
open
skies
agreements
have
been
signed
with
the
home
countries
of
all
the
foreign
applicants,
and
those
foreign
carriers
will
continue
to
be
members
of
the
immunized
alliances
whatever
DOT
decides
here.
Granting
immunity
for
Continental
to
coordinate
with
Star
ATI
Alliance
1
members
on
U.S.
to
Latin
American
or
Pacific
routes
is
not
likely
to
result
in
further
liberalization
discussions
between
the
U.S.
and
countries
with
which
we
have
not
yet
negotiated
open
skies,
such
as
China
or
Brazil.
Therefore,
an
expansion
of
immunity
offers
no
open
skies
benefits
for
U.S.
consumers.
Where
an
application
does
not
directly
promote
open
skies
with
its
attendant
consumer
benefits,
applicants
bear
a
heavy
burden
to
prove
benefits
specific
to
their
alliance
agreements
that
justify
immunity.
Where
an
application
involves
the
presence
of
two
major
domestic
competitors,
the
request
for
immunity
warrants
particularly
close
scrutiny.
DOJ
believes
the
Joint
Applicants
have
failed
to
demonstrate
the
required
elements
for
the
broad
immunity
sought
-
immunity
encompassing
transborder,
transatlantic
and
transpacific
markets
without
regard
to
the
planned
level
of
integration
among
Applicants
-
and
that
DOT
should
deny
the
broad
requested
immunity
and
instead
grant
a
more
limited
immunity.
In
considering
the
Joint
Applicants
immunity
request,
we
urge
DOT
to
take
into
account
the
following
DOJ
conclusions:
The
Applicants
proposed
elimination
of
competition
between
United
and
Continental
for
transpacific
and
Latin
American
service
threatens
competitive
harm
in
markets
where
entry
is
limited
by
restrictive
bilateral
agreements.
It
will,
for
example,
substantially
lessen
competition
in
city
pairs
between
the
U.S.
and
Beijing,
where
United
and
1
As
described
in
greater
detail
below,
the
Star
Alliance
is
an
alliance
of
more
than
20
U.S.
and
international
airlines
that
interact
together
at
many
levels
without
antitrust
immunity.
The
Star
ATI
Alliance
is
a
subset
of
nine
Star
Alliance
members
that
have
received
authority
from
DOT
to
coordinate
on
an
immunized
basis.
Two
of
the
Star
ATI
members
-
United
and
Lufthansa
-
have
yet
another
alliance
agreement,
proscribing
a
greater
level
of
integration
than
found
in
the
arrangements
between
the
Star
ATI
members
at
large,
for
which
DOT
has also
granted
antitrust
immunity.
United
and
Lufthansa
refer
to
that
alliance
as
the
Atlantic
Plus
or
A+
agreement.
2
Continental
provide
substantial
connecting
service.
The
Applicants
have
provided
no
concrete
plans
for
cooperation
in
non-transat
l
antic
markets,
let
alone
established
that
immunity
is
necessary
to
achieve
specific
benefits.
A
DOT
grant
of
immunity
for
two
U.S.
carriers
to
coordinate
their
international
operations
outside
of
an
explicit
joint
venture
with
foreign
carriers
would
be
unprecedented.
The
Applicants
proposed
elimination
of
competition
between
Continental
and
Air
Canada
on
U.S.-Canada
routes
(
transborder
routes
)
will
substantially
limit
competitive
alternatives
on
certain
transborder
routes
where
entry
is
unlikely.
Applicants
have
provided
no
plans
detailing
any
future
integration
between
the
parties
and
hence
no
justification
for
this
immunity
request.
The
Applicants
proposed
elimination
of
competition
between
Continental
and
SAS,
Swiss
and
TAP
(as a
function
of
Continental
joining
the
Star
ATI
Alliance)
will
likely
result
in
competitive
harm
for
consumers
in
several
transatlantic
markets,
including
New
York
-
Stockholm,
New
York-Copenhagen,
New
York-Geneva,
New
York-Zurich,
and
New
York-Lisbon.
The
Applicants
have
offered
little,
if
any,
evidence
to
show
that
immunity
between
Continental
and
the
nine
Star
ATI
alliance
members
is
necessary
to
achieve
any
benefits,
or
to
support
their
failure
to
carve
out
these
particular
markets
from
their
immunity
request.
The
Applicants
proposed
elimination
of
competition
between
United
and
Lufthansa
in
the
Dulles-Frankfurt
and
Chicago-Frankfurt
markets
(by
removing
the
existing
carve
outs
to
immunity)
will
likely
lead
to
higher
fares.
Applicants
have
offered
no
evidence
showing
(1)
that
they
need
to
remove
the
carve
outs
to
achieve
specific
benefits
and
(2)
that
the
value
to
consumers
of
those
benefits
outweighs
the
likely
competitive
harm.
Because
the
Applicants
include
two
large,
domestic
competitors,
a
sweeping
grant
of
immunity
raises
significant
concerns
about
harm
to
domestic
competition,
a
risk
that
cannot
be
completely
mitigated
through
confidentiality
guidelines.
Thus,
the
request
for
immunity
should
be
viewed
with
enhanced
skepticism.
II.
Background
A.
The
Star
Alliance
and
its
immunized
components
The
member
airlines
of
the
Star
Alliance
together
operate
flights
to
over
900
destinations
worldwide.
Its
founding
-
and
principal
members
--
-
include:
United-.
United,
the
third
largest
U.S.
airline
with
over
$20
billion
in
annual
revenue,
has
hubs
in
Chicago,
Denver,
San
Francisco,
Los
Angeles
and
Washington,
D.C.
United
offers
international
service
to
Canada,
Europe,
Asia,
and
Latin
America.
In
addition
to
its
immunized
participation
in
the
Star
ATI
3
3
Alliance
(described
below)
and
its
longstanding
immunized
cooperation
with
Lufthansa,
United
also
has
bilateral
immunized
relationships
with
Asiana
and
Air
New
Zealand
that
exist
independent
of
United
’s
relationships
with
the
other
Star
participants.
Lufthansa
:
.
Lufthansa
is
one
of
the
world
s
largest
airlines,
with
hubs
in
Frankfurt
and
Munich
and
over
$35
billion
in
annual
revenue.
Lufthansa
owns
100%
of
Swiss,
and
has
significant
ownership
interests
in
BMI
and
JetBlue.
Lufthansa
provides
extensive
service
to
the
United
States.
Air
Canada
:
.
Air
Canada
is
the
largest
provider
of
scheduled
passenger
service
in
the
Canadian
market,
the
Canada-U.S.
transborder
markets,
and
in
the
international
markets
to
and
from
Canada.
Air
Canada
has
hubs
in
Toronto,
Montreal,
Vancouver
and
Calgary,
and
provides
service
directly
to
numerous
destinations
in
the
United
States
and
cities
in
Europe,
Asia,
and
Latin
America.
The
Star
Alliance
includes
eighteen
additional
members,
2
all
of
which
have
agreed
to
provide
Alliance
customers
certain
joint
services
such
as
codesharing,
coordinated
processes
for
reservations
and
baggage
transfer,
through-ticketing,
frequent
flyer
reciprocity,
and
lounge
sharing.
Star
members
interact
with
one
another
with
varying
degrees
of
integration
and
across
various
sets
of
markets.
The
full
group
of
twenty-one
members
operates
without
antitrust
immunity.
For
example,
US
Airways
participation
in
the
Star
Alliance
is
not
subject
to
antitrust
immunity;
therefore,
the
2
The
current
members
of
the
Star
Alliance
are
United,
Lufthansa,
Air
Canada,
Air
China,
Air
New
Zealand,
ANA,
Asiana
Airlines,
Austrian,
BMI,
Egyptair,
LOT,
SAS,
Shanghai
Airlines,
Singapore
Airlines,
South
African
Airways,
Spanair,
Swiss,
TAP,
Turkish
Airways,
THAI
and
US
Airways.
Star also
has
three
regional
members:
Adria
Airways,
Bluel
and
Croatia
Airlines.
4
antitrust
laws
fully
apply
to
its
collaboration
with
other
Star
members
-
including
that
with
its
domestic
rival
United.
Certain
Star
members,
however,
have
entered
into
more
extensive
agreements
with
one
another
for
which
they
have
requested
-
and
received
-
antitrust
immunity
from
DOT:
The
United/Lufthansa
Joint
Venture:
In
1996,
United
and
Lufthansa
received
antitrust
immunity
to
coordinate
pricing,
scheduling
and
other
activities
as
part
of
their
alliance
agreement.
DOT
imposed
carve
outs
from
the
immunity
for
the
Frankfurt
to
Chicago/Washington
routes
-
the
only
routes
then
served
by
both
airlines
on
a
nonstop
basis.
The
carve
outs
remained
following
each
subsequent
renewal
of
the
United/Lufthansa
immunity
grant
and
each
expansion
of
the
membership
of
the
Star
ATI
Alliance.
The
two
carriers
instituted
revenue
sharing
in
2003,
when
they
changed
the
name
of
the
venture
to
the
Atlantic
Plus
(
A+
)
Alliance.
*
The
Star
ATI
Alliance:
United,
Air
Canada,
Lufthansa
and
six
other
Star
members
5
have
entered
into
a
coordination
agreement
to
promote
global
cooperation,
while
maintaining
their
distinct
corporate
identities.
6
DOT
granted
this
group
global
antitrust
immunity
but
excluded
routes
between
Frankfurt
and
Chicago/Washington
(discussed
above)
and
between
Toronto
and
San
Francisco/Chicago.
DOT
had
previously
carved
out
these
routes
from
bilateral
agreements
between
United/Lufthansa
and
United/Air
Canada
7
due
to
competitive
concerns
and
then
ordered
these
carve
outs
continued
under
the
Star
ATI
Alliance;
accordingly,
the
antitrust
laws
continue
to
apply
to
operations
on
those
routes.
B.
Continenta
l
s
request
to
join
Star
and
receive
antitrust
immunity
Continental,
the
fourth
largest
U.S.
airline
with
hubs
in
Newark,
Houston
and
Cleveland,
has
an
extensive
international
network,
including
significant
transatlantic,
transpacific
and
Latin
American
operations.
It
currently
is
an
non-immunized
member
of
the
Sky
Team
Alliance
and
5
United,
Air
Canada,
Lufthansa,
Austrian,
BMI,
LOT,
SAS,
Swiss
and
TAP
are
the
current
members
of
the
Star
ATI
Alliance.
6
Docket
2005-22922,
Joint
Application
Ex.
2.
7
DOT
first
granted
United
and
Air
Canada
immunity
in
1997.
That
order
exempted
from
immunity
Toronto
to
Chicago/San
Francisco
routes
-
two
of
the
five
routes
where
United
and
Air
Canada
each
offered
nonstop
service
between
the
U.S.
and
Canada
at
the
time.
5
also
participates
in
a
domestic
alliance
with
Northwest
and
Delta.
Continental
competes
with
United
on
numerous
domestic
routes;
the
airlines
also
provide
competing
service
to
Europe,
Canada,
Asia
and
Latin
America.
Continental
now
seeks
to
exit
Sky
Team
and
join
United
in
the
Star
Alliance.
8
In
addition
to
becoming
a
member
of
the
full,
non-immunized
alliance,
the
Applicants
request
that
DOT
provide
antitrust
immunity
for Continental
s
inclusion
in
the
Star
ATI
Alliance
agreement,
with
the
result
that
Continental
will
have
global
immunity
to
cooperate
with
the
existing
Star
ATI
participants.
9
The
Applicants
also
propose
an
integrated
joint
venture
among
Continental,
United,
Air
Canada,
and
Lufthansa
patterned
after
the
immunized
A+
alliance.
The
venture
-
named
A++
-
provides
for
the
four
parties
to
engage
in
joint
pricing,
sales
and
marketing,
and
revenue
sharing
for
the
transatlantic
routes
encompassed
by
the
agreement.
The
Applicants
contend
that
revenue
sharing
will
promote
sales
without
preference
or
metal
neutrality,
and
allow
the
parties
to
focus
on
jointly
tailoring
their
service
to
serve
customers
better,
rather
than
diverting
passengers
from
one
another.
8
Due
to
contractual
obligations,
Continental
cannot
transition
from
SkyTeam
to
the
Star
Alliance,
or
any
of
the
other
coordination
agreements
set
forth
in
the
Joint
Application,
until
October
24,
2009.
9
Continental
proposes
to
enter
into
bilateral
agreements
with
each
of
the
existing
members
to
facilitate
this
coordination.
10
6
in
support
of
their
overall
request,
the
Applicants
claim
that
Continental
s
inclusion
in
the
immunized
Star
ATI
Alliance
will
provide
significant
consumer
benefits,
which
include
expansion
of
service,
prevention
of
service
cuts,
cost
efficiencies,
and
more
vigorous
competition
among
the
three
major
international
alliances
(Star,
SkyTeam
and
largely
non-immunized
oneworld).
They
place
significant
emphasis
on
the
common
bottom
line
of
the
A++
agreement,
which
they
claim
will
allow
significant
integration
and
operational
efficiencies.
They
assert
that
antitrust
immunity
is
required
to
achieve
these
consumer
benefits
because
a
grant
of
immunity
would
negate
the
threat
of
costly
and
burdensome
private
antitrust
litigation;
satisfy
due
process
and
equitable
considerations
by
providing
the
Star
ATI
Alliance,
plus
Continental,
immunity
to
match
the
immunity
currently
in
place
for
the
SkyTeam
Alliance;
and
further
the
goals
of
the
U.S.-E.U.
open
skies
agreement.
12
The
Applicants
assert
that
the
benefits
justify
global,
unrestricted
immunity;
i.e.,
that
DOT
should
not
impose
carve
outs
on
new
overlap
routes
and
that
DOT
should
rescind
the
carve
outs
that
apply
to
the
Star
ATI
members
existing
grants
of
immunity.
13
The
Applicants
claim
that
they
will
not
carry
out
the
joint
activities
contemplated
by
the
proposed
alliance
agreements
without
immunity.
14
11
The
agreement
does
not
specifically
provide
for
expansion
of
the
venture
to
other
international
routes.
The
Applicants
have
stated
that
they
intend
to
pursue
similar
integrated
joint
ventures
to
cover
Latin
America
and
Asia,
but
no
such
contractual
obligation
exists.
12
J.A.
at
97,
13,
and
9.
13
J.A.
at
85.
14
J.A.
at
97.
7
Continental
and
United
also
contemplate
forming
a
domestic
alliance
spanning
their
entire
U.S.
networks.
15
Continental
and
United
assert
that
they
will
maintain
their
separate
domestic
networks
and
make
independent
pricing,
scheduling
and
sales
decision
for
the
domestic
entities.
C.
The
Show
Cause
Order
DOT
conducted
an
analysis
of
the
competitive
effects
and
claimed
benefits
of
the
proposed
agreements.
DOT
explains
that
its
competitive
analysis
treats
the
agreements
as
a
merger
and
that
the
appropriate
framework
is
an
application
of
Clayton
Act
standards.
16
Under
its
review
process,
DOT
analyzes
the
potential
effects
of
the
proposed
agreements
on
competition
in
regional,
country-pair,
and
city-pair
markets,
and
the
Order
finds
the
combination
to
be
pro-competitive
or
neutral
with
respect
to
regional
and
country-pair
markets.
17
With
respect
to
city-pair
markets,
the
Order
notes
that
there
are
fourteen
city
pairs
in
which
Continental
and
a
Star
ATI
carrier
compete
on
a
nonstop
basis.
DOT
states
that
each
of
the
nonstop
overlap
markets
will
continue
to
have
adequate
competition
on
a
nonstop
or
connecting
basis
but
does
not
discuss
the
specific
facts
of
each.
The
Order
also
states
that
even
[wjhere
the
transaction
materially
reduces
the
number
of
competitors
.
..
the
particular
facts
and
circumstances
of
this
15
Continental
and
United
hope
eventually
to
codeshare
on
nearly
all
of
their
domestic
flight
segments,
combine
customer
lounges,
consolidate
their
operations
at
common
airports,
provide
frequent
flyer
reciprocity,
cooperate
on
ticketing,
reservations
and
check-in,
and
perform
joint
procurement.
16
Order
at
7-13.
17
The
Order
does
not
explain
how
DOT
determined that
regional
and
country-pair
markets
are
relevant
markets
under
the
Clayton
Act.
In
its
analysis
of
country-pair
markets,
DOT
focuses
on
the
predicted
effect
of
the
transaction
on
inter-alliance
competition.
As
discussed
infra,
when
DOJ
analyzes
the
competitive
effects
of
transactions
involving
air
transportation
service,
DOJ
considers
travel
between
city
pairs,
or
nonstop
travel
between
city
pairs,
to
be
the
appropriate
relevant
markets
for
review.
8
case
indicate
that
consumers
will
not
be
harmed.
18
DOT
also
explains
its
view
that
carving
out
service
on
transatlantic
overlap
city-pair
routes
from
immunity
would
interfere
with
the
expected
integration
efficiencies
from
the
A++
venture
and
would
disadvantage
the
smaller
Star
carriers
SAS,
Swiss,
and
TAP,
which
compete
on
certain
of
the
overlap
routes
but
are
not
A++
members.
19
In
addition,
the
Order
states
that
entry
is
easy
in
U.S.-Canada
markets,
and
thus
DOT
does
not
impose
carve
outs
of
overlaps
between
Continental
and
the
Star
ATI
members.
20
The
Order
does
not
address
competitive
issues
in
any
other
non-transatlantic
international
city
pairs
(such
as
routes
from
the
U.S.
to
Asia
or
Latin
America).
The
Order
notes
that,
although
there
is
some
risk
that
immunized
coordination
between
Continental
and
United
will
have
spillover
effects
on
competition
in
domestic
markets,
that risk
is
small
and
outweighed
by
the
benefits
of
integration.
The
Order
states
that
the
adoption
of
antitrust
protocols
by
United
and
Continental
is
critical
to
this
finding.
The
Order
concludes
that
the
extensive
integration
contemplated
in
the
A++joint
venture
might
create
a
risk
of
antitrust
litigation
for
the
four
participants.
21
The
Order
does
not
expressly
analyze
why
immunity
is
necessary
for
Continental
to
join
the
broader,
less
integrated
Star
ATI
alliance.
The
Order
states
that
restricting
the
scope
of
the
alliance
agreements
at
this
juncture
would
“primarily
serve
to
disadvantage
Continental
and
its
customers.
22
18
Order
at
12.
19
Order
at
13.
20
Id.
The
Order
maintains
existing
transborder
carve
outs
between
Star
ATI
members
United
and
Air
Canada.
Order
at
13,27.
21
Order
at
17-18.
22
Order
at
20.
9
The
Order
grants
global
immunity
for
Continental
to
coordinate
with
the
Star
ATI
members
and
for
the
A++joint
venture.
23
The
Applicants
are
required
to
submit
evidence
showing
that
the
A++joint
venture
has
been
implemented
-
i.e.,
the
parties
must
negotiate
a
revenue
sharing
formula
-
within
18
months.
If
they
do
so,
the
existing
carve-outs
on
the
Washington-Frankfurt
and
Chicago-Frankfurt
markets
will
be
removed.
If
they
fail
to
do
so,
the
grant
of
antitrust
immunity
shall
be
automatically
withdrawn.
24
III.
The
Statutory
Scheme
Disfavors
Immunity
and
Places
a
Significant
Burden
on
the
Applicants
to
Justify
Their
Request
Under
the
applicable
statute,
DOT
must
disapprove
a
proposed
agreement
if
it
substantially
reduces
or
eliminates
competition
unless
DOT
finds
that
the
agreement
is
necessary
to
meet
a
serious
transportation
need
or
to
achieve
important
public
benefits
and
there
is
no
less
anticompetitive
alternative.
49
U.S.C.
§41309(b).
If
DOT
approves
an
anticompetitive
agreement
on
those
grounds,
it
must
exempt
it
from
the
antitrust
laws.
49
U.S.C.
§41308(c).
If
DOT
finds
that
an
agreement
does
not
reduce
or
eliminate
competition
and
is
consistent
with
the
public
interest,
DOT
must
approve
it,
but
exemption
from
the
antitrust
laws
is
authorized
only
if
it
is
required
by
the
public
interest;
even
then
immunity
is
authorized
only
to
the
extent
necessary
to
allow
the
person
to
proceed
with
the
transaction
specifically
approved
by
the
order
and
with
any
transaction
necessarily
contemplated
by
the
order.
49
U.S.C.
§§41309(b)
and
23
The
immunity
grant
is
subject
to
the
adoption
of
antitrust
guidelines
by
United,
Continental,
and
Lufthansa,
and
does
not
extend
to
any
market
solely
within
the
United
States.
Order
at
27,
Appendix
A.
The
Applicants
also
must
submit
for
prior
approval
any
agreements
materially
altering
their
cooperation
agreements
and
must
resubmit
the
alliance
agreements
five
years
after
issuance
of
the
Final
Order.
Order
at
27.
24
Order
at
26-27.
10
41308(b).
In
such
a
case,
the
burden
is
on
the
Applicants
to
make
a
strong
showing
on
the
record
that
antitrust
immunity
is
required
by
the
public
interest,
and
that
the
parties
will
not
proceed
with
the
transaction
without
the
antitrust
immunity.”
25
A.
Antitrust
enforcement
plays
a
central
role
in
the
deregulated
airline
industry
Antitrust
enforcement
protects
U.S.
consumers.
The
antitrust
laws
rest
on
the
premise
that
the
unrestrained
interaction
of
competitive
forces
will
yield
the
best
allocation
of
our
economic
resources,
the
lowest
prices,
the
highest
quality
and
the
greatest
material
progress.
26
Accordingly,
the
Supreme
Court
has
consistently
held
that
exemptions
from
the
antitrust
laws
are
to
be
narrowly
construed.
27
An
important
goal
of
airline
deregulation
was
to
“make
the
airline
industry
subject
to
the
same
competitive
and
antitrust
standards
applicable
to
other
industries,
as
far
as
is
practicable.
28
As
the
Civil
Aeronautics
Board
(
CAB
)
itself
recognized,
regulatory
protection
from
antitrust
enforcement
may
have
unanticipated
consequences:
Congress
intended
the Board
to
be
circumspect
in
its
use
of
414
[the
antitrust
exemption
for
airlines],
both
because
the
threat
of
antitrust
liability
is
a
valuable
regulator
of
business
conduct
and
because
the
consequences
of
the
grant
of
immunity
can
be
difficult
to
predict.
29
25
Order
93-1-11
(Northwest/KLM)
at
10.
26
N.
Pac.
Ry.
Co.
v.
United
States,
356
U.S.
1,
4
(1958).
27
Union
Labor
Life
Ins.
Co.
v.
Pireno,
458
U.S.
119,
126
(1982);
FMC
v.
Seatrain
Lines,
Inc.,
411
U.S.
726,
732-33
(1973).
This
doctrine
applies
with
equal
force
to
both
implicit
and
express
statutory
exemptions.
Group
Life
&
Health
Ins.
Co.
v.
Royal
Drug
Co.,
440
U.S.
205,
231
(1979);
United
States
v.
McKesson
&
Robbins,
Inc.,
351
U.S.
305,
316
(1956).
28
Air
Carrier
Agreements
Affecting
Interstate
and
Overseas
Air
Transportation,
Order
88-12-11
at
1
(1988).
29
National
Airlines,
Acquisition,
84
C.A.B.
408,
415
(1979).
11
The
CAB
and
DOT
have
in
the
past
exercised
their
authority
to
grant
immunity
mindful
of
competitive
consequences:
In
enacting
the
ADA,
Congress
directed
that
control
of
the
air
transportation
system
be
returned
to
the
marketplace.
We
have
consistently
held
that
a
part
of
the
return
to
market
control
is
exposure
of
participants
to
the
antitrust
laws,
as
that
exposure
exists
in
unregulated
industries.
30
B.
Applicants
must
show
that
immunity
is
required
by
the
public
interest
The
burden
is
on
the
Applicants
to
make
a
strong
showing
on
the
record
that
antitrust
immunity
is
required
by
the
public
interest,
and
that
the
parties
will
not
proceed
with
the
transaction
without
the
antitrust
immunity.”
31
DOT
has
“determined
that
it
will
grant
antitrust
immunity
only
if
it
is
necessary
to
enable
a
transaction
that
will
provide
significant
public
benefits
to
go
forward.
32
Previous
decisions
have
described
the
high
standard
or
exceptional
showing
required.
33
The
courts
have
upheld
this
approach.
For
example,
in
affirming
a
CAB
denial
of
antitrust
immunity,
the
Eighth
Circuit
explained
that
[examination
of
[the
approval
and
immunity
provisions]
and
their
legislative
history
clearly
reveals
that
antitrust
immunity
for
30
Competitive
Marketing
of
Air
Transportation,
Order
82-12-85,
99
C.A.B.
1,131
(1982).
ADA
refers
to
the
Airline
Deregulation
Act
of
1978,
Pub.
L.
No.
95-504,
92
Stat.
1705,
codified
as
amended
at
49
U.S.C.
§§
40101-46501
(2005).
31
Order
93-1-11
(North
west/KLM)
at
10.
32
DOT Report
to
Congress:
Administration
of
Aviation
Antitrust
Functions,
at
16
(May
1987).
See
also
49
U.S.C.
§
41308(b)
(stating
the
necessary
requirement).
33
See,
e.g,
UATP-1976
Agreements,
Order
80-6-66,
85
C.A.B.
2481,
2512-14
(1980)
(
[F]ull
exposure
to
antitrust
liability
is
consistent
with
the
marketplace
orientation
of
[the
Airline
Deregulation
Act]
);
Airline
Fuel
Corporation
Case,
Order
79-9-120,
83
C.A.B.
1358,
1363-64
(1979)
(holding
that
Board
s
continuing
jurisdiction
over
agreements
was
not
sufficient
substitute
for
antitrust
exposure
and
noting
that
the
threat
of
unwarranted
litigation
is
simply
one
of
the
risks
of
doing
business
);
see
also,
Competitive
Marketing
of
Air
Transportation,
Order
82-12-85,
99
C.A.B.
1,
13
(1982)
(recognizing
that
full
antitrust
exposure
is
consistent
with
deregulation
and
setting
a
“high
standard
for
granting
antitrust
immunity”
).
12
airline
agreements
is
intended
to
be
the
exception
and
not
the
rule.
34
All
prudent
businesses
devote
some
concern
to
antitrust
liability;
this
level
of
awareness
normal
and,
from
a
consumer
standpoint,
healthy.
Subjective
fears
of
antitrust
litigation
are
an
insufficient
basis
for
granting
immunity:
Petitioners
seem
to
read
the
[Federal
Aviation
Act]
as
authorizing
immunity
on
demand
for
any
agreement
which
produces
public
benefits.
Neither
the
text
nor
the
legislative
history
of
the
statute
supports
such
a
reading,
which
would
make
the
grant
of
antitrust
immunity
turn
on
the
subjective
desire
of
the
parties
to
avoid
antitrust
litigation.
This
desire
is
one
shared
by
all
businesses
subject
to
the
Sherman
Act,
and
we
do
not
believe
that
it
is
relevant
to
the
Board
s
task.
Petitioners
are
entitled
to
immunity
on
the
basis
of
an
objective
demonstration
that
the
statutory
requirements
for
such
immunity
have
been
met.
35
An
application
for
immunity
must
therefore
make
a
strong
showing
that,
from
the
standpoint
of
the
public
interest,
the
predicted
value
of
antitrust
immunity
is
greater
than
the
proven
value
of
the
normal
antitrust
regime.
IV.
DOT
Should
Deny
the
Broad
Application
for
Immunity
Over
the
last
sixteen
years,
DOT
has
exercised
its
authority
to
grant
antitrust
immunity
to
more
than
twenty
alliance
agreements.
36
During
this
time
most
of
the
largest
airlines
in
the
world
have
become
members
of
one
of
three
large
alliances
and,
in
many
cases,
have
been
granted
immunity
from
the
antitrust
laws
by
DOT.
Many
of
the
immunity
grants
DOT
has
issued
were
intended,
in
large
part,
to
further
the
foreign
policy
goal
of
inducing
the
governments
of
the
foreign
alliance
partners
home
countries
34
Republic
Airlines,
Inc.
v.
C.A.B.,
756
F.2d
1304,
1317
(8
t
h
Cir.
1985).
35
Id.
(emphasis
in
original).
36
DOT
has
published
lists
of
open
skies
agreements
and
immunized
alliances
at
http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/aviation/X-40%20Role_Files/bilatosagreement.htm
and
at
http://ostpxweb.dot.gov/aviation/X-50%20Role_files/immunizedalliances.htm
.
13
to
enter
into
open
skies
agreements
with
the
United
States.
Indeed,
DOT
asked
Congress
to
retain
the
authority
to
approve
and
immunize
agreements
as
a
tool
to
be
used
in
the
conduct
of
U.S.
international
aviation
policy.
37
For
example,
in
granting
immunity
to
the
North
west/KLM
alliance,
foreign
policy
considerations
led
DOT
to
overcome
its
normal
reluctance
to
grant
antitrust
immunity:
We
have
rarely
been
willing
to
grant
antitrust
immunity
to
carrier
agreements
because
immunity
is
usually
inconsistent
with
airline
deregulation
and
the
promotion
of
airline
competition.
In
this
case,
however,
the
grant
of
immunity
should
promote
competition
by
furthering
our
efforts
to
obtain
less
restrictive
aviation
agreements
with
other
European
38
countries.
The
agreements
facilitated
by
earlier
grants
of
immunity
have
removed
entry
restrictions
and
pricing
regulation
in
most
large
international
markets.
In
this
case,
however,
open
skies
agreements
are
in
place
with
all
of
the
relevant
governments
39
and
an
immunity
grant
to
Continental
does
not
advance
this
important
goal.
40
37
Report
to
Congress:
Administration
of
Aviation
Antitrust
Functions,
May
1987,
at
24.
38
Order
93-1-11
at
11-12.
39
Although
in
some
previous
cases,
DOT
granted
immunity
to
a
new
alliance
after
open
skies
were
achieved,
these
decisions
occurred
where
the
foreign
carrier
’s
original
alliance
with
a
U.S.
carrier
had
terminated
or
where
the
citizen
airline
of
the
open
skies
partner
was
newly
joining
an
alliance
with
a
single
U.S.
carrier.
As
DOT
has
explained,
“the
existence
of
an
open-skies
relationship
in
no
way
guarantees
any
grant
of
immunity.
To
the
contrary,
it
is
possible
that
immunity
will
not
be
found
to
be
pro-competitive
or
pro-consumer
in
particular
cases,
notwithstanding
an
open
national
market,
depending
on
such
factors
as
relevant
market
concentration,
potential
future
barriers,
overall
dominance
and
size
of
the
applicants,
among
other
things
[;]
...
an
Open-Skies
agreement
is
a
necessary,
but
not
automatically
sufficient,
basis
for
the
grant
of
antitrust
immunity.
Order
2001-12-18
(Delta/Air
France/Alitalia/Czech)
at
2.
40
The
EU
and
the
U.S.
have
negotiated
and
implemented
a
first
stage
open
skies
agreement
and
are
negotiating
an
expansion
of
that
agreement.
There
has
been
no
claim
here
that
granting
expanded
immunity
to
Star
would
lead
to
success
in
those
negotiations.
14
DOT
has
also
based
its
prior
decisions
to
grant
immunity
to
alliances
on
the
assumption
that
immunity
would
allow
the
partner
airlines
to
coordinate
in
ways
that
create
large
public
benefits,
and
that
such
coordination
would
not
occur
without
immunity.
The
primary
benefit
asserted
by
the
Applicants
is
that,
like
other
international
alliances,
immunity
here
will
allow
the
partner
airlines
to
extend
their
networks
to
provide
passengers
with
online
service
in
a
large
number
of
city
pair
markets
that
no
partner
serves
on
its
own.
They
further
argue
that
immunity
will
benefit
passengers
by
creating
broader
frequent
flyer
programs,
improved
access
to
airport
lounges,
and
more
efficient
service
through
shared
airport
facilities
and
passenger
handling.
Time
has
shown,
however,
that
non-immunized
alliances
(including
some
involving
the
Applicants)
routinely
provide
these
same
public
benefits
through
code-sharing,
joint
marketing
programs,
and
operational
cooperation.
See
infra
Section
VI.
A.
The
Applicants
also
argue
that
immunity
would
lead
to
reduced
fares
through
the
elimination
of
double
marginalization.
Comparison
of
immunized
and
non-immunized
alliances,
however,
shows
that
immunity
is
not
necessary
to
achieve
this
benefit.
See
infra
Section
VI.
E.
Finally,
the
Applicants
claim
that
they
would
not
engage
in
the
proposed
coordination
without
immunity
due
to
fear
of
frivolous
antitrust
litigation.
This
fear
is
without
substantial
foundation,
and
long
experience
shows
that
airlines
routinely
engage
in
profitable
and
beneficial
coordination
without
antitrust
immunity.
See
infra
Section
VI.
V.
Immunizing
an
Alliance
that
Includes
Continental
and
the
Other
Star
ATI
Members
Risks
Significant
Competitive
Harm
in
Certain
Markets
DOJ
s
analysis
shows
that
the
addition
of
Continental
to
the
immunized
Star
ATI
Alliance
is
likely
to
result
in
harm
to
certain
international
routes,
including
routes
between
the
U.S.
and
China,
routes
spanning
the
U.S.
and
Canadian
border,
and
routes
between
the
U.S.
and
Denmark,
15
Portugal,
Sweden,
and
Switzerland.
The
proposed
agreements
also
pose
harm
to
domestic
competition.
A.
Analyzing
the
competitive
effects
of
the
Joint
Application
agreements
To
determine
the
competitive
effect
of
adding
Continental
to
the
immunized
Star
ATI
Alliance,
DOJ
undertakes
an
analysis
based
on
the
antitrust
agencies
Antitrust
Guidelines
for
Collaborations
Among
Competitors
(hereinafter
Joint
Venture
Guidelines
).
41
The
central
question
is
whether
the
joint
venture
is
likely
to
harm
competition
in
any
relevant
markets
by
increasing
the
participants
ability
or
incentive
to
raise
price
or
reduce
output.
42
The
first
part
of
this
analysis
asks
whether
the
venture
may
reduce
competition
in
the
markets
within
which
the
venture
operates.
The
second
asks
whether
the
joint
venture
may
reduce
competition
in
other
markets
where
the
joint
venturers
remain
competitors.
The
likelihood
of
any
harm
to
competition
depends
on,
among
other
things,
the
nature
of
the
collaboration,
its
organization
and
governance,
and
safeguards
implemented
to
prevent
or
minimize
such
disclosure.
43
A
joint
venture
may
facilitate
collusion
by
providing
the
participants
with
opportunities
to
discuss
and
agree
on
anticompetitive
terms
or
enhancing
their
ability
to
detect
and
punish
deviations
from
a
collusive
agreement.
44
Evaluating
the
competitive
effects
requires
a
detailed
and
fact-intensive
analysis
of
the
specifics
of
the
joint
venture
structure
41
These
guidelines,
prepared
by
DOJ
and
the
Federal
Trade
Commission
and
available
at
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/04/ftcdojguidelines.pdf
,
explain
the
framework
for
analysis
of
the
competitive
effects
of
joint
ventures.
42
Joint
Venture
Guidelines
at
1.2;
3.3.
43
See
Joint
Venture
Guidelines
at
3.34(e).
44
Id.
at
3.31(b).
16
and
proposed
operations
in
the
relevant
markets.
DOJ
uses
the
principles
contained
in
the
1992
Horizontal
Merger
Guidelines
to
analyze
the
likely
competitive
effects
of
agreements
such
as
those
in
the
Joint
Application,
45
and
DOT
has
adopted
this
Merger
Guidelines
approach.
46
The
analysis
identifies
the
relevant
markets
and
the
firms
that
compete
in
those
markets,
and
considers
whether
entry
into
the
market
is
so
easy
that
the
market
participants,
after
the
transaction,
would
not
be
able
profitably
to
maintain
a
price
increase
above
pre-merger
levels.
47
In
analyzing
airline
matters,
the
relevant
markets
are
no
larger
than
city
pairs.
However,
there
are
often
narrower
markets
for
nonstop
service
because
a
significant
number
of
travelers
may
not
consider
onestop
service
to
be
a
reasonable
substitute
for
nonstop
in
a
given
city-pair
market.
In
principle,
a
transaction
may
not increase
market
power,
notwithstanding
a
significant
increase
in
concentration,
if
entry
were
so
easy
that
profitable
price
increases
could
not
be
sustained
after
the
transaction.
Here,
the
Applicants
have
made
no
showing
that
such
entry
would
be
timely,
likely
or
sufficient
on
the
routes
of
greatest
concern.
Moreover,
experience
shows
that
entry
on
certain
routes,
in
particular
routes
connecting
two
hubs
of
an
airline,
can
be
difficult
for
a
45
For
a
more
detailed
description
of
DOJ
’s
approach
to
analyzing
airline
mergers,
see
Statement
of
James
J.
O
Connell
before
the
Subcommittee
of
Aviation,
Committee
on
Transportation
and
Infrastructure,
U.S.
House
of
Representatives
(May
14,
2008)
at
7-10.
46
M
[W]e
primarily
consider
whether
the
alliance
would
significantly
increase
market
concentration,
whether
the
alliance
raises
concerns
about
potential
anticompetitive
effects
in
light
of
other
factors,
and
whether
new
entry
into
the
market
would
be
timely,
likely,
and
sufficient
either
to
deter
or
counteract
a
proposed
alliance
s
potential
for
harm.
Order
at
7.
47
Entry
is
that
easy
if
entry
would
be
timely,
likely,
and
sufficient
in
its
magnitude,
character
and
scope
to
deter
and
counteract
the
competitive
effects
of
concern.
Merger
Guidelines
§
3.0.
17
non-hub
carrier.
48
B.
Competition
on
non-transatlantic
routes
If
global
antitrust
immunity
is
granted,
United
and
Continental
will
be
free
to
cease
competing
in
non-transatlantic
international
markets.
Although
the
two
carriers
have
no
nonstop
overlaps
on
non-transatlantic
city
pairs,
they
are
nevertheless
important
competitors
in
non
-
transatlantic
regions.
Pacific
and
Latin
American
markets
tend
to
have
significantly
less
service
from
the
U.S.
than
European
markets,
both
because
the
markets
are
thinner
and
because
service
to
several
countries
is
still
subject
to
limited
entry
bilaterals.
49
The
Order
contains
no
analysis
of
the
competitive
effects
of
immunizing
the
non-transatlantic
international
operations
of
Continental
and
United.
50
The
most
serious
competitive
concerns
raised
by
a
grant
of
global
immunity
involve
China.
U.S.
airlines
must
receive
DOT
authorization
to
serve
between
specific
cities
in
the
U.S.
and
China,
and
such
authorization
has
strict
frequency
limits.
United
and
Continental
are
currently
the
only
two
U.S.
carriers
offering
nonstop
service
to
Beijing
from
the
U.S.
mainland.
Together,
they
account
for
57%
of
the
available
nonstop
seats
to
Beijing,
while
(non-immunized)
48
Entry
by
non-hub
carriers
in
transatlantic
hub
routes
where
only
a
few
airlines
offer
nonstop
flights
is
extremely
unlikely.
For
the
46
transatlantic
hub
routes
studied
in
Appendix
B
that
had
nonstop
service
from
only
one
or
two
carriers,
there
was
only
one
instance
in
the
past
three
years
of
a
non-hub
carrier
entering
a
route
with
regular
service.
See
Appendix
B,
fn.
119.
See
also,
infra
notes
67
and
122.
49
Countries
that
still
have
restricted
bilaterals
include
Brazil,
Mexico,
China,
and
Japan.
50
The
Order
notes
Delta
Air
Lines
objection
to
extending
immunity
to
limited
entry
countries,
but
merely
states
that
DOT
is
unwilling
to
jeopardize
the
network
benefits
of
the
proposed
alliance
by
limiting
the
points
that
be
served
without
stronger
evidence
of
competitive
harm.
Order
at
20.
The
Order
does
not
describe
which
limited
entry
markets
DOT
examined
for
competitive
effects
or
which
evidence
DOT
would
have
found
sufficient.
18
Star
member
Air
China
accounts
for
another
41%.
51
United
and
Continental
are
also
the
only
U.S.
carriers
providing
nonstop
service
from
U.S.
gateways
to
Hong
Kong;
those
nonstop
flights
accounted
for
28%
of
all
nonstop
seats
offered
from
the
U.S.
to
Hong
Kong
in
2008.
52
United
and
Continental
currently
do
not
provide
nonstop
service
between
the
same
U.S.-China
city
pairs
(e.g.,
United
has
authority
to
provide
some
service
between
Beijing
and
Chicago/San
Francisco/Washington,
while
Continental
is
authorized
to
offer
some
service
between
Beijing
and
Newark).
However,
because
DOT
can
authorize
service
to
China
from
only
a
handful
of
U.S.
cities,
53
customers
in
many
U.S.
cities
must
use
connect
service
when
traveling
to/from
China.
Thus,
Continental
and
United
today
compete
for
connecting
traffic
between
numerous
non-gateway
U.S.
cities
and
Beijing.
That
competition
would
be
lost
under
the
terms
of
the
Order.
Under
current
service
patterns,
post-application
the
Star
Alliance
would
provide
a
dominant
share
of
the
onestop
connecting
service
available
to
U.S.
consumers,
with
immunized
Star
ATI
members
Continental
and
United
accounting
for
many
of
the
onestop
options
involving
Eastern
U.S.
points.
Although
significant
new
U.S.-China
service
has
been
negotiated
and
awarded,
54
most
of
that
new
service
has
been
deferred
by
the
recipient
airlines
for
at
least
a
year.
55
51
OAG
data
for
2008.
52
Id.
53
See
Order
2007-9-25,
Docket
OST-2007-28567,
at
2-3
(discussing
limits
on
DOT'S
ability
to
award
service
to
China).
54
See
Order
2007-9-25,
Docket
OST-2007-28567.
55
See,
e.g,
Docket
OST-2007-28567,
Motion
of
United
Airlines,
March
20,
2009,
at
2-
19
Even
if
all
the
authorized
service
were
implemented
eventually,
the
combination
of
the
Continental
and
United
frequencies
will
leave
the
Star
ATI
alliance
with over
half
of
the
authorized
U.S.
carrier
frequencies
from
the
U.S.
to
Beijing.
C.
Competition
on
transatlantic
routes
Continental
has
extensive
transatlantic
operations
-
with
flights
to
25
destinations
in
Europe
-
primarily
from
its
hub
in
Newark
and
more
limited
service
from
Houston
and
Cleveland.
Continental
competes
on
a
nonstop
basis
with
the
Star
ATI
carriers
in
certain
U.S.-
Europe
city-pair
markets,
as
discussed
in
Section
V.
C.
2
below.
58
Granting
Continental
authority
to
join
the
immunized
Star
ATI
Alliance
will
likely
harm
nonstop
competition
in
these
markets.
1.
Nonstop
service
is
a
separate
product
market
In
transatlantic
routes
covered
by
this
Application,
nonstop
service
is
a
separate
product
56
See
Appendix
A.
57
58
With
respect
to
transatlantic
city-pair
markets
in
which
Continental
today
provides
only
connecting
service,
the
proposed
immunity
grant
does
not
raise
competitive
concerns
for
passengers.
20
market.
Empirical
analyses
(discussed
in
more
detail
below)
show
that
the
number
of
nonstop
carriers
competing
in
a
market
has
a
significant
impact
on
the
average
fares
paid
by
customers
in
the
market.
That
finding
strongly
supports
the conclusion
that
nonstop
service
is
a
separate
market,
59
The
evidence
shows
that
for
a
large
group
of
passengers,
connecting
service
is
not
a
reasonable
substitute
and
airlines
can
target
this
group
for
higher
fares.
60
These
travelers
generally
have
fewer
options
on
the
timing
of
trips,
tend
to
purchase
tickets
closer
to
the
time
of
travel,
are
able
to
pay
more
for
better
service
and
flexibility,
and
are
less
likely
to
accept
the
delays
attendant
to
connecting
service
when
nonstop
service
is
available.
In
other
words,
for
many
passengers,
connecting
service
is
not
a
reasonable
substitute
for
nonstop
service.
The
existence
of
a
separate
market
for
nonstop
service
is
supported
by
the
airlines
own
documents
and
actions.
The
airlines
structure
restrictions
on
their
tickets
to
segment
time-
sensitive
from
non-time-sensitive
demand,
thereby
encouraging passengers
to
self-select
into
either lower
priced
tickets
with
more
restrictions
purchased
in
advance
of
travel,
or
less
restricted
59
Moreover,
on
transatlantic
hub
routes
the
vast
majority
of
coach
passengers
fly
nonstop
when
it
is
available
even
though
average
connect
fares
are
10%
lower
than
average
nonstop
fares
(see
Appendix
B).
Such
evidence
is
consistent
with
the
existence
of
a
separate
non-stop
market.
60
See,
e.g.,
Armantier,
O
.,
and
Richard,
0.,
2008,
“Domestic
Airline
Alliances
and
Consumer Welfare,
39
RAND
Journal
of
Economics
875-904,
and
Berry,
S.,
Ca
rn
all,
M.,
and
Spiller,
P.,
2006,
“Airline
Hubs:
Costs,
Markups
and
the
Implications
of
Customer
Heterogeneity,
1
Advances
in
Airlines
Economics
(Darin
Lee,
Elsevier
B.V.,
ed.).
21
tickets
purchased
within
a
few
days
of
travel
at
relatively
high
prices.
61
To
similar
effect,
the
airlines
QSI
(
quality
of
service
index
)
models
award
nonstop
service
a
significantly
higher
projected
share
than
connect
service
when
predicting
the
market
share
a
carrier
should
receive
based
upon
its
level
or
quality
of
service
in
a
market.
62
Finally,
business
travelers
conduct
supports
the
existence
of
a
nonstop
market.
63
Many
corporations
have
explicit
guidelines
governing
when
their
employees
are
required
to
take
onestop
alternatives
due
to
lower
price.
Those guidelines
require
a
significant
fare
difference
before
the
onestop
option
is
mandated
-- -
generally
at
least
10%
and
in
some
cases
25%
or
more.
Some
corporations
actually
require
passengers
to
take
nonstop
service
if
available.
This
is
not
surprising
given
the
value
of
employees
time,
especially
the
types
of
employees
likely
to
be
dispatched
on
international
travel.
2.
Nonstop
overlap
on
specific
transatlantic
routes
Continental
currently
competes
against
other
Star
ATI
members
on
five
nonstop
transatlantic
routes:
New
York-Stockholm,
New
York-Copenhagen,
New
York-Geneva,
New
61
62
63
DOJ
interviewed
numerous
corporate
travel
managers
about
their
companies
travel
policies
during
the
course
of
investigating
the
Joint
Applicants
proposals
and
other
airline
transactions.
22
York-Lisbon,
and
New
York-Zurich.
64
The
two
charts
below
show
Continental
and
the
Star
ATI
carriers
shares
on
these
five
routes
of
all
passengers
(nonstop
and
connecting)
and
nonstop
passengers:
65
Total
Passenger
Shares
(Nonstop
and
Connecting)
in
Selected
N.Y.C.
Overlap
Routes
New
York
City
2007
CO
Share
Current
Star
New Star
Transatlantic
Service
Passengers
ATI
Share
ATI
Share
Stockholm
Copenhagen
Geneva
Zurich
Lisbon
Total
Nonstop
Passenger
Shares
in
Selected
N.Y.C.
Overlap
Routes
New
York
City
2007
CO
Share
Current
Star
New
Star
Transatlantic
Service
Passengers
ATI
Share
ATI
Share
Stockholm
Copenhagen
Geneva
Zurich
Lisbon
On
each
of
these
routes,
Continental
and
its
potential
immunized
partner
account
for
at
least
of
the
passenger
traffic.
Thus,
even
if
the
relevant
market
is
more
broadly
defined
to
include
nonstop
and
connecting
service,
the
proposed
Application
would
substantially
increase
market concentration
in
each
of
the
above-referenced
markets.
On
four
of
the routes
(New
York
to
Copenhagen,
Geneva,
Lisbon,
and
Stockholm)
they
offer
the
only
daily
nonstop
service
on
the
64
SAS
serves
New
York-Copenhagen/Stockholm,
Swiss
serves
New
York-
Geneva/Zurich,
and
TAP
serves
New
York-Lisbon.
6S
Source:
MIDT
data
(2007).
|
23
route,
and
on
the
fifth
(New
York
to
Zurich)
they
are
two
of
three
nonstop
competitors.
The
proposed
immunity
order
would
thus
significantly
reduce
-
and
in
some
cases
completely
eliminate
-
nonstop
competition
on
these
routes.
As
the
table
below
shows,
the
vast
majority
of
passengers
traveling
in
these
markets
fly
nonstop,
and
the
percentage
of
business
passengers
(identified
by
fare
class)
flying
nonstop
is
generally
even
higher.
66
Business
Class
Share
Coach
Class
Share
New
York
City
Nonstop
Connecting
Nonstop
Connecting
Transatlantic
Service
Carriers
Carriers
Carriers
Carriers
Stockholm
Copenhagen
Geneva
Zurich
Lisbon
3.
The
loss
of
a
nonstop
competitor
is
likely
to
result
in
significant
fare
increases
The
immunity
grant
will
substantially
reduce
competition
on
routes
where
the
Star
ATI
members
offer
nonstop
service
in
competition
with
Continental.
Numerous
economic
studies
of
the
domestic
U.S.
airline
industry
since
deregulation
have
shown
that
reducing
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors,
particularly
from
three
to
two,
or
from
two
to
one,
results
in
significant
fare
increases.
67
Recent
work
by
DOJ,
using
cross-sectional
analysis
of
third
quarter
2008
fare
data
66
Source:
MIDT
data
(2007).
Includes
all
carriers
with
at
least
500
passengers
in
the
calendar
year.
67
See,
e.g.,
Kamita,
Analyzing
the
Effects
of
Temporary
Antitrust
Immunity:
The
Aloha-Hawaiian
Immunity
Agreement,
Journal
of
Law
and
Economics
(forthcoming
2009);
24
for
U.S.
carriers
on
transatlantic
routes,
shows
that
fares
paid
by
nonstop
passengers
increase
by
15%
when
the
number
of
nonstop
carriers
goes
from
two
to
one
(as
would
be
the
result
in
a
number
of
the
nonstop
overlap
markets
at
issue
here
if
immunity
is
granted)
and
increase
by
6.6%
when
the
number
of
nonstop
carriers
goes
from
three
to
two.
68
4.
Nonstop
entry
is
unlikely
The
Applicants
have
failed
to
show
that
nonstop
entry
would
prevent
fare
increases
by
Continental
and
its
immunized
Star
ATI
partners
in
overlap
transatlantic
markets.
If
Continental
has
immunity
to
coordinate
with
the
Star
ATI
members,
the
Star
ATI
Alliance
will,
in
essence,
operate
hubs
at
both
ends
of
the
overlap
city
pairs.
It
is
very
difficult
to
enter
the
hub-hub
market
of
another
carrier
because
the
entrant
does
not
have
access
to
feed
traffic
and
because
the
hub
carrier
has
significant
marketing
advantages.
69
New
York-Copenhagen
and
New
York-Stockholm
Peters,
Evaluating
the
Performance
of
Merger
Simulation:
Evidence
from
the
U.S.
Airline
Industry,
49
Journal
of
Law
and
Economics
627
(2006);
Joskow,
Werden
&
Johnson,
Entry,
Exit
and
Performance
in
Airline
Markets,
12
International
Journal
of
Industrial
Organization
457
(1994);
Borenstein,
“The
Evolution
of
U.S.
Airline
Competition,
6
Journal
of
Economic
Perspectives
45
(1992);
Borenstein,
“Hubs
and
High
Fares:
Airport
Dominance
and
Market
Power
in
the
U.S.
Airline
Industry,
20
Rand
Journal
of
Economics
344
(1989);
Brueckner,
Dyer
&
Spiller,
“Fare
Determination
in
Hub
and
Spoke
Networks,
23
Rand
Journal
of
Economics
309
(1992);
Morrison
&
Winston,
Enhancing
Performance
in
the
Deregulated
Air
Transportation
System,
1989
Brookings
Papers:
Microeconomics
61
(1989).
Recent
DOJ
empirical
work
on
domestic
markets
also
confirms
that
going
from
three
to
two
nonstop
carriers
increases
fares.
68
The
fare
change
findings
for
two
to
one
routes
are
statistically
significant.
See
Appendix
B,
Section
I,
for
further
description
of
the
analysis
performed.
69
The
hub
carrier
s
strong
frequent
flyer
base
and
its
relationships
with
local
travel
agents
make
it
difficult
for
an
entrant
to
attract
local
passengers.
see
also
Gurrea,
International
Airline
Code
Sharing
and
Entry
Deterrence,
1
Competition
Policy
and
Antitrust
109
(2006);
Lijesen,
Nijkamp,
Pels
&
Rietveld,
The
Home
Carrier
Advantage
in
Civil
Aviation,
1
Competition
Policy
and
Antitrust
215
(2006).
25
each
have
less
that
local
passengers
per
year,
making
those
routes
particularly
unattractive
for
entry
by
a
non-hub
carrier.
Constraints
on
service
at
New
York
airports
are
another
factor
that
makes
entry
in
these
overlap
markets
unlikely.
All
Continental
transatlantic
nonstop
overlaps
with
the
Star
carriers
involve
New
York
as
an
endpoint.
Long-term,
ongoing
congestion
problems
in
the
New
York
area
airspace
have
resulted
in
actions
by
the
FAA
to
limit
scheduled
operations
at
both
JFK
and
Newark
Liberty.
70
Currently,
it
would
be
difficult
for
a
competitor
to
gain
additional
operating
authority
to
begin
service
in
the
event
fares
increased
on
the
overlap
markets.
D.
Competition
on
transborder
routes
Continental
and
Air
Canada
are
the
only,
or
two
of
only
three,
airlines
providing
nonstop
service
on
five
transborder
routes.
71
As
is
the
case
on
the
transatlantic
overlaps,
the
vast
majority
of
passengers
on
these
routes
travel
nonstop.
72
The
charts
below
show
shares
of
all
passengers
(nonstop
and
connecting)
and
nonstop
passengers
on
five
of
the
Continental/Air
Canada
nonstop
overlaps:
73
70
Order
Limiting
Scheduled
Operations
at
John
F.
Kennedy
International
Airport,
Docket
FAA-2007-29320
(Jan.
15,
2008);
Order
Limiting
Scheduled
Operations
at
Newark
Liberty
International
Airport,
Docket
FAA-2008-0221
(May
15,
2008).
7
1
Continental
and
Air
Canada
also
each
offer
nonstop
service
in
New
York-Vancouver;
however,
Continental
only
serves
this
market
on
a
seasonal
basis
(summer).
The
New
York-
Montreal/Toronto
markets
are
currently
served
by
four
carriers
on
anonstop
basis
-
American,
Delta,
and
the
two
Applicants.
These
are
large
local
markets
(over
passengers
per
year
in
the
case
of
New
York-Toronto);
thus,
nonhub
carriers
are
able
to
profitably
to
provide
service
even
without
access
to
feed
traffic.
Continental
and
United
have
no
transborder
nonstop
overlaps,
but
do
compete
for
connecting
traffic
over
their
various
hubs.
72
The
nonstop
carriers
have
well
over
of
the
coach
Y
fare,
business
and
first-class
traffic
on
all
of
the
transborder
overlaps.
73
Source:
MIDT
data
(2007).
26
Total
Passenger
Shares
(Nonstop
and
Connecting)
in
Selected
U.S-Canada
Overlap
Routes
Transborder
2007
CO
Share
AC
+
UA
CO+AC+UA
Market
Passengers
Share
Share
Houston-Calgary
Houston-Toronto
Cleveland-Toronto
New
York-Ottawa
New
York-Halifax
Total
Nonstop
Passenger
Shares
in
Selected
U.S-Canada
Overlap
Routes
Transborder
2007
CO
Share
AC
+
UA
CO+AC+UA
Market
Passengers
Share
Share
Houston-Calgary
Houston-Toronto
Cleveland-Toronto
New
York-Ottawa
New
York-Halifax
As
detailed
in
our
analysis
of
transatlantic
nonstop
overlaps,
a
grant
of
immunity
will
harm
passengers
in
the
above
markets
unless
the
characteristics
of
these
particular
markets
indicate
that
entry
is
likely
to
counteract
the
anticompetitive
effects.
DOJ
agrees
with
the
Order
that
the
competitive
structure
of
transborder
routes
is
very
similar
to
U.S.
domestic
routes.
74
As
discussed
above
in
Section
V.
C.
3.,
however,
there
is
substantial
evidence
that
a
reduction
in
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
from
three
to
two,
or
two
to
one,
in
domestic
markets
leads
to
significant
fare
increases.
There
is
no
persuasive
evidence
in
the
record
that
entry
will
occur
on
these
routes.
Entry
is
particularly
unlikely
in
Houston-Calgary,
Houston-Toronto,
and
Cleveland
Toronto
because
Continental
and
Air
Canada
each
operate
a
hub
at
one
end
of
these
routes.
75
74
Order
at
13.
75
The
Applicants
argue
that
low
cost
carriers,
such
as
Westjet
and
Porter
Airlines,
are
potential
entrants
on
the
transborder
overlaps.
Consolidated
Reply
of
the
Joint
Applicants
at
30-
27
E.
Competition
on
domestic
routes
United
and
Continental
are
the
third
and
fourth
largest
domestic
carriers;
if
merged,
the
combined
carrier
would
be
the
largest
airline
in
the
world.
76
Domestically,
United
and
Continental
offer
competing
nonstop
service
between
United
s
hubs
(Chicago,
Washington,
Denver,
San
Francisco,
and
Los
Angeles)
and
Continental
s
hubs
(Newark,
Houston
and
Cleveland).
In
some
cases
they
are
the
only
carriers
offering
nonstop
service.
In
addition,
the
two
carriers
compete
on
a
very
large
number
of
domestic
connecting
routes.
As
DOT
recognizes,
immunized
cooperation
between
two
U.S.
carriers
on
international
routes
carries
with
it
the
risk
of
competitive
harm
in
domestic
markets.
77
United
and
Continental
have
adopted
antitrust
guidelines
designed
to
lessen
the
risk
of
domestic
spillover.
78
These
guidelines
have
been
reviewed
by
DOJ
and
revised
to
some
extent
in
light
of
our
concerns.
It
is
important
to
understand,
however,
that
no
guidelines
can
completely
eliminate
the
risk
of
domestic
spillover.
An
airline
s
domestic
and
international
operations
are
closely
31.
Service
offered
by
Westjet
(an
airline
that
has
traditionally
targeted
leisure
passengers)
via
its
potential
codeshare
with
Southwest
would
likely
be
connecting,
which
as
discussed
above,
is
unattractive
to
time-sensitive passengers.
Porter
s
fleet
choice
-
modern
turboprops
-
makes
entry
into
routes
like
Houston
to
Calgary
or
Toronto
extremely
unlikely.
Even
if
Westjet
or
Porter
were
to
enter
the
overlap
transborder
routes
on
a
nonstop
basis,
they
would
still
have
to
overcome
the
advantage
an
immunized
Air
Canada/Continental
relationship
would
have
by
way
of
operating
hubs
at
each
end.
See,
76
See,
e.g.,
77
Order
at
14.
78
Exhibit
JA-2
(revised).
28
integrated,
as
DOT
also
recognizes.
79
Within
the
context
of
their
international
alliance,
United
and
Continental
will
be
discussing
the
most
sensitive
competitive
subjects,
including
pricing,
yield
management,
capacity
planning,
entry
and
exit
decisions,
and
aircraft
deployment.
The
opportunities
and
incentives
to
extend
coordination
to
non-immunized
domestic
operations
are
clear.
Moreover,
this
risk
increases
as
the
scope
of
international
cooperation
between
the
two
domestic
carriers
increases.
,
80
If
the
international
cooperation
is
broad
but
undefined,
however
-
as
is
the
case
for
the
overall
Star
ATI
Alliance
-
the
opportunities
for
domestic
spillover
increase
significantly.
81
VI.
The
Applicants
Make
No
Showing
Why
Immunity
Is
Required
to
Achieve
the
Claimed
Public
Benefits
Arising
from
the
Joint
Application
Agreements
The
Applicants
have
the
burden
of
showing
immunity
is
required
by
the
public
interest.
In
assessing
whether
they
have
met
their
burden,
DOT
considers
the
likely
benefits
of
the
proposed
coordination
and
whether
the
Applicants
could
obtain
those
benefits
without
immunity
The
Applicants
claim,
and
DOT
has
tentatively
found,
that
the
agreements
will
result
in
public
benefits.
DOT
cites
the
Applicants
assertion
that
the
A++
integrated
venture
will
enable
its
participants
to
pool
resources
to
achieve
substantial
efficiency
and
cost
savings.
Order
at
19.
In
DOJ
s
view,
it
is
not
sufficient,
however,
merely
to
point
toward
claimed
benefits;
rather,
the
79
See
Order
at
13-14.
80
J.A.
Ex.
2
(revised).
81
For
example,
we
understand
that
U.S.-Canada
pricing
is
typically
handled
by
the
domestic
pricing
staff.
29
Applicants
need
to
demonstrate
that
immunity
is
necessary
to
achieve
them.
82
In
this
regard,
the
Applicants
fall
short.
It
is
likely
that
Continental
’s
entry
into
the
Star
Alliance
(or
the
smaller
Star
ATI
Alliance)
will
reduce
travel
times
for
some
connecting
passengers
and
increase
the
number
of
itineraries
available
from
which
to
select.
The
Applicants
present
no
evidence,
however,
that
customers
will
receive
quantitatively
or
qualitatively
different
service
if
Continental
receives
antitrust
immunity
to
coordinate
with
the
Star
ATI
members
compared
to
what
would
be
provided
if
Continental
merely
interacted
with
the
level
of
cooperation
expected
of
any
member
of
the
broader,
non-immunized
Star
Alliance.
83
The
Applicants
do
not
describe
which
specific
important
consumer
benefits
will
be
lost
if
DOT
does
not
grant
the
requested
immunity.
Nor
do
the
Applicants
make any
attempt
to
quantify
how
much
smaller
the
benefits
enuring
to
the
traveling
public
would
be
if
Continental
merely
engaged
with
the
Star
ATI
members,
without
antitrust
immunity,
in
such
standard
alliance
cooperation
practices
as
codesharing,
through-ticketing,
frequent
flyer
reciprocity
and
lounge
sharing
-
in
short,
the
type
of
interaction
Continental
currently
has
with
immunized
SkyTeam
members,
or
that
US
Airways
has
with
the
Star
ATI
members,
including
United.
Rather,
the
82
See,
e.g.,
Joint
Venture
Guidelines
at
3.36
(the
proponents
of
a
potentially
anticompetitive
collaborative
agreement
have
the
burden
of
showing
the
agreement
is
reasonably
necessary
to
achieve
cognizable
benefits
and
there
is
no
less
restrictive
means
of
achieving
those
benefits).
83
30
Applicants
proffer
unsubstantiated
assertions
about
why they
must
have
immunity.
The
Applicants
documents
also
indicate
that
cost
savings
of
any
significance
are
unlikely,
84
and,
more
importantly,
none
of
the
evidence
shows
that
cost
savings
are
likely
to
be
passed
on
to
passengers.
A.
The
Applicants
assertion
that
they
will
not
move
forward
without
immunity
is
not
convincing
The
Applicants
insist
that
they
would
not
enter
into
the
proposed
alliance
agreements
without
a
grant
of
immunity.
While
it
may
be
true
that
the
Applicants
would
not
enter
into
alliances
exactly
as
set
forth
in
the
Joint
Application,
we do
not
find
it
credible
for
the
Applicants
to
assert
that
they
would
not
engage
in
some
sort
of
cooperation
that
would
provide
nearly
identical
benefits
to
consumers
as
those
likely
to
result
from
the
application
agreements.
Carriers
routinely
enter
into
commercial
relationships
with
each
other
and
make
significant
long
term
investments
in
such
relationships,
without
immunity
from
the
antitrust
laws.
85
8
4
See,
e.
g
.
I
n
add
i
tion,
the
precipitous
drop
in
fuel
prices
since
the
parties
filed
their
application
in
July
2008,
negates
the
Applicants
already
less
than
compelling
argument
that
immunized
coordination
was
necessary
to
combat
fuel
costs.
85
31
Both
United
and
Continental
have
invested
significant
effort
into
furthering
their
respective
domestic
alliances
(United
with
US
Airways,
and
Continental
with
Northwest
and
Delta)
to
the
benefit
of
both
the
airlines
and
their
customers,
but
the
airlines
remain
fully
accountable
to
the
antitrust
laws.
Parties
to
domestic
codeshare
agreements
regularly
endeavor
to
consolidate
their
operations
at
airports,
independently
modify
their
capacity
to
facilitate
connections
between
each
other,
and
take
other
steps
to
extend
their
network
offerings.
In
SkyTeam
7,
United
urged
DOT
to
prohibit
immunity
as
a
matter
of
policy
between
domestic
U.S.
carriers,
absent
compelling
evidence
that
[granting
immunity]
would
achieve
important
public
benefits
not
otherwise
obtainable.
It
explained:
Absent
a
grant
of
immunity,
Northwest
and
Delta
have
.
..
possible
alternatives
available
that
will
allow
them
to
gain
significant
benefits
from
participation
in
the
SkyTeam
alliance.
[E]ither
Delta
or
Northwest
may
forego
immunity
with
the
foreign
members
of
the
SkyTeam
alliance
(and
with
each
other),
but
remain
a
member
of
the
alliance
and
engage
in
cooperative
activities
that
do
not
raise
a
meaningful
antitrust
risk.
This
is
precisely
the
situation
with
US
Airways
and
members
of
the
Star
Alliance;
while
US
Airways
has
no
immunity
with
the
other
Star
members,
it
participates
in
Star
and
generates
benefits
by
code
sharing
with
each
of
the
foreign
members
(and
United),
allowing
it
to
gain
behind
and
beyond
benefits,
network
expansions
and
integrated
scheduling,
ticketing
and
passenger
handling
that
goes
with
such
codesharing.
It
can
also
participate
in
joint
alliance
discount
offers
to
corporate
customers,
subject
to
certain
conditions
designed
to
preserve
competition,
and
participate
in
many
joint
purchasing
programs
and
other
joint
activities
that
do
not
touch
on
competitively
sensitive
behavior.
87
B.
The
Applicants
exaggerate
their
claim
that
significant
litigation
risks
exist
absent
immunity
The
Applicants
argue
that
they
will
not
attempt
to
achieve
the
claimed
benefits
of
any
of
86
87
Reply
of
United
Air
Lines,
Inc.,
Docket
OST-2004-19214.
32
the
Joint
Application
agreements
without
the
protection
of
antitrust
immunity
due
to
the
risk
of
litigation.
In
particular,
the
Applicants
state
that
because
this
particular
venture
contemplates
joint
sales,
route
and
schedule
coordination,
revenue
pooling
and
joint
pricing
decisions,
it
carries
with
it
the
threat
of
legal
challenge.
88
As
courts
have
recognized,
however,
a
grant
of
antitrust
immunity
does
not
turn
on
the
subjective
desire
of
the
parties
to
avoid
antitrust
litigation,
and
[i]t
is
not
realistic
to
expect
a
flood
of
antitrust
lawsuits
attacking
a
substantially
procompetitive
agreement.
89
If
the
Applicants
claims
of
significant
benefits
arising
from
the
agreements
are
accurate,
the
Applicants
will
have
the
incentive
to
pursue
further
integration,
which
they
can
accomplish
in
ways
consistent
with
the
antitrust
laws.
DOJ
is
aware
of
no
legal
challenge
to
the
actions
taken
by
carriers
within
and
in
furtherance
of
a
legitimate
airline
alliance.
90
C.
The
Applicants
inflate
the
importance
of
inter-alliance
competition
The
Applicants
maintain
that
immunity
is
necessary
to
allow
Star
to
achieve
parity
with
the
SkyTeam
alliance,
which
received
immunity.
The
Applicants
also
suggest,
without
evidentiary
support,
that
consumers
benefit
from
competition
between
alliances,
particularly
immunized
alliances.
88
J.A.
at
98.
8
9
Republic
Airlines,
Inc.
v.
C.A.B.,
756
F.2d
1304,
1317
(8th
Cir.
1985).
90
The
cases
cited
by
the
Applicants
regarding
their
continuing
risk
of
legal
challenge
by
third
parties
(J.A.
at
98,
fn.
190)
are
inapposite.
First,
those
cases
do
not
demonstrate
that
airlines
were
sued
because
they
were
acting
pursuant
to
a
joint
venture.
The
airline
defendants
may
have
been
members
of
various
alliances,
but
the
causes
of
action
were
not
based
on
activities
undertaken
only
because
of
the
joint
venture.
Second,
granting
antitrust
immunity
to
the
Applicants
will
not
provide
them
with
immunity
from
suit
for
coordination
with
carriers
that
are
not
members
of
the
joint
venture,
as
was
the
case
in
the
multi-defendant
travel
agent
commission
litigation.
33
First,
achieving
balance
in
the
market
success
of
differing
alliances
is
not
a
legitimate
goal
of
sound
competition
policy,
in
DOJ
s
view.
Alliances
should
compete
against
each
other,
and
the
market
should
determine
the
outcome
of
that
competition.
Second,
those
assertions
are
not
supported
by
any
party
evidence
and
are
inconsistent
with
the
evidence
DOJ
has
gathered,
which
shows
that
immunity
is
not
necessary
for
effective
alliance
competition.
Few,
if
any,
corporate
travel
managers
we
interviewed
during
our
investigation
of
this
application
and
in
the
course
of
other
airline
investigations
have
stated
a
desire
for
increased
inter-alliance
competition.
Even
when
a
particular
corporation
had
negotiated
a
contract
with
an
alliance,
that
contract
seldom
encompassed
all
members
of
the
alliance
or
had
resulted
in
lower
fares
than
if
the
corporation
had
negotiated
separate
contracts
with
the
carriers.
91
Moreover,
the
Order
ignores
the
competition
between
Star
and
oneworld, whose
two
largest
members
-
American
and
British
Airways
---
today
function
effectively
without
immunity
between
each
other.
D.
Immunity
will
not
advance
open
skies
Recognizing
that
granting
the
immunity
application
will
not
itself
lead
to
new
open
skies
agreements,
the
Applicants
assert
that
immunity
is
warranted
because
their
proposed
agreements
will
help
achieve
the
goals
of
the
U.S.-E.U.
open
skies
agreement.
92
They
claim
that
the
Memorandum
of
Consultations
accompanying
the
U.S.-E.U.
Agreement
“underscores
the
strategic
and
economic
importance
of
antitrust-immunized
alliances
as
a
matter
of
aviation
policy.
93
But
the
Memorandum
provides
only
that
U.S.
authorities
will
give a
procedural
91
None
of
the
Applicants
corporate
customers
filed letters
in
support
of
the
Joint
Application.
92
J.A.
at
9.
93
J.A.
at
10.
34
guaranty
of
fair
and
expeditious consideration
of
immunity
applications,
94
E,
The
Applicants
overemphasize
the
likelihood
that
immunity
for
the
proposed
alliance
will
substantially
reduce double
marginalization
The
Order
cites
the
elimination
of
double
marginalization
as
a
significant
benefit
of
the
proposed
immunity
grant,
as
do
the
Applicants
in
the
Joint
Application.
95
Although
alliances
can
lead
to
lower
fares
by
reducing
incentives
for
each
carrier
to
impose
an
additional
markup
on
connecting
traffic,
immunity
is
not
necessary
to
realize
that
result.
It
is
true
that
economic
studies
of
the
fares
offered
by
international
airline
alliances
in
the
1
990s
found
that
immunized
alliance
carriers
charged
interline
fares
that
were
lower
than
the
interline
fares
charged
by
non-immunized
alliance
carriers.
96
These
studies,
however,
never
proved
that
the
airlines
needed
immunity
to
provide
the
lower
fares,
i.e.,
that
the
airlines
could
eliminate
double
marginalization
only
by
engaging
in
activity
that
raised
antitrust
concerns.
The
1990s
were
a
time
of
flux
for
airline
alliances
as
the
airlines
experimented
with
different
partner
alignments
and
degrees
of
coordination
and
integration.
Indeed,
most
of
the
immunized
alliance
relationships
included
in
these
earlier
studies
featured
only
minimal
levels
of
revenue
sharing,
in
most
cases,
no
more
than
dictated
by
a
special
prorate
agreement.
97
Since
94
See
J.A.
at
10
(quoting
Memorandum
of
Consultations).
95
Order
at
19;
J.A.
at
37-39.
96
See
Brueckner,
J.,
and
Whalen,
T.,
2000,
“The
Price
Effects
of
International
Airline
Alliances.
Journal
of
Law
and
Economics,
Vol.
43, pp.
503-545.
Brueckner,
J,
2003,
International
Airfares
in
the
Age
of
Alliances,
Review
of
Economics
and
Statistics,
Vol.
85,
pp.105-1
18.
Whalen,
T.,
2007,
A
Panel
Data
Analysis
of
Code-Sharing,
Antitrust
Immunity,
and
Open
Skies
Treaties
in
International
Aviation
Markets.
Review
of
Industrial
Organization,
Vol.
30,
pp.39-61.
97
With
the
exception
of
No
rth
west/KLM,
the
immunized
alliances
operating
during
the
time
period
covered
by
these
studies
did
not
engage
in
the
sort
of
revenue
sharing
DOT
35
then,
most
airlines
have
grouped
into
three
major
alliances,
and
more
recent
empirical
work
by
DOJ
strongly
suggests
that
over
the
past
ten
years
(after
the
period
studied
in
those
earlier
papers),
airlines
participating
in
alliances,
whether
immunized
or
not,
have
made
strides
toward
managing
their
inventory
and
pricing
activities
to
provide
more
competitive
fares
when
forming
a
connection
with
another
airline.
98
In
fact,
using
2005-2008
data,
DOJ
has
found
that
connecting
fares
offered
by
non-immunized
alliances
for
transatlantic
routes
are
no
more
expensive
than
fares
offered
by
immunized
alliances.
99
VII.
Any
Grant
of
Antitrust
Immunity
Should
Include
Restrictions
to
Limit
Potential
Anticompetitive
Effects
Approval
of
the
Applicants
request
for
global
immunity
for
the
Joint
Application
agreements
will
likely
reduce
competition
in
specific
city
pairs
and
increases
the
risk
of
harm
to
domestic
competition,
all
with
scant
evidence
or
quantification
of
any
consumer
benefits
to
which
such
a
broad
grant
of
immunity
is
inextricably
linked.
Thus,
the
final
Order
should
carve
out
the
transatlantic
and
transborder
markets
where
competitive
harm
is
most
likely
to
occur,
maintain
existing
carve
outs,
and
limit
immunity
to
transatlantic
markets.
A.
Carve
out
nonstop
overlap
routes
As
discussed
above,
the
immunity
DOT
previously
granted
to
the
Star
ATI
Alliance
carves
apparently
believes
results
in
metal
neutrality.
98
99
See
Appendix
B,
Section
2,
for
further
description
of
this
DOJ
empirical
analysis.
36
out
nonstop
service
between
Frankfurt
and
Chicago/Washington
(maintaining
the
carve
outs
first
mandated
in
the
1996
United/Lufthansa
immunity
authorization)
and
between
Toronto
and
Chicago/San
Francisco
(maintaining
the
carve
outs
first
mandated
in
the
1997
United/Air
Canada
immunity
authorization).
100
The
carve
outs
do
not
prohibit
the
carriers
from
engaging
in
cooperative
conduct,
but
merely
make
that
conduct
subject
to
the
antitrust
laws.
In
the
present
Order,
DOT
has
tentatively
concluded
that
the
Applicants:
must
maintain
the
carve
outs
for
Toronto
to
Chicago/San
Francisco,
may
remove
the
Frankfurt-Chicago/Washington
carve
outs,
provided
the
Applicants
present
evidence
within
18
months
that
they
have
implemented
the
A++
alliance,
need
not
carve
out
any
additional
routes
from
the
scope
of
immunity
held
by
Star
ATI
after
Continental
joins.
The
analysis
underlying
DOT
’s
conclusions
on
carve
outs
is
unclear.
The
Order
declines
to
carve
out
any
of
the
overlap
transborder
routes
in
which
Continental
and
the
Star
ATI
members
currently
compete
on a
nonstop
basis,
without
citing
evidence
from
the
record
describing
the
public
benefits
likely
to
result
from
coordination
on
these
routes.
At
the
same
time,
the
Order
requires
the
Applicants
to
maintain
the
existing
carve
outs
in
Toronto-Chicago/San
Francisco
because
the
Applicants
did
not
demonstrate
integrative
benefits
in
the
subject
markets.
101
The
reason
for
the
differing
treatment
of
these
routes
is
not
stated.
100
See
Order
2007-2-16.
Over
time,
DOT
has
varied
the
scope
of
the
carve
outs
it
has
imposed.
In
some
cases
all
local
traffic
except
for
bulk
fares
and
corporate
fares
was
carved
out,
in
other
cases
only
restricted
business-type
fares were
carved
out.
Compare
Order
96-5-27
at
App.
A
(United/Lufthansa)(carving
out
local
U.S.
point
of
sale
passengers
flying
nonstop
”)
with
Order
2002-1-6
(Delta/Air
France)(carving-out
unrestricted
coach-class
fares
or
any
business
or
first-class
fares
for
local
U.S.
point
of
sale
passengers
flying
nonstop”
).
101
Order
at
13.
37
The
Order
declines
to
carve
out
the
six
transatlantic
overlap
routes
where
Continental
and
the
Star
ATI
members
provide
competing
nonstop
service:
New
York
to
Copenhagen/Frankfurt/Geneva/Lisbon/Stockholm/Zurich.
The
Order
defends
this
decision
by
noting
that
these
city
pairs
"are
subject
to
close
cooperation
under
[A++]
and
relies
heavily
on
the
alleged
integration
efficiencies
the
Applicants
state
they
will
realize
on
transatlantic
routes
through
the
A++joint
venture
-
including
the
Applicants
claim
that
these
efficiencies
will
be
passed
on
to
consumers.
102
But,
as
the
Order
recognizes,
only
one
new
nonstop
overlap
route
actually
involves
parties
to
the
A++
agreement
-
New
York-Frankfurt.
Each
of
the
other
overlap
transatlantic
routes
at
issue
(New
York-Copenhagen,
Geneva,
Lisbon,
Stockholm
and
Zurich)
involves
Continental
and
a
Star
airline
-
SAS,
Swiss
or
TAP
-
that
is
not
one
of
the
A++
partners;
the
purported
A++
integrative
efficiencies
thus
would
not
apply
to
SAS,
Swiss,
or
TAP
’s
operations
on
these
routes.
The
only
explanation
for
DOT
s
decision
is
that
carve
outs
would
prevent
the
alliance
members
from
improving
connections
on
these
bridge
routes
-
i.e.,
the
links
between
Continental
s
extensive
U.S.
network
and
the
European
networks
of
SAS,
Swiss
and
TAP
-
thereby
“disadvantaging
the
smaller
carriers
and
jeopardizing
potential
benefits
for
consumers,
Order
at
13.
DOT,
however,
does
not
cite
to
evidence
that
carve
outs
in
these
markets
would
foreclose
efficiency-enhancing
network
improvements.
103
DOT
also
states
that
it
will
remove
the
existing
carve
outs
in
Frankfurt-
102
Order
at
12.
103
The
Applicants
state
that
carve
outs
are
not
needed
on
these
routes
because,
even
though
SAS,
Swiss,
and
TAP
are
not
parties
to
the
A++
Agreement,
the
specific
transatlantic
city
pairs
are
within
the
geographical
scope
of
the
A++
Agreement.
J.A.
at
92,
n.l
81.
They
do
not
-
and
cannot
-
explain
how
the
purported
integrative
efficiencies
of
A++
could
apply
on
routes
where
the
overlap
airlines
are
not
both
A++
members.
38
Chicago/Washington
-
provided
the
Applicants
submit
proof
within
18
months
that
the
A++
agreement
has
been
executed
and
implemented
-
because
the
“proposed
alliance
is
pro-
competitive.
104
Other
than
the
fact
that
these
two
routes
fall
within
the
scope
of
A++,
the
Order
cites
no
evidence
to
support
revoking
the
carve
outs
beyond
the
Applicants
own
self-serving
statements.
The
Applicants
do
not
provide
specific
evidence
or
quantification
of
diminished
efficiencies
or
consumer
value,
even
though
Star
members
have
long
operated
under
carve
outs
imposed
as
part
of
prior
immunity
grants.
DOJ
recommendation
on
carve
outs
Absent
a
showing
of
substantial
efficiencies
that
would
be
imperiled
by
a
narrower
grant
of
immunity
-
which
the
Applicants
have
not
made
-
we
believe
that
the
competitive
harm
likely
to
be
suffered
by
consumers
in
these
transborder
and
transatlantic
markets
is
not
offset
by
public
benefits.
Therefore,
the
immunity
grant
should
be
more
narrowly
tailored
to
minimize
anticompetitive
effects.
In
the
case
of
the
current
application,
we
recommend
that
any
grant
of
antitrust
immunity
not
apply
to
travel
on
the
following
routes:
Houston-Calgary,
Houston-Toronto,
Cleveland-Toronto,
NYC-Halifax,
NYC-Ottawa,
NYC-Stockholm, NYC-Copenhagen,
NYC-
Lisbon,
NYC-Geneva,
and
NYC-Zurich.
These
routes
are
concentrated
and
entry
would
likely
be
difficult
due
to
the
existence
of
a
Star
ATI
Alliance
carrier
hub
at
either
one
end
or
both.
105
DOT
should
also
maintain
the
existing
Frankfurt
to
Chicago/Dulles
carve
outs.
When
DOT
imposed
carve
outs
in
the
original
United/Lufthansa
immunity
request,
it
1
04
Order
at
13.
105
As
discussed
above,
it
would
be
very
difficult
for
a
non-hub
carrier
to
offer
sufficient
frequencies
to
attract
local
customers
or
to
garner
the
connecting
feed
traffic
necessary
to
sustain
nonstop
service
in
thin
markets.
39
provided
that
antitrust
immunity
would
not
extend
to
coordinated
activity
with
respect
to
local
U.S.-point-of-sale
passengers
flying
nonstop
on
the
listed
routes.
106
In
subsequent
grants
of
immunity,
however,
DOT
has
limited
the
carve
out
to
coordinated
activity
“with
respect
to
unrestricted
coach-class
fares
or
any
business
or
first-class
fares
for
local
U.S.-point-of-sale
passengers
flying
nonstop
in
the
specified
city-pair
markets.
107
Such
a
narrow
exemption
applies
at
most
to
a
very
small
number
of
coach
tickets
and
does
not
include
many
tickets
with
modest
restrictions
commonly
sold
to
business
passengers
at
a
discount
to
full
Y
fares.
Our
analysis
of
coach
fares
on
international
routes
indicates
that
the
narrow
carve-out
language
is
insufficient
to
protect
competition
on
overlapping
hub-hub
routes
operated
by
alliance
partners
because
decreasing
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
increases
all
nonstop
coach
prices,
not
just
the
prices
charged
for
unrestricted
coach-class,
business
or
first-class
nonstop
fares.
108
To
be
effective,
carve
outs
should
not
be
restricted
to
such
a
limited
range
of
fare
classes;
instead,
DOJ
recommends
a
return
to
the
more
expansive
carve
out
language
used
in
the
1996
United/Lufthansa
order.
B.
Deny
global
immunity
The
Applicants
seek,
and
the
Order
to
Show
Cause
tentatively
grants,
immunity
for
Continental
and
the
Star
ATI
members
to
coordinate
on
a
global
basis,
despite
the
lack
of
any
concrete
plans
for
integration
outside
the
transatlantic
venture.
The
Applicants
present
no
106
Order
96-5-27,
App.
4.
107
See,
e.g.,
Order
2000-5-13
(American/Swissair),
Appendix
1.
108
See
Appendix
B,
Section
I,
which
estimates
that
fares
that
are
paid
by
nonstop
coach
passengers
increase,
on
average,
when
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
decreases.
The
carve
out
language
proposed
by
DOJ
would
protect
these
passengers;
the
carve
out
language
in
more
recent
DOT
orders
would
not.
40
evidence
that
immunity
for
non-transatiantic
operations
is
required
by
the
public
interest:
they
do
not
describe
how
they
will
integrate
their
operations
in
these
markets,
what
new
routes
they
will
serve,
or
what
public
benefits
will
flow
from
non-transatlantic
immunity.
109
The
Applicants
allege
that
they
plan
in
the
future
to
enter
into
ventures
modeled
upon
A++
covering
areas
outside
of
the
transatlantic.
The
record, however,
is
devoid
of
details
as
to
where
these
additional
joint
ventures
will
operate,
who
the
parties
to
the
ventures
will
be,
what
form
their
integration
will
take,
or when
the
ventures
will
be
implemented.
110
A
public
interest
determination
cannot
be
based
on
entirely
hypothetical
agreements.
Moreover,
the
evidence
in
the
record
shows
that
current
non-transatlantic
cooperation
is
minimal
even
among
the
currently
immunized
Star
members.
Asked
by
DOT
to
describe
the
current
state
of
non-transatlantic
cooperation,
the
best
example
the
Applicants
could
provide
was
the
consolidation
of
airport
facilities
at
Beijing
and
Tokyo.
111
While
such
cooperation
may
constitute
an
efficiency,
it
does
not
require
antitrust
immunity;
in
fact,
the
highlighted
109
DOT
dismisses
concerns
about
the
scope
of
the
immunity
on
the
grounds
that
the
other
Star
partners
have
global
immunity
with
each
other
for
many
years.
Therefore
DOT
concludes
that
it
“has
enough
information
to
analyze
the
alliance
plans
and
that
restricting
the
scope
here
would
unfairly
disadvantage
Continental.
Order
at
20.
DOT
does
not
cite
the
other
information
it
relies
upon
to
analyze
the
alliance
plans,
nor
does
it
explain
how
Continental,
or
more
significantly,
consumers,
would
be
harmed
by
the
lack
of
global
immunity.
110
The
Order
directs
the
Applicants
to
show
that
the
A++
joint
venture
has
been
implemented
as
described
in
the
Joint
Application
within
18
months
to
retain
immunity.
Order
at
26.
There
is
no
requirement
that
the
Applicants
demonstrate,
at
any
point
during
the
5-year
period
covered
by
the
Order,
that
they
have
implemented
similar
integration
agreements
that
cover
non-transatlantic
markets
or
that
include
Star
ATI
members
not
parties
to
the
existing
A++
agreement.
111
Responses
of
Joint
Applicants
to
Clarification
Questions
at
4-5.
41
consolidation
effort
included
a
number
of
non-immunized
Asian
Star
Alliance
carriers.
2
The
documents
cited
by
the
Applicants
as
providing
additional
examples
of
non-transatlantic
cooperation
requiring
antitrust
immunity
contain
similar
examples
of
operational
and
marketing
coordination
such
as
lounge
sharing,
frequent
flyer
cooperation,
and
joint
baggage
handling?
13
Such
coordination
is
a
common
feature
of
non-immunized
alliances,
and
the
non-immunized
members
of
Star
routinely
engage
in
such
conduct.
A
grant
of
global
immunity
between
Continental
and
United
would
eliminate
competition
in
non-transatlantic
international
markets
where
they
currently
compete
and
would
increase
the
risk
of
spillover
effects
in
domestic
markets.
The
Applicants
have
not
shown
that
global
immunity
between
United
and
Continental
is
necessary
to
the
public
interest;
in
the
absence
of
such
a
showing
there
is
no
justification
for
accepting
the
risk
of
harm
to
passengers
in
both
international
and
domestic
markets.
Accordingly,
we
recommend
limiting
the
grant
of
immunity
between
Continental
and
the
other
Star
ATI
members
to
transatlantic
operations.
VIII.
Conclusion
The
immunity
requested
by
the
Joint
Applicants
is
unprecedented
in
scope
and
breadth,
sanctioning
collusion
by
United
and
Continental
on
all
international
service,
eliminating
or
significantly
reducing
competition
between
certain
Star
alliance
members
on
routes
where
they
provide
the
only
-
or
almost
all
of
-
the
competitive
alternatives,
and
removing
previously
112
At
Narita,
the
immunized
Star
airlines
are
located
in
the
South
Wing
along
with
non-
immunized
Star
members
ANA,
Shanghai,
Thai
and
US
Airways.
113
42
imposed
protections
designed
to
preserve
competition
on
overlap
routes.
The
result
is
likely
to
be
substantia]
consumer
harm.
Our
empirical
work
indicates
that
fares
are
likely
to
increase
by
roughly
15%
on
routes where
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
decreases
from
two
to
one,
and
by
roughly
6%
on
routes
where
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
decreases
from
three
to
two.
Competition
will
be
significantly
diminished
in
limited
entry
markets
such
as
China,
where
United
and
Continental
today
present
the
best,
and
in
some
cases,
only
service
alternatives.
Domestic
competition
between
United
and
Continental
may
also
be
affected.
The
Joint
Applicants
have
offered
little
in
the
way
of
consumer
benefits
arising
from
the
application
to
counter
the
likely
harm;
in
contrast,
DOJ
empirical
work
shows
that
carriers
in
non-
immunized
alliances
offer
lower
prices
than
those
in
immunized
ones.
In
short,
the
Joint
Applicants
have
not
justified
their
extraordinary
immunity
request.
Thus,
for
these
and
all
the
foregoing
reasons,
the
DOJ
believes
the
DOT
should
amend
its
Order
granting
the
Joint
Application.
Respectfully
submitted,
Christine
A.
Varney
Assistant
Attorney
General
Antitrust
Division
Molly
S.
Boast
Carl
Shapiro
Deputy
Assistant
Attorneys
General
Donna
Kooperstein
Ji
ll
A.
Ptacek
Chief
Michael
D.
Billiel
William
H.
Stallings
Tracey
D.
Chambers
Assistant
Chief
Robert
D.
Young
Attorneys
43
Appendix
A:
China/Beijing
U
.S origin
City
to
Beijing
New
Orleans
Syracuse
Manchester
Tulsa
Cleveland
Rochester
Richmond
W
Palm
Beach
Buffalo
Boston
Tampa
Pittsburgh
Orlando
Columbus
Fort
Lauderdale
Jacksonville
Raleigh
Kansas
City
Nashville
Indianapolis
Austin
Charlotte
Atlanta
Birmingham
St.
Louis
Houston
Miami
Baltimore
U.S.
to
Beijing
Passenger
Shares
for
One
and
Two
Stop
Passengers,
2007Q4
-
2008Q3
nw interline total
all
co
C
O
UA
UA
NW
All
Other
Interline
CO+UA
other
pass
Share
Pass
share
pass
share
Airlines
share pass
share
Share
Pass
Data;
O
D
I
B
passengers with
one
or
two
stops
for
2007
Q4
-
2008Q3,
adjusted
for
sampling
by
multiplying
by
10.
Routes
must
have
at
least
200
passengers
for
each
of
CO
and
UA
to
be
included,
and
a
combined
CO
+
UA
share
of
at
least
50%
of
all
passe
nger
Interline
passengers
have
different
marketing
carriers
on
different
segments
of
their
trip.
Share
Appendix
A:
China/Hong
Kong
U.S.
to
Hong
Kong
Passenger
Shares
for
One
and
Two
Stop
Passengers,
2007Q4
-
2008Q3.
U.S Origin
city to hong
kong
C
O
Pass
CO
Share
UA
Pass
UA
share
NW
Pass
NW
share
All
Other
Air
l
in
es
All
others
share
Interline
pass
I
nterline
Share
CO
+UA
Total
Pass
W
Palm
Beach
Rochester
Columbus
Richmond
Cleveland
Fort
Lauderdale
Greensboro
Birmingham
Wash
Dulles
Providence
Orlando
Kansas
City
Baltimore
Hartford
New
Orleans
Tampa
San
Antonio
Pittsburgh
Boston
Houston
Jacksonville
Raleigh
Wash
National
Nashville
St.
Louis
Cincinnati
Data;
O
D1B
passengers
with
one
or
two
stops
for
2007
Q4
-
2008Q3,
adjusted
for
sampling
by
multiplying
by
10.
Routes
m
u
st
h
ave
at
least
200
pass
eng
ers
for
each
of
CO
and
UA
to
be
include
d,
and
a
c
o
mbined
CO
+
UA
share
of
at
lea
st
50% o
f
all
passengers.
Interline
passengers
have
different
marketing
carrier
s
on
different
se
gments
of
their
trip.
46
Appendix
B:
Empirical
Addendum
The
empirical
analyses
in
this
Addendum
use
the
publicly-available
DB1B
ticket
database
maintained
by
the
U.S.
Department
of
Transportation.
The
DB1B
data
are
a
10%
random
sample
of
tickets
either
ticketed
by
a
U.S.
carrier
or
where
a
U.S.
carrier
operated
at
least
one
flight
in
the
ticket
s
itinerary.
The
data
are
compiled
quarterly.
The
only
information
provided
by
a
ticket
in
DB1B
is
the
purchased
price
(in
dollars),
number
of
coupons
in
the
ticket
’s
itinerary,
1
14
number
of
sampled
passengers
traveling
the
itinerary
at
the
particular
fare,
and,
for
each
coupon,
the
fare
class,
115
origin
and
destination
airports
as
well
as
the
operating
and
marketing
carriers.
Tickets
ticketed
by
foreign
carriers
that
include
no
flights
operated
by
U.S.
carriers
are
not
reported
in
DB1B.
I.
Price
Effects
from
the
Loss
of
Nonstop
Competition
in
Transatlantic
Routes.
Our
empirical
evidence
shows
that
a
reduction
in
the
number
of
competing
airlines
offering
nonstop
transatlantic
flights
may
result
in
large,
statistically
significant
price
increases.
To
determine
the
effects
from
changes
in
the
number
of
competing
airlines
offering
nonstop
transatlantic
flights,
we
analyze
the
DB1B
data
for
the
3
rd
quarter
of
2008.
We
define
a
route
as
a
non-
directional
city
pair
with
one
endpoint
in
the
U.S.
and
the
other
endpoint
in
Europe
(that
is,
transatlantic
routes)
.
We
extract
from
DB
1B
1
-coupon
coach-class
tickets
(one-way
tickets)
and
2-coupon
coach-class
round-trip
tickets
that
have
the
same
starting
and
ending
city.
116
We
split
the
round-trip
tickets
into
one
-
way
tickets
and
divide
the
fare
by
two,
so
that
the
data
are
on a
one-way
basis.
Following
Brueckner
and
Whalen
(2000),
117
we
drop
tickets
with
one-way
fares
below
$50
since
these
may
represent
trips
purchased
with
frequent-flyer
miles
or
made
by
airline
employees
at
significantly
reduced
fares.
We
then
compute
the
passenger-weighted
average
fare
for
each
route.
The
object
of
the
empirical
analysis
is
to
analyze
how
the
average
fare
varies
across
transatlantic
routes
based
on
the
number
of
airlines
offering
nonstop
flights
in
a
route,
controlling
for
other
factors
that
may
affect
fares.
In
the
hub-and-spoke
networks
that
the
major
transatlantic
carriers
operate,
the
majority
of
nonstop
service
that
an
airline
offers
radiates
from
its
hubs,
and
the
airline
relies
on
connections
through
its
hubs
to
serve
thousands
of
other
routes.
Given
this
structure,
the
major
network
carriers
provide
overlapping
transatlantic
nonstop
service
on
routes
between
their
hubs
or
from
the
same
hub
airport
if
they
share
a
hub
airport.
To
control
for
the
economics
of
hubs,
we
focus
our
attention
on
routes
between
two
hubs
of
an
immunized
alliance
and
routes
served
by
multiple
carriers
with
a
hub
airport
in
the
route.
Our
sample
data
include
65
routes
(see
the
Attachment
for
a list).
To
identify
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
in
these
routes,
we
use
flight
listing
data
from
the
1
1
4
A
coupon
may
denote
a
nonstop
flight
or
a
direct
flight.
A
direct
flight
is
a
connecting
flight
(that
is,
a
flight
with
a
stop
at
an
intermediate
transit
airport)
with
no
change
of
aircraft
or
flight
number.
1
1
5
The
DB
IB
data
reports
the
generic
fare
class
for
each
coupon
in
a
ticket.
The
most
common
fare
classes
are
C,
D,
X,
and
Y,
where
C
and
D
are
business
fare
classes,
X
is
the
main
coach
cabin
fare
class,
and
Y
typically
stands
for
full-fare
coach
fare.
DB1B
provides
no
other
data
on
passenger
mix.
1
1
6
We
focus
on
tickets
in
which
all
coupons
have
coach
fare class
X.
These
tickets
represent
90%
of
all
tickets
in
our
data.
Our
results
are
not
affected
if
we
also
include
tickets
with
Y
fare
class
coupons
(only
1.5%
of
tickets
have
coupons
with
Y
fare
classes).
117
Brueckner,
J.,
and
Whalen,
T.,
2000,
The
Price
Effects
of
International
Alliances,
Journal
of
Law
and
Economics,
43,
503-454.
These
authors
analyze
the
price
effects
of
immunity
grants
in
transatlantic
routes
with
nonstop
service
using
1997
quarter
three
data
from
DOT.
They
estimate
that
average
fares
rise
by
about
5%
when
immunity
is
granted
to
two
previously
competitive
carriers.
47
Official
Airline
Guide.
An
airline
is
counted
as
serving
a
route
nonstop
if
it
offers
at
least
60
flights
in
each
direction
during
the
quarter.
Different
airlines
serving
the
route
nonstop
are
counted
as
competing
unless
they
were
immunized
members
of
the
same
alliance
during
the
quarter,
in
which
case
they
count
as
a
single
competitor.
158
We
define
dummy
variables
to
denote
the
number
of
competitors
in
a
route.
Monopoly
routes
are
the
reference
group.
The
competitive
variables
equal
one
when
there
are,
respectively,
2, 3, 4,
or
5
or
more
nonstop
competitors
in
the
route
and
zero
otherwise.
Eighteen
of
the
65
routes
in
our
data
are
nonstop
monopolies,
28
have
2
nonstop
competitors,
13
have
3
nonstop
competitors,
4
have
4
nonstop
competitors,
and
2
have
6
nonstop
competitors.
519
Having
already
controlled
for
hub
effects,
following
Brueckner
and
Whalen
(2000),
we
include
as
additional
control
variables
the
mileage
of
the
route
and
the
route
s
population
potential,
which
is
computed
as
the
geometric
mean
of
the
population
at
the
two
endpoint
cities
in
the
route.
120
Lastly,
the
airports
in
our
transatlantic
routes
are
major
U.S.
and
European
airports,
at
which,
to
begin
with,
members
of
all
of
the
major
airline
alliances
have
flight
operations.
These
alliances
include
multiple
members
that
make
available
a
large
number
of
single-connect
and
double-connect
travel
itineraries
to
passengers
across
the
sample
routes.
121
That
is,
there
is
significant
connecting
service
offered
across
all
of
our
routes.
We
use
the
ordinary
least
squares
method
to
estimate how
average
fares
vary
across
routes
based
on
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
in
a
route.
In
particular,
we
estimate
how
the
natural
logarithm
transformation
of
the
average
fare
varies
as
a
function
of
the
dummy
variables
denoting
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors,
the
natural
logarithm
transformation
of
the
mileage
distance,
and
the
population
potential.
122
Results
are
listed
in
Table
1.
The
model
explains
59%
of
the
variation
in
average
fares
across
118
This
assumes
that
non-immunized
members
of
the
same
alliance
remain
vigorous
competitors.
If
not,
then
the
price
effects
we
estimate
from
the
loss
of
a
nonstop
competitor
may
underscore
the
magnitude
of
the
true
price
effects.
119
In
seven
routes,
an
airline,
such
as
Air
India,
Eurofly,
Malaysia,
Kuwait
or
Pakistan
International
Airlines,
offers
less
than
60
nonstop
flights
in
each
direction
(it
typically
offers
30
to
40
flights
during
the
quarter).
Dropping
these
routes
from
our
data
does
not
affect
our
findings:
the
estimated
price
effects
are
statistically
significant
and,
if
anything,
slightly
larger
in
magnitude
than
those
reported
in
Table
1.
We
note
that,
over
the
past
three
years,
there
is
only
one
instance
of
a
non-hub
carrier
beginning
to
serve
any
of
the
46
transatlantic
hub
routes
that
have
one
or
two
nonstop
competitors
in
quarter
three
2008.
Chicago-Frankfurt
had
two
nonstop
competitors
in
quarter
three
2008;
during
quarter
four
2008,
Air
India
increased
its
Chicago-
Frankfurt
service
(part
of
its
longer
haul
service
to
India)
to
about
90
flights.
120
The
mileage
is
the
great
circle
distance
mileage
between
the
endpoints
of
the
route.
We
use
the
2008
U.S.
metropolitan
area
population
data
at
http://www.census.
g
ov/popest/metro/metro.html
.
European
population
data
is
from
European
Spatial
Planning
Observation
Network,
Study
on
Urban
Functions
(Project
1.4.3),
Final
Report,
Chapter
3,
(ESPON,
2007),
located
at
http://www.espon.eu/mmp/online/website/content/proiects/261/420/index
EN.html.
Additional
connecting
travel
itineraries
are
also
available
as
a
result
of
traditional
interline
agreements
or
bilateral
arrangements
between
airlines
not
in
alliances
or
across
different
alliances.
122
We
assume
that
the
number
of
airlines
offering
nonstop
flights
in
a
transatlantic
route
is
determined
prior
to
these
airlines
pricing
decisions.
This
assumption
is
reasonable
at
several
levels.
First,
given
that
airline
demand
is
revealed
over
time,
and
the
high
costs
associated
with
establishing
transatlantic
nonstop
service,
airlines
who
enter
a
transatlantic
route
will
publish
their
flight
schedule
and
advertise
their
new
service
well-ahead
of
actual
departure
dates.
Second,
the
number
of
airlines
with
nonstop
flights
in
our
hub
routes
is
quite
stable
over
time,
and
almost
exclusively
made
of
airlines
with
a
hub
at
an
endpoint
of
the
route.
Moreover,
across
our
sample
routes,
over
the
period
2005-2008,
the
number
of
nonstop
airlines
during
quarter
three
equals
that
in
quarter
two
99%
of
the
time.
We
also
note
48
routes
(R
2
0.59),
=
which
means
that
the
model
fits
the
data
well.
We
estimate
that
reducing
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
in
a
route
from
2
to
1
raises
average
nonstop
fares
in
the
route
by
15.0%,
all
else
equal.
123
This
effect
is
statistically
significant
at
the
1%
level.
In
addition,
we
estimate
that
reducing
the
number
of
nonstop
competitors
in
a
route
from
3
to
2
(4
to
3,
respectively)
raises
average
nonstop
fares
by
6.6%
(6.3%,
respectively),
all
else
equal.
12il
These
findings
are
consistent
with
both
previously
published
work
and
internal
DOJ
analyses
on
the
price
effects
from
the
loss
of
a
nonstop
carrier
in
domestic
hub
routes.
125
Moreover,
across
our
routes,
the
vast
majority
of
coach-class
passengers
(73%)
fly
nonstop,
even
though
average
connecting
fares
are
10%
lower
than
average
nonstop
fares.
Hence,
even
if
connecting
service
is
in
the
relevant
market,
the
loss
of
nonstop
competition
significantly
increases
concentration
levels
in
the
market,
and
we
have
evidence
of
large,
statistically
significant
price
effects
from
the
loss
of
nonstop
competition
on
the
fares
paid
by
the
vast
majority
of
passengers.
II.
Price
Differences
across
Tickets
within
a
Route.
The
parties
claim
that
immunity
grants
to
airline
alliances
are
necessary
to
reduce
a
double
marginalization
problem,
which
otherwise
arises
from
the
uncoordinated
choice
of
alliance
fares
in
the
absence
of
immunity.
To
support
their
claim,
they
cite
empirical
evidence
in
the
economics
literature
that
finds
that
immunized
alliance
fares
for
connecting
travel
itineraries
were
lower
in
the
1990s
than
non-
immunized
alliance
fares.
126
Since
the
1990s,
however,
the
airline
industry
has
undergone
major
global
changes,
including,
but not
limited
to,
an
increase
in
the
global
demand
for
travel
and consolidation
in
Europe.
Airlines
have
also
grouped
into
three
major
global
alliances
(Oneworld,
Sky
team,
Star)
and,
within
these
alliances,
non-immunized carriers
appear
to
have
made
significant
strides
towards
managing
more
efficiently
their
yield
management
and
capacity.
In
this
Section,
using
quarter
three
DB1B
data
for
2005
through
2008,
we
provide
newer
empirical
evidence
on
pricing.
Our
evidence,
which
shows
that
immunized
alliance
fares
are
higher
than
non-immunized
ones,
does
not
support
the
parties
claims
on
immunity
grants
and
double
marginalization.
that
if
we
delete
from
the
data
routes
with
entry
or
exit
in
other
quarters
in
2008,
we
obtain
similar,
statistically
significant
effects.
123
We
obtain
similar
results
running
the
model
on
quartile
fares
(25
th
,
50
th
,
or
75
th
percentile
fare)
rather
than
on
the
average
fare.
We
also
obtain
similar
results
if
we
expand
the
sample
to
include
all
129
transatlantic
nonstop
routes
for
which
we
have
data
(adding
to
the
model
a
dummy
variable
to
control
for
the
presence
of
dual
hubs
on
the
65
routes
of
focus
in
the
text).
The
itinerary
in
a
DB
1
B
ticket
is
reported
in
terms
of
coupons,
and
the
estimated
effects
apply
to
passengers
in
nonstop
and,
if
any,
direct
flights.
In
only
7
of
the
65
routes,
there
are
1-stop
direct
flights
reported
in
the
Official Airline
Guide
data,
in
the
text,
for
parsimony,
we
discuss
the
estimates
in
terms
of
their
effect
on
the
fares
paid
by
nonstop
passengers.
124
There
are
few
routes
in
our
data
with
3
or
more
competitors,
and
the
3-to-2
and
4-to-3
effects
are
not
statistically
significant.
125
See,
e.g.,
Peters,
C.,
2006,
Airline
Merger
Simulation,
Journal
of
Law
and
Economics,
49,
pp.627-649.
He
computes
actual
price
increases
of
between
7.2%
and
29.4%
following
the
loss
of
nonstop
competition
in
overlap
domestic
routes
involved
in
mergers.
126
See,
e.g.,
Brueckner
and
Whalen
(2000),
Brueckner,
j.,
2003,
International
Airfares
in
the
Age
of
Alliances,
Review
of
Economics
and
Statistics,
85,
pp.
105-118,
and
Whalen,
T.,
2007,
A
Panel
Data
Analysis
of
Code-Sharing,
Antitrust
Immunity,
and
Open
Skies
Treaties
in
International
Aviation
Markets,
Review
of
Industrial
Organization,
30,
39-61.
49
We
define
a
route
as
a
city-pair
in
a
quarter,
with
origin
u.s
the
U.S.
and
destination
in
Europe.
As
in
Brueckner
and
Whalen
(2000),
Brueckner
(2003)
and
Whalen
(2007),
we
drop
from
the
data
(i)
routes
from
U.S.
cities
where
foreign
carriers
offer
at
least
one
nonstop
flight
per
business
day
to
Europe,
because
the
DB
1
B
data
do
not
report
tickets
ticketed
by
foreign
carriers,
and
(ii)
routes
that
have
nonstop
flights
between
their
endpoints,
to
focus
on
routes
where
service
by
domestic
and
foreign
airlines
is
complementary
1
27
We
extract
from
DB1B
tickets
with
itineraries
that
represent
round-trip
travel
with
same
starting
and
ending
city.
Itineraries
may
have
up
to
6
coupons,
but
no
more
than
3
coupons
one-way
and no
surface
transfers.
Tickets
with
round-trip
fares
below
$100
(in
2008
quarter
three
dollars)
are
dropped,
since
these
may
represent
trips
purchased
with
frequent-flyer
miles
or
made
by
airline
employees
at
significantly
reduced
fares.
We
then
differentiate
between
tickets
that
are
either
online
tickets,
immunized
alliance
tickets,
non-immunized
alliance
tickets,
or
interline
tickets.
A
ticket
is
an
online
ticket
if
all
of
the
coupons
in
the
ticket
are
operated
and
marketed
by
a
single
airline
(including
its
regional
affiliates).
12
8
An
immunized
alliance
ticket
is
a
ticket
that
lists
two
or
more
airlines
as
operating
or
marketing
carriers
and
all
of
the
airlines
listed
on
the
ticket
are
immunized
members
of
the
same
alliance.
A
non-immunized
alliance
ticket
is
a
ticket
that
lists
two
or
more
airlines,
and
all
listed
airlines
are
members
of
the
same
alliance,
and
at
least
one
of
the
airlines
is
not
an
immunized
alliance
member.
Lastly,
a
ticket
is
an
interline
ticket
if
it
is
none
of
the
above?
29
Using
these
definitions,
67.8%
of
all
tickets
in
the
sample
are
online,
7.4%
are
non-immunized
alliance
tickets,
17.4%
are
immunized
alliance
tickets,
and
the
other
7.4%
are
interline
tickets.
We
use
ordinary
least-squares
regression
to
analyze
how
prices
vary
across
tickets
based
on
the
type
of
ticket,
the
major
U.S.
airline
reporting
the
ticket
130
,
and
the
mileage
and
number
of
coupons
in
the
ticket
s
itinerary.
We
use
dummy
variables
to
denote
each
of
the
type
of
ticket
(online,
immunized
alliance,
non-immunized
alliance,
or
interline
ticket)
and
carriers.
Online
tickets
are
the
reference
group.
We
also
include
in
the
model
route
fixed
effects
to
control
for
all
of
the
factors
that
are
invariant
in
a
route,
including,
but
not
limited
to,
the
level
of
competition
in
the
route.
We
estimate
the
model
using:
(i) all
of
the
tickets
in
the
data,
and
(ii)
coach-class
tickets
only?
31
Results
for
both
data
are
reported
in
Table
2.
We
discuss
below
the
results
based
on
the
coach
class
tickets;
the
estimated
fare
differentials
127
Within
the
U.S.,
we
exclude
Hawaii.
Within
Europe,
we
focus
on
destinations
in
the
European
Union,
Switzerland,
Norway,
and
Croatia.
Our
data
include
approximately
23,000
routes.
128
A
coupon
in
a
ticket
is
online
if
the
operating
carrier
is
the
marketing
carrier
on
the
coupon.
If
the
carriers
do
not
match,
the
coupon
may
yet
be
online
since
the
operating
carrier
may
be
a
regional
affiliate
of
the
marketing
carrier.
We
use
the
flight
listing
data
in
the
Official Airline
Guide
to
identify
regional
carrier
affiliations
for
major
airlines
on
an
individual
coupon
basis.
If
all
of
the
coupons
in
a
ticket
are
online
coupons
from
the
same
carrier,
then
the
ticket
is
online.
129
These
tickets
include
traditional
interline
tickets
and
tickets
that
obtain
from
bilateral
arrangements
between
airlines
not
in
alliances
or
in
different
alliances.
130
To
be
included
in
the
DB
1
B
data,
a
ticket
must
be
either
ticketed
by
a
U.S.
airline
or
include
at
least
one
flight
operated
by
a
U.S.
airline.
We
identify
the
major
U.S.
airline
listed
as
marketing
or
operating
carrier
across
the
coupons
in
the
ticket.
Fortractability,
we
drop
the
few
tickets
(5%
of
tickets)
that
list
two
or
more
major
U.S.
carriers.
131
The
coach
class
tickets
are
tickets
in
which
all
coupons
have
coach
fare
class
X.
In
this
Section,
these
tickets
represent
93%
of
all
tickets
sold.
We
note
that
Brueckner
and
Whalen
(2000),
Brueckner
(2003),
and
Whalen
(2007)
estimate
a
model
similar
to
ours
using
all
of
the
tickets
in
the
DOT
data,
but
for
first-class
tickets.
First-class
tickets
account
for
only
0.2%
of
all
the
tickets
in
our
data.
Dropping
these
tickets
is
inconsequential
for
the
results
in
Table
2
that
use
all
of
the
tickets
in
the
data.
50
are
slightly
larger
if
we
look
at
the
results
based
on
all
of
the
tickets.
We
estimate
that
interline
tickets
have
the
highest
sales
prices.
Interline
fares
are,
for
instance,
6.3%
higher
than
online
fares,
all
else
equal.
We
also
find
that
non-immunized
alliance
fares
are
1.5%
lower
than
online
fares.
This
difference
is
not
statistically
significant.
More
importantly,
controlling
for
other
factors,
we
estimate
that
immunized
alliance
fares
are
2.1%
higher
than
online
fares
and
3.6%
higher
than
non-immunized
alliance
fares.
Both
of
these
fare
differentials
are
statistically
significant
at
the
1%
level.
51
Table
1
Price
Effects
from
Loss
of
Nonstop
Competition
on
Transatlantic
Routes.
The
Dependent
Variable
is
In
(Average
Fare)
Estimate
Change
in
#
Estimated
Explanatory
Variables
(Standard
error)
of
nonstop
price
effect
in
competitors
percentages
1
Number
of
Nonstop
2
-.140*
2
to
1
+15.0%*
Competitors
(.043)
3
-.204*
3
to
2
##
+6.6%
(.044)
4
-.265*
4
to
3
+6.3%
(.064)
5
or
more
-.422*
(.081)
ln(Mileage
of
the
Route)
.638*
(.114)
Mean
of
City
Populations
.948
in
the
Route
(.731)
Constant
term
1.218*
(.953)
R
2
-
0.59.
Number
of
observations
(routes)
=
65.
Standard
errors
computed
with
White
heteroskedasticity
correction.
The
population
variable
is
divided
by
100
million,
for
scaling
purposes.
*
Indicates
statistical
significance
at
a
1%
level.
#
The
2
to
1
percentage
effect
equals
exp(,140)
-
1
-
15.0%.
##
-
=
6.6%.
The
3
to
2
percentage
effect
equals
exp(-.
1
40+.204)
1
##
#
The
4
to
3
percentage
effect
equals
exp(-.204+.265)
-
1
=
6.3%
52
Table
2
Price
Differences
Across
Tickets
based
upon
the
Type
of
Ticket.
The
Dependent
Variable
is
ln(
Ticket
Fare
)
Coach
Class
All
Tickets
Coach
Class
Tickets
Tickets
Estimate
Estimate
Estimated
Explanatory
variables:
(Standard
(Standard
Price
Differentials
error)
error)
Type
of
ticket:
Online
tickets
(
reference
group)
Non-immunized
alliance
-.017
-.015
relative
to
-1.5%
tickets
(0.010)
(0.009)
online
tickets
Immunized
alliance
.035*
.021*
relative
to
+2.1%*
tickets
(0.008)
(0.007)
online
tickets
Interline
tickets
.070*
.061*
relative
to
+6.3%*
(0.009)
(0.007)
online
tickets
#
Mileage
of
itinerary
-.046
-0.096*
in
ticket
(0.044)
(0.036)
Number
of
coupons
-.054*
-0.046*
in
itinerary
(0.005)
(0.004)
R
2
0.25
0.30
Number
of
tickets
126,520
117,494
Standard
errors
computed
with
White
heteroskedasticity
correction.
Estimates
for
route
and
carrier
fixed
effects
not
shown
in
the
Table.
*
Indicates
statistical
significance
at
a
1%
level.
#
The
percentage
effect
is
computed
as
exp(0.061)
-
1
=
6.3%
53
Attachment
Price
Effects
from
Loss
of
Nonstop
Competition
on
Transatlantic
Routes.
List
of
Transatlantic
Routes
in
the
Sample
Data.
U.S.
European
U.S.
European
endpoint
endpoint
endpoint
endpoint
Atlanta
Amsterdam
New
York
City
Stockholm
Atlanta
Paris
New
York
City
Athens
Atlanta
Rome
New
York
City
Barcelona
Atlanta
Frankfurt
New
York
City
Brussels
Atlanta
London
New
York
City
Budapest
Cincinnati
Amsterdam
New
York
City
Paris
Cincinnati
Paris
New
York
City
Copenhagen
Cincinnati
Rome
New
York
City
Dublin
Denver
London
New
York
City
Edinburgh
Detroit
Frankfurt
New
York
City
Rome
Detroit
London
New
York
City
Frankfurt
Detroit
Amsterdam
New
York
City
Lisbon
Detroit
Paris
New
York
City
London
Detroit
Frankfurt
New
York
City
Madrid
Washington
Amsterdam
New
York
City
Manchester
Washington
Paris
New
York
City
Milan
Washington
Frankfurt
New
York
City
Shannon
Washington
London
New
York
City
Berlin
Washington
Munich
New
York
City
Zurich
Washington
Zurich
Chicago Amsterdam
Houston
Amsterdam
Chicago
Paris
Houston
Paris
Chicago
Dublin
Houston
London
Chicago
Rome
Los
Angeles
Frankfurt
Chicago
Frankfurt
Los
Angeles
London
Chicago
London
Memphis
Amsterdam
Chicago
Manchester
Miami
Paris Chicago
Munich
Miami
London
Philadelphia
Paris
Miami
Madrid
Philadelphia
Frankfurt
Minneapolis
-
St
Paul
Amsterdam
Philadelphia
London
Minneapolis
-
St
Paul
Paris
San
Francisco
Frankfurt
New
York
City
Amsterdam
San
Francisco
London
Salt
Lake
Cit
y
Paris
54
CERTIFICATE
OF
SERVICE
I
hereby
certify
that
a
copy
of
the
foregoing
COMMENTS
OF
THE
DEPARTMENT
OF
JUSTICE
have
been
served
this
day
by
e-mail
upon
each
of
the
following
addresses:
jonathan.moss@wilmerhale.com
lachter@starpower.net
dvaughan@kelleydrye.com
recohn@hhlaw.com
howard_kass@usairways.com
kevin.montgomery@polaraircargo.com
nssparks@fedex.com
1
dwasko
@ero
ls.com
john.fredericksen@suncountry.com
Jeffrey
.
ogar@aa
.
com
prrizzi@hhlaw
.
com
bruce.rabinovitz@wilmerhale.com
lhalloway@crowell.com
dhainbach@ggh-airlaw.com
scott.mcclain@delta.com
sametta
.c
.
barnett@de
l
ta.com
david.heffernan@wilmerhale.com
Kathleen.Knowlton@wilmerhale.com
jrichardson@johnlrichardson.com
matwood@sherblackwell.com
Shannon.edwards@evergreenaviation.com
amendelsohn@sherblackwell.com
Benjamin.slocum@usairways.com
russell.bailey@alpa.org
slachter@lachter-clements.com
June
26,
2009
_________
Jill
Ptacek
55